The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2006-14 Screen Reader version*
Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy:
Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut

Jeffrey R. Brown

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign and NBER

 

Nellie Liang

Federal Reserve Board

 

Scott Weisbenner

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign and NBER

 

This version: January 2006

Keywords: Payout policy, Dividends, Share Repurchases, Executive Ownership, Executive Compensation, Agency Costs

Abstract:

Using the 2003 reduction in dividend tax rates to identify an exogenous change in the after-tax value of dividends to shareholders, we test whether stock holdings among company executives is an important determinant of payout policy. We have three primary findings. First, we find that when top executives have greater stock ownership, and thus an incentive to increase dividends for personal liquidity reasons, there is a significantly greater likelihood of a dividend increase following the 2003 dividend tax cut, whereas no such relation existed in the prior decade when the dividend tax rate was much higher. This finding is strongest for dividend initiations, and is robust to a rich set of firm and shareholder characteristics. Second, we provide evidence that approximately one-third of the firms that initiated dividends in 2003, a higher share than in previous years, scaled back share repurchases by an amount sufficient to reduce their total payouts. This offset potentially raised the total tax burden on shareholders at these firms because share repurchases are still tax-advantaged relative to dividends. Third, we find that while dividend-paying firms with a larger fraction of individual shareholders had greater stock price gains in response to the tax cut, the market appears to have at least partially anticipated that executives with high stock ownership might raise dividends at the expense of share repurchases and increase the average tax burden for individuals, which is consistent with the presence of agency conflicts within the firm.

JEL Classification: G32, G35. H24


The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Board. We thank Darrell Ashton, Vivek Choudhary, Yoon Sok Lee, and Lizy Mathai for excellent research assistance. We thank John Graham, Paul Harrison, Kevin Hassett, and seminar participants at the University of Illinois, the Federal Reserve Board, the American Enterprise Institute, and the 2006 AFA Meetings for their comments and constructive suggestions.

1. Introduction

Shareholder payouts have changed dramatically over the past two decades, with dividend payout ratios falling substantially and share repurchases increasing rapidly (Fama and French 2001; Grullon and Michaely, 2002). Following the dividend tax cut in the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA) of May 2003, however, dividend activity increased sharply, particularly the number of dividend initiations (e.g., Blouin, Raedy and Shackelford, 2004; Chetty and Saez, 2005).1 The dividend tax cut represented a large increase in the after-tax value of dividends to individual investors, as the top marginal tax rate on dividends was cut over 20 percentage points, from 38.6 percent to 15 percent.2 This tax change moved from initial proposal to signed law in under five months, and was thus largely unanticipated prior to 2003. Because this tax cut is an exogenous increase in the after-tax value of dividends to individual investors, it represents a unique laboratory for using actual firm behavior to determine the role of taxes and other factors that affect dividend policy.

We use this dividend tax change to answer three questions. First, what determines how firms responded to the dividend tax cut? In particular, can executive stock holdings explain the cross-sectional pattern of dividend increases? Second, do the dividend increases raise total firm payouts, or are they partially offset by reduced share repurchases? Third, by examining share price reactions around key events leading to the tax cut, are we able to shed light on whether these payout policy decisions reflect possible agency problems within firms?

Why might executive stock holdings influence the firm's reaction to the dividend tax cut? The 2003 dividend tax cut raised the after-tax value of a $1 dividend to high-income shareholders from 61.4 cents to 85 cents, a 38 percent increase. Thus, the cost of initiating or increasing dividend payments for executives who have large direct stock ownership decreased substantially in 2003. Moreover, executives who are non-diversified with large company stock ownership may place additional value on dividends for liquidity reasons, stemming from the fact that they may face explicit/contractual restrictions (e.g., Core and Guay, 1999) or implicit restrictions (e.g., insider sales may be viewed as a negative signal by the market) on their ability to sell shares of stock.3

In contrast, firms whose executives are compensated primarily in the form of cash or stock options would have no such incentives. Because employee stock options are rarely dividend-protected (Murphy, 1999), executives compensated with options have a personal financial incentive to limit dividends because they face a 100 percent implicit "tax" rate on dividends, both before and after the dividend tax cut. That is, executive options fall in value with the decline in the share price that results from a cash dividend which is not offset by the receipt of the dividend to option holders. Thus, while an executive who holds a large share of their wealth in options would have a personal financial incentive to keep dividend payments low, this is true both before and after the dividend tax cut. Indeed, several prior studies have found that when managers have more of their wealth in the form of options, rather than direct shares, they tend to use dividends less heavily (Lambert, Lanen and Larcker, 1989; Jolls, 1998; Weisbenner, 2000; Fenn and Liang, 2001; Kahle, 2002).

These prior studies, however, did not have any exogenous shift in the relative cost of distributing cash through dividends or repurchases. Because of this lack of exogenous variation, the previous literature is subject to the criticism that the cross-sectional correlation between executive compensation and payout policy may reflect unobservable characteristics, such as managerial quality or corporate governance, that generate both compensation policy and dividend policy. A key contribution of our study is that we use the unexpected and exogenous shift in the relative cost of paying dividends that arises from the tax change to address these criticisms and thus provide stronger econometric identification of the relations of interest.

More recently, in work conducted simultaneously with ours, other authors have also investigated the effect of the 2003 tax cut on firm payout behavior. While Chetty and Saez (2005) and Nam, Wang and Zhang (2004) are primarily focused on establishing a causal link between the tax cut and increased dividend activity, they do provide some cross-sectional evidence that dividend increases are positively related to share ownership by managers.4 Blouin, Raedy and Shackelford (2004) also report that dividend increases are positively related to insider ownership. Our study differs from these studies in several ways. First, our primary focus is on using the tax cut as a source of exogenous variation in the tax cost of executive ownership as a way of more definitively testing whether executive ownership influences payout decisions. Second, we test whether the dividend tax cut resulted in an increase in total firm payouts, or instead represented a substitution between payout mechanisms for some firms. Grullon and Michaely (2002) find that some of the increase in share repurchases over the past decade has come at the expense of a reduction (or lack of increase) in dividends. We provide what we believe is the first test of whether this pattern occurs in reverse, i.e., whether in response to the 2003 dividend tax cut, an increase in dividends is accompanied by a decrease in share repurchases. Third, we examine whether excess stock returns around key legislative events pertaining to the tax cut reflect potential agency costs. Specifically, we are interested in whether stock prices reacted to the possible agency conflict between executives' incentives to raise dividends when their personal ownership stakes are higher and the fact that the overall tax burden for other individual shareholders may have actually risen if dividends were substituted for share repurchases (which ought to still be preferred due to their lower effective tax rate).5

We have three principal findings. First, we provide evidence that executive stock holdings are an important explanation of which firms chose to respond to the tax cut by increasing dividends. We show that the substantial variation across firms in the fraction of shares held by top executives can explain approximately one quarter of the total unexpected increase in dividends after the May 2003 tax cut, and an even larger share (roughly one-half) of dividend initiations. In further support of this effect, we find that while there is virtually no relation between executive stock ownership and the likelihood of a dividend increase in the decade before the tax cut (when the dividend tax rate, and hence the cost to the stock-owning executive of paying out dividends, was much higher), not only is the relation quite strong in 2003, but it is disproportionately concentrated after the passage of the act in late May of that year (when the tax cost of paying dividends is substantially reduced). While other factors, such as executive stock option holdings, firm cash flow, leverage, past firm performance, and institutional ownership are important determinants of dividend policy in general, only the effect of executive stock holdings substantially changed with the change in tax regime, which is supportive of a tax effect. These results are quite robust to additional controls and to alternative specifications.

Our second finding is that, despite the increase in dividends in response to the tax cut, about one-third of firms that initiated dividends in 2003 scaled back repurchases by an amount sufficient to reduce total payouts (dividends plus share repurchases). This is in sharp contrast to prior years, when approximately 10 percent of dividend initiators reduced total payouts in the year of initiation. Our results further suggest that while the firms with more executive stock holdings are more likely to increase dividends, they are no more likely to increase total payouts. This suggests that, among those firms for which executive ownership had a large effect on dividend initiations, there is some degree of dividend-repurchase substitution occurring. Thus, while Grullon and Michaely (2002) found that firms with lower-than-expected dividend yields had larger repurchase programs in the 1990s, we find that many of the firms that initiated dividends in response to the 2003 tax cut were likely to at the same time reduce share repurchases, suggesting that payout substitution may work in both directions.

Finally, we explore potential agency problems by examining how the market responded to news of the 2003 tax cut. To the extent that there is some substitution occurring between dividends and share repurchases, this suggests that the dividend tax cut may have actually increased the overall tax burden for the typical individual shareholder as, even after the tax cut, capital gains are likely still tax advantaged relative to dividends. We find that the firms which historically have paid large dividends and which have a large fraction of individual shareholders experienced stock price gains in response to the proposal and passage of the tax cut. However, the market appears to have at least partially anticipated that some firms, in particular those firms whose executives had large stock holdings, would substitute dividends for tax-advantaged share repurchases or the retention of earnings, and thus potentially raise the tax burden on total distributions for individual shareholders.

This paper proceeds as follows. In section 2, we discuss our sample, summary statistics of the data, and provide more background on the 2003 dividend tax cut. In section 3, we present our results on the effect of executive share ownership on dividend increases, and test how the relation between executive holdings and dividend policy has changed over the pre- and post-tax-change regimes. In section 4, we examine whether firms who increase dividends are increasing total payouts, or are just substituting dividends for share repurchases, leaving total payouts unchanged. In section 5, we analyze the market response to news of the tax cut to determine whether the market anticipated for which firms the tax cut would lead to dividend substitution. Section 6 concludes.

2. Sample, Summary Statistics, and the 2003 Tax Cut

We begin with approximately 1,700 publicly traded firms in each year from 1993 to 2003 for which we are able to merge the necessary firm characteristic, stock, and executive compensation data from Compustat, CRSP and Execucomp.6 These firms together comprise the vast majority of total U.S. stock market capitalization. In addition to share ownership and options outstanding held by the top five executives, as provided by Execucomp, we are also interested in shares and options held by others. Because institutional investors may face different tax rates from managers and may serve as important monitors of firm activity, we collect data on institutional ownership from CDA Spectrum, including a split between mutual funds and other institutions. We also hand-collect data from company 10-k filings on options held by employees who are not among the top executive ranks. Specifically, we define options held by non-executive employees to be the difference between total and top executive holdings.

Table 1 reports summary statistics for our sample in 2002 and 2003. We focus on ordinary dividend increases in 2003 and contrast them with those in earlier years.7 We use CRSP data so that we can accurately measure whether the dividend announcement date was before or after the passage of the tax cut in May 2003. We code a firm as having increased dividends if, at any time during the period in question, the firm announced a dividend that was higher than the level of dividends they paid previously. Specifically, an increase in dividends is defined as an increase in dividends per share (adjusted for stock splits). We also make use of the Compustat definition of dividends to confirm dividend initiations among firms that previously did not pay dividends.

In 2003, 28.7 percent of the entire sample increased dividends, which is substantially larger than the fraction of dividend increasers in 2002 (which was 22.0 percent) and in other recent years. Particularly striking is the frequency of dividend initiations: 5.9 percent of previously non-dividend paying firms started paying dividends in 2003, compared to only 1.2 percent in 2002, and it is higher than for any other year since 1980.

Because our primary question of interest is how the executive ownership of company stock influences firm dividend policy, we highlight executive stock and option holdings in table 1. Consistent with prior literature, top executive ownership is 0.8 percent of firm shares at the median firm, and 3.8 percent on average. While the fraction of total shares outstanding held by top executives is relatively small, this can represent substantial wealth for these individuals. For example, at the median, the value of stock held by the top executives at the end of 2002 was almost $12 million, nearly four times the median annual cash salary and bonus for top executives of $3.3 million. Summary statistics for other variables are provided at the bottom of table 1.

3. Empirical Results on Executive Ownership and Dividend Increases

3.1 Results: Dividend Increases for 2003 Relative to Prior Decade

The May 2003 dividend tax cut represents an ideal experiment for several reasons. First, it is the first time in 17 years that the market faced a substantial reduction in the tax cost of paying dividends.8 Second, aside from the reduction in dividend taxes, the legislation was free of other major changes to the tax law that might confound empirical analysis of its effects. Third, it came largely as a "surprise" to the market, thus enabling us to treat it as an exogenous event. Specifically, the May 2003 legislation, which was made retroactive to January 1, 2003, was completely unanticipated until the days leading up to President Bush's speech to the Economic Club of Chicago in early January 2003. The news leakage of this idea prior to this event was minimal, and fewer than five months elapsed from the time of this announcement until the legislation passed.9 Therefore, it is virtually certain that firms did not adjust their compensation structure prior to 2003 in anticipation of a future dividend tax cut, and thus we can treat our measure of executive ownership (which is based on 2002 data) as pre-determined. This allows us to identify the causal effect of executive holdings on changes in dividend policy in response to the tax cut.

In table 2, we begin by exploring the correlation between the likelihood of a dividend increase and the fraction of shares held by the top five executives of the company.10 We also control for a rich set of covariates, including executive holdings of options, the firm's market-to-book ratio (a proxy for growth opportunities), free cash flow, cash on hand, leverage, past firm stock market performance, volatility, firm size, firm age (to control for the "maturity" effect posited by Julio & Ikenberry, 2005), and industry effects (covering 14 broad groups).11 These variables are as of year-end 2002, and are related to whether the firm increased ordinary dividends per share in 2003. Columns 1 through 3 report the results from a linear probability model, whereas columns 4 through 6 report results for a Probit model.

Our first principal finding is that the fraction of shares held by top five executives is a very important determinant of dividend policy. As shown in column 1, the coefficient on the fraction of shares outstanding held by the top executives is positive and highly significant; the coefficient of 54 indicates that moving from the 25^{th} percentile (0.3 percent) to the 75^{th} percentile (3.2 percent) of the fraction of shares held by the top executives raises the probability of a dividend increase by 1.6 percentage points, from a baseline of 28.7 percentage points.12 Further, a one-standard-deviation increase in executive ownership translates into a 4.2 percentage point higher likelihood of a dividend increase.

If it is indeed the case that the relation between executive stock ownership and dividend activity is driven by the change in the tax cost of paying dividends, then such a relation should not appear in prior years when dividends were taxed at a considerably higher rate (the top personal rate was nearly 40 percent over the 1993-2002 period). The next two columns, which report coefficients from a single regression, provide such a comparison. In column 2, we report the coefficients on key covariates over the 1993-2002 period pooled, while column 3 reports the interaction of these covariates with a year 2003 indicator variable.13 This approach allows us to easily test whether the effect of each covariate is different in 2003 than in prior years.

Focusing again on shares held by top five executives, we immediately see that there is no correlation between executive share ownership and dividend increases in the prior decade, but a strong relation in 2003, with the difference in the executive ownership effect highly significant. This pattern is consistent with the view that the dividend tax cut reduced the cost of paying dividends and thus raised the probability of a dividend increase for those firms in which management had the most to gain, such as by obtaining liquidity through dividend payments.

Before discussing other covariates, we also report, in columns 4 through 6, the marginal effects from a Probit specification. The marginal effect of a change in the fraction of shares held by the top five executives is nearly identical to that from the linear probability model.14

Turning to the many covariates that might plausibly explain firm payout behavior, we find a pattern that is quite consistent with our hypothesis. Not surprisingly, most of these covariates have significant explanatory power in explaining cross-sectional differences in dividend policy. Starting with the OLS results over the 1993-2002 period, the likelihood of increasing dividends is increasing with free cash flow, past five-year returns, and (log) market value of the firm. It is decreasing in the number of options held by top executives, cash on hand, leverage, and monthly stock price volatility.15

Perhaps most importantly for our hypothesis, the differences in the magnitude of these effects between 2003 and the earlier decade are all insignificant. In other words, we cannot reject a zero difference between the effect of these covariates in 2003 versus prior years (the p-value of the joint test that the differences in the non-ownership coefficients are all zero is 0.85). Thus, the only effect that has a differential effect in 2003 is executive share ownership, which is consistent with our tax-motivation hypothesis. The lack of a significant difference on the executive options variable is particularly notable, because the implicit 100% tax on dividends faced by executives who own non-dividend protected options did not change with the change in the tax law. This provides further reassurance that the observed correlations of interest are not being spuriously driven by some third factor that generally influences both executive compensation and payout policy.

The results from the Probit are similar. Executive stock option holdings, free cash flow, cash on hand, leverage, past returns, volatility, and firm market value are all significant predictors of firm payout behavior in general, but there is again no significant difference between 2003 and prior years. Owing to the non-linear fit of the Probit model, the magnitude of the marginal effects for many of the covariates are larger in absolute value than in the linear probability model, but as noted, our primary coefficient of interest (executive shares) is essentially unaffected. The p-value of the joint test that the differences (i.e., 2003 relative to 1993-2002 period) in the non-ownership coefficients are all zero is 0.53, with only the difference in the coefficient on market-to-book individually significant at the 10 percent level.

To summarize, the results in table 2 are consistent with our hypothesis that dividend increases were motivated by executives' personal financial incentives. Executive share ownership is a significant determinant of dividend policy in 2003 but not in prior years, which is consistent with a change in tax rates in 2003. Conversely, other determinants of dividend policy, while significant in all years, are generally not significantly different in 2003 versus prior years. This provides assurance that there were not other factors or events changing in 2003 that are spuriously driving the observed relation. These results suggest that dividend policy was changed in 2003 in response to the fact that the fall in dividend taxes reduces the cost of paying dividends, and this effect is strongest in firms where the executives' personal financial incentives are most affected by the tax cut.

3.2 Further Identification of the Executive Ownership Effect

In order to provide further evidence that the executive ownership effect is due to the tax cut, in table 3, we extend our analysis in two important ways. First, recognizing that the tax cut did not occur until late May 2003, we break 2003 into two shorter time periods representing the part of the year that fell before the tax cut and the part that fell after the tax cut. In other words, rather than simply focusing on 2003 versus 2002 (or the prior decade), we can focus on: i) the pre-2003 period, ii) the portion of 2003 through May 23 (when the tax cut was formally passed by Congress), and iii) the portion of 2003 after May 23 (the period immediately after the tax cut was passed). The CRSP data allow us to divide dividend increases into these sub-periods based on the announcement date, rather than the payable date, so that we can be sure of the relevant tax regime in place at the time the firm made its dividend decisions.

Second, we distinguish between dividend increases that are dividend initiations among firms that did not pay dividends in the prior year and dividend increases among firms that were already paying dividends. Among this latter group of firms that were already paying dividends, we can also look at firms increased dividends by a large amount, which we define as an increase in dividends per share of more than 25%.

These extensions are potentially important for determining causality. For example, dividing 2003 into a period before and after the tax cut may provide insight as to whether the tax cut itself is the reason for the observed strong 2003 correlation between executive ownership and dividend policy. If the observed correlation occurred mostly in the early part of the year, when ultimate passage of the tax cut was uncertain, one might be concerned that the observed correlation is not tax related. Of course, as with any legislative event, there is uncertainty about the release of information during the period between the initial announcement and the final passage of the act, and thus how firms will react. As noted earlier, the tax cut was unanticipated before January 2003, but then from January to May, the possibility of a dividend tax cut was in the news regularly. While the ultimate passage of the tax bill was not a "sure thing" during this period, some firms may have made changes to their dividend policy in anticipation of the possible tax cut. In particular, while it is highly unlikely that many firms would make a dramatic change in payouts, such as initiating a dividend program, solely in anticipation of a possible future tax cut, it is quite conceivable that a firm that was already paying dividends and already considering an increase, might go ahead and raise the dividend during the January to May period in anticipation of the tax cut. If the latter were the case, and if executives with heavy stock ownership are more likely to push for the increase, then we might expect to see the correlation between ownership and dividend increases become more important even before the passage of the Act than in previous years. Such an uptick in the correlation at the start of 2003 should be less likely for a dividend initiation, however, since the cost of being wrong about the tax cut would be greater (because the dollar amount of an average dividend initiation is typically much larger than the size of a dividend increase among prior dividend payers.)

The results, reported in table 3, are consistent with these patterns. Each coefficient reported in table 3 represents the marginal effect of the percent of shares held by top five executives on dividend increases from a separate linear probability model.16 In each regression, we include all of the same control variables from table 2, including the age and industry effects, but do not report the individual coefficients on those controls in the interest of brevity.17

The first row corresponds to the linear probability model from table 2, where the dependent variable is defined as any dividend increase (including firms with and without a previous history of paying dividends). In column 1, the 6.3 coefficient on the probability of increasing dividends over the 1993 to 2002 period suggests that executive share ownership was uncorrelated with dividend increases in the decade prior to the tax cut (this is the same 6.3 coefficient from column 2 in table 2). The second column in table 3 shows the result for 2002 only, and the coefficient is again quite similar and insignificant, as expected. In column 3, we see the highly significant coefficient of 54 on executive ownership for the year 2003, suggesting a strong effect of executive ownership on dividend increases (again, this is the same coefficient that we found in column 1 of table 2). In columns 4 and 5 of table 3, we separate 2003 into pre- and post-tax cut periods. As can be seen, the significant correlation between executive ownership and dividend increases is driven almost entirely by the post-tax cut period. The coefficient in the pre-tax cut period is indeed higher than in prior years, consistent with the possibility that some firms may have increased dividends in anticipation of the tax cut, but the effect is not statistically different from zero. In contrast, the coefficient for the post-tax cut period is 43.3, which is significantly different not only from zero, but also from the coefficient in prior years. These results provide further evidence that the observed correlation is indeed a tax effect.

How big is this executive ownership effect? The actual fraction of firms increasing dividends in the portion of 2003 following the tax cut approval in May was 16.8 percent. If one estimated a regression of dividend increases on the various explanatory variables during the same time period in 2002, and used the estimated coefficients to predict the post-May 2003 dividend increases, one would have predicted that only 9.5 percent of firms would have increased dividends. The difference, approximately 7.4 percent, represents the "unexpected" increase in dividend activity. The change in the relation between dividend policy and executive ownership after the tax cut (relative to the same period in 2002) can explain 2.0 of this 7.4 percentage points, or about one-quarter of the overall effect.

The results from row 1 of table 3 represent the combined effect of dividend initiations and dividend increases among firms already paying dividends. As noted, however, there are reasons to suspect that firms already paying dividends might be willing to increase their dividend in anticipation of a possible tax cut, whereas firms are less likely to initiate a new dividend program for tax reasons until after the tax cut has become law. This is because dividends are "sticky," in that investors may expect dividends to be paid out regularly once started and rarely cut (Lintner, 1956).

Turning to the second row of table 3, we focus on the subset of firms that did not pay dividends in the prior year and examine how executive compensation affects initiations. In the period prior to 2003, there is no discernable relation between executive compensation and dividend initiations, with an insignificant coefficient of 6.2 over the prior decade and -3.6 in 2002. In contrast, there is a strong relation in 2003, with a highly significant coefficient of 37.8. The coefficient of 37.8 indicates that moving from the 25^{th} percentile (0.3 percent) to the 75^{th} percentile (3.2 percent) of the fraction of shares held by the top executives raises the probability of a dividend initiation by 1.1 percentage points, while a one-standard-deviation increase in executive ownership translates into a 2.9 percentage point higher likelihood of a dividend initiation - both are economically large effects given the baseline initiation rate of 5.9 percentage points in 2003. An examination of columns 4 and 5 indicate that this correlation with initiations occurs entirely after the passage of the 2003 dividend tax cut. This result is consistent with our hypothesis, as a firm is unlikely to initiate a new dividend program for tax reasons until they are quite confident in the passage of the act.

As above, we can use the regression coefficients from the latter part of 2002 to predict the level of dividend initiations in the latter part of 2003 had the tax cut not occurred. By comparing the predicted to the actual, we find an "extra" 3.8 percentage points of firms initiated dividends after the tax cut. The change in the relation between dividend initiations and executive ownership after the tax cut (relative to the same period in 2002) can explain approximately half of this additional initiation activity (specifically, 1.8 percentage points of the 3.8 percentage point "unexpected" increase.)

In row 3, we turn to dividend increases among firms that already have a prior history of paying dividends to shareholders. While there is no significant relation between executive share ownership and dividend increases in the period before 2003, there is a highly significant coefficient (72.6) for the year 2003. In contrast to initiations, where this effect was concentrated in the post-tax cut months, this effect is more evenly divided over the pre and post tax cut period. This is not entirely surprising given that firms that already pay dividends and that may be already considering increasing dividends further may be more willing to go ahead and increase the level of their dividend in anticipation of the tax cut, because of the lower cost of being wrong about the tax cut.

Because many firms with dividend programs follow a rather predictable pattern of slightly increasing dividends every year, it is also of interest to focus on "large" dividend increases. We therefore examine whether executive ownership is correlated with the probability of increasing dividends by more than 25 percent over the prior year's dividend level.18 We observe a statistically significant relation between executive ownership in the pooled 1993 to 2002 data, although this effect is substantially and significantly smaller than in 2003, with a coefficient of only 12.9, versus the 64.9 that we observe in 2003. Thus, the overall pattern is similar to that of any dividend increase among prior payers (i.e., including smaller increases), with a coefficient for 2003 that is significant and much higher than in prior years, but with the effect spread much more evenly over 2003 than initiations.

Overall, these results indicate that the correlation between executive share ownership and dividend activity was uniquely strong in the year 2003. Firms were loathe to start paying dividends for tax reasons until they had a high degree of confidence that the tax reduction would become law, and thus the executive ownership effect upon initiations is concentrated almost entirely in the period following the tax cut. For dividend increases among firms that already pay dividends, the results suggest that many of the firms with high executive ownership increased dividends even prior to final passage, during the period in which the President and Republican members of Congress were moving the tax cut from initial proposal to final legislation.

3.3. Share and Option Ownership by Institutions and Other Individuals

Our results provide evidence that the stock ownership of top executives has a significant effect on a firm's decision of whether to increase dividends after the tax cut. Of course, ownership by other groups could also have led to a differential response to the tax cut. For example, a firm that is owned mostly by individual investors would benefit relatively more from the tax cut than a firm whose shares are owned primarily by pension funds, whose dividend income is not subject to tax.19 Further, options held by non-executives, as well as those held by top executives, have been shown to influence payout policy (Lambert, Lanen and Larcker, 1989; Jolls, 1998; Weisbenner, 2000; Fenn and Liang, 2001; Kahle, 2002). However, since options are not dividend-protected, their effect on dividends should not vary with a change in dividend tax rates. In light of this, we have tested whether these other stock and option holders influence dividend policy, and if so, whether the effect changed with the tax cut.

In table 4, we re-estimate our primary specifications for the 2003 sample, as well as the difference in the relevant coefficient for 2003 relative to the pooled period 1993-2002. However, this time we include additional controls for the fraction of shares held by individual investors other then the top five executives and the fraction of shares held by non-mutual fund institutional investors (primarily tax-exempt pension funds). Like top executives, all individuals would face a higher after-return to dividends in 2003 than earlier years. However, the share of the firm held by each of the non-executive individuals is less likely to represent a large part of their own personal wealth, and so the provision of liquidity is not nearly as an important an incentive for dividend payments as it is for top management. The omitted category in this specification is mutual funds, which includes both taxable and tax-exempt accounts and which would potentially benefit more from the tax cut than non-mutual fund institutional investors.

The key finding from this specification is that even after controlling for individual and institutional ownership, the coefficient on executive ownership shares in 2003 relative to the prior decade (displayed in column 3 of table 4), is 47.4 and highly significant (little changed from the 47.7 in the specification without individual and institutional ownership displayed in column 3 of table 2).20 Thus, while many of the other ownership variables are themselves significant, their inclusion does not alter the executive ownership effect, and, unlike executive stock holdings, their own effect on dividend policy does not change in 2003 with the tax cut.

The effects of the other ownership variables are of some interest in their own right. For example, we find a positive relation between the fraction of shares held by individuals and the likelihood of a dividend boost during 2003 which by itself is consistent with the tax motivations. However, in contrast to the results for executive ownership, the relation for non-executive individuals was no different in 2003 than it was for the prior decade when dividend tax rates were much higher.21 Brav, Graham, Harvey, and Michaely (2005) find that only 1/5 of chief financial officers report that the personal taxes shareholders pay are important when making dividend decisions. Our results are consistent with this survey evidence; we find that firms with high individual ownership did not boost dividends in response to the 2003 tax cut, rather what matters is whether executives themselves owned stock.

In addition, we find a positive and significant coefficient on the fraction of shares held by non-mutual fund institutions, which presumably have more tax-exempt assets than mutual funds (the omitted category), throughout the 1993 - 2003 period. The effect is not statistically different in 2003 than over the prior decade. Of course, the dividend tax cut yields no direct increase in the after-tax value of dividends paid on shares held by tax-exempt institutions, and a pure tax story would suggest the opposite sign. This finding, however, is consistent with the view that institutional investors such as pension funds serve as monitors of firms. Pension funds, for example, are generally considered to be much more active monitors of corporations, whereas mutual funds are thought to "vote with their feet" and simply sell the shares of companies with poor governance mechanisms (Gillan and Starks, 1998). With skepticism about the quality of corporate earnings in the post-Enron period, there was a growing perception that firms should be pressured to pay dividends, because cash distributions cannot be manipulated and make it easier for investors to verify the cash flows of the firm. In addition, DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Skinner (2000) also argue that institutions may like the smoothness of regular dividends because it makes their task of rebalancing their portfolios more predictable and thus they increase their demand for dividends when its after-tax cost to other shareholders declines.

In unreported results, we also find that options held by employees outside of the top senior ranks have a negative effect on dividend increases in 2003, but that the effect is about one-third the magnitude of that for options held by the top executives. Similar to executive options, the effect of lower management options on dividend policy is not different in 2003 relative to 2002, as would be expected, given that the dividend "tax rate" on options is 100% both years.22

In sum, the coefficients on the additional ownership variables and the option variables, both for upper management and lower level employees, suggest that they also influenced the likelihood of a dividend increase in 2003. However, only the relation with executive stock ownership is larger in 2003 relative to the pre-tax cut period, indicating that the tax cut did not influence dividends through these other measures. The inclusion of these other controls has very little influence on the executive holdings variables, suggesting that our executive holdings results are not being spuriously driven by the composition of the other owners of the firm.

3.4 Further Robustness Checks

In this section, we briefly discuss the large number of specification checks that we conducted.23 The key point is that our primary finding - namely, that executive stock ownership strongly influenced payout policy following the 2003 dividend tax cut - is extremely robust.

Using the CRSP definition of dividends allows us to determine the precise dividend announcement date, and thus sub-divide the 2003 period into pre- and post-tax cut periods. We have, however, also tested our hypothesis using annual dividends paid as measured in Compustat, which includes both ordinary dividends as well as special dividends. In contrast to ordinary dividends, where the firm has the incentive to increase them only if they are confident that they continue to pay them in the future, special dividends are a one-time tool and do not necessarily signal a long-term increase in payouts. Given the prominence of Microsoft's announcement in July 2004 that they would pay a special dividend of $3 per share, totaling about $32 billion,24 and the work of Blouin, Raedy, and Shackelford (2004) that finds a rise in special dividends after the tax cut, one might be interested in whether the results are significantly affected. Using the Compustat measure of annual total dividends paid to construct dividend increases and initiations, we find that the results for 2003 are quite similar, with a highly significant coefficient on executive share ownership of 55.5 in the dividend increase regression and 38.1 in the initiation regression (the differences between these 2003 coefficients and those from the pre-tax cut period 1993-2002 are 51.4 and 32.6, respectively, and are also highly significant).25

Baker and Hall (2004) argue that for many incentive problems, the dollar amount of management ownership is a more accurate measure of management's incentives. Thus, as a second specification check, we replace our dependent variable with the log of the dollar amount of shares held. Returning to our CRSP definition of an increase in ordinary dividends, we find a coefficient on the natural log of the dollar value of shares held by top executive shares of 3.0, which is significant at the 1 percent level. Of note, we find that the coefficient in 2003 is also greater than the coefficient in the 1993-2002 period, and that this difference of 1.8 is significant at the 5 percent level. Among dividend initiators, we find a similar effect, with a coefficient on the log of the dollar value of executive shares of 1.8, which is significantly different from both zero and from the coefficient in the 1993-2002 period at the 1 percent level (difference in coefficients is 1.7).

Finally, we also break executive ownership into that held by the CEO and that held by other top executives to see if the holdings of the CEO are a bigger determinant of payout policy than those of the next four top executives in the firm (CEOs, on average, account for about one- half of the stock held by the firm's top five executives at the end of 2002). For both total dividend increases and dividend initiations, we find that both the share ownership of the CEO as well as that for the other top executives are important determinants of dividend policy in 2003.

4. Executive Holdings and the Dividend Substitution Hypothesis

The 2003 Economic Report of the President, released in February of that year, provided the Bush administration's economic rationale for the dividend tax cut. In the analysis, the administration highlighted a number of reasons that a cut in dividend tax rates could have positive economic effects, including the elimination of distortions to investment decisions of firms, arguing that "the heavier tax burden on dividends can encourage investment in established businesses with internally generated earnings, because these businesses will tend to have more retained earnings because of the tax distortion." Implicit in this claim is that the dividend tax cut will increase dividends and result in higher total payouts, rather than cause firms to shift the type of payout towards dividends and away from share repurchases. Grullon and Michaely (2002) find that firms with large repurchase programs also have a lower than expected dividend yield, indicating some substitutability between the two. We, on the other hand, wish to test if the reverse is also true - do firms that increased dividends in response to the tax cut at the same time reduce share repurchases?

In table 5, we examine dividends and share repurchases paid during a given year by firms in our sample as reported in Compustat. We define share repurchases as funds used to buy back shares, as reported on cash flow statements, consistent with other studies (e.g., Jagannathan, Stephens, and Weisbach, 2000; Fenn and Liang, 2001; Grullon and Michaely, 2002). For the subset of firms that increased/initiated dividends, as well as for firms that did not increase their dividend payouts, we report three statistics. First, we report the likelihood the firm repurchased shares in the previous year and thus has a track record of distributing cash through other means. Second, we report the likelihood that the firm decreased share repurchases (normalized by assets) conditional on having bought back stock in the prior year. Third, we report the probability that the firm increased total payouts (dividend plus share repurchases, normalized by assets) relative to the prior year. We do these calculations for three cohorts of dividend increasers, those that increased in the periods prior to the tax cut (1993-2002 and 2002) and those that increased dividends in 2003.26

The first row of table 5 reports results for all firms that increased dividends. It indicates that the fraction of dividend increasers in 2003 that had previously repurchased shares (67%) was not significantly different from the prior decade (65%). Just under two-thirds of the firms that increased dividends in 2003 reduced their level of share repurchases (normalized by assets), which is slightly higher than in prior years. The net result is that only half (52%) of dividend increasers actually increased total payouts (normalized by assets). This fraction is in line with prior years.27

For dividend initiations, the evidence is strongly suggestive of partial substitution. As shown in the middle row of the upper panel, we find that among firms that initiated dividends in 2003, 68 percent had repurchased shares in the previous year, significantly greater than the 38 percent in 1993-2002. Among these repurchasing-firms, 78 percent reduced their share repurchases from the previous year's level upon initiating dividends in 2003, again significantly greater than the 56 percent in 1993-2002. The net result is that 66 percent of all the firms that initiated dividends in 2003 (including those that had not repurchased shares in 2002) also increased total payouts, with the remaining one-third actually cutting total payouts the year they started paying dividends. As a benchmark, if no substitution had occurred, 100 percent of the firms that initiated dividends would have increased total payouts.28 The contrast of the effect of a dividend initiation on total payouts for 2003 relative to previous years is striking. During the previous decade (1993 to 2002), 89 percent of firms that initiated dividends increased total payouts. In 2002, the figure was 92 percent. These are much closer to the 100 percent rate that we would expect if no substitution had occurred. These results are not driven by what may have been a lower inclination to repurchase shares in the early to mid-1990s, as the pattern of increased payouts upon a dividend initiation is also present when we focus only on the year 2002. Thus, it appears that there are an additional 20 - 25 percent of dividend initiators in 2003 than in prior years that failed to increase total payouts in the year they initiated dividends.

Another possible reason that repurchases might have fallen in 2003 is that fewer stock options were being exercised that year, and thus the need to enter the market to acquire stock is potentially lessened. To test this possibility, we show in row 3 of table 5 that payouts did not decline to the same degree for firms that did not increase dividends. Specifically, the fraction of non-dividend increasers in 2003 that repurchased shares in the prior year (50 percent) was similar in 2003 as in prior years (44% over 1993-2002, 51% in 2002). Similarly, the fraction of firms that did not increase dividends in 2003 that experienced a decline in repurchases / assets in 2003 was quite similar to prior years (64% in 2003, versus 63% over prior decade and 58% in 2002). As such, it does not appear that our substitution result among initiators is driven by a general decline repurchases across all firms.

To provide perspective on the size of the change in total payouts, the bottom panel of the table shows the distribution of changes in dividends, share repurchases, and total payouts (all normalized by assets) for firms that initiated dividends. The normalized size of the dividend initiation is comparable for the pre-tax cut period (1993-2002) and the post-tax cut (2003), with no statistical difference in the mean or median. However, the changes in both share repurchases and total payouts in 2003 are considerably lower than the changes in previous years. The mean change in share repurchases (normalized by assets) is -1.6 percentage points in 2003, leading to only a 0.6 percentage point increase in the payout-to-asset ratio, compared to an average of a 4.5 percentage point increase over the period 1993-2002. Median changes in total payouts are also smaller in 2003, though not significantly different from earlier years. Perhaps most telling is the negative change in payouts at the 25^{th} percentile in 2003 relative to the slight increase in payouts at the 25^{th} percentile from 1993 to 2002, owing to the more frequent cutback in share repurchases that occurred in 2003.

Overall, these tabulations suggest some substitution from repurchases to dividends, at least among dividend initiators, prompted by the dividend tax cut. The fact that, among about one third of dividend initiators, there was no increase in total payouts might be somewhat surprising given that the tax burden of total payouts declined. However, for firms that had relied more heavily on share repurchases to distribute excess cash flow (which was evidently the case for many of the dividend initiators in 2003), the reduction in the tax burden is actually somewhat small. The tax rate on dividends was cut to the statutory rate on long-term capital gains (both are now 15%), but firms for which the higher tax burden of dividends was important likely had switched to share repurchases to exploit their tax advantage. With an equalization of statutory rates, these firms became more willing to substitute towards dividends and scale back repurchases, leaving total payouts little changed.

The analysis in table 5 suggests nontrivial substitution of dividends for share repurchases among firms initiating dividend programs. In table 6 we more rigorously model the determinants of the broader payout policy choices firms made in response to the 2003 tax cut. As in the bottom panel of table 4, we also focus here on the level of payouts, this time using a Tobit specification. Having established that there is some substitution occurring, we are now interested in whether the executive-ownership-induced increase in dividends in 2003 translated directly into higher total payouts or was instead offset, leaving total payouts little changed.

We begin by running a Tobit specification where the dependent variable is equal to the increase in the amount of dividends paid (again normalized by assets), or zero for firms that did not increase dividends-to-assets, during the year 2003. Column (1) reports the coefficients for the specification estimated on all firms. Looking first at the non-ownership control variables in the Tobit model, the results indicate, not surprisingly, that free cash flow and cash on hand are positively related to the size of a dividend increase, while the executive option holdings, the market-to-book ratio, and volatility are negatively related to the amount of the increase. This holds true both in 2003 and in unreported results for prior years. Turning to the primary coefficient of interest, we see that greater executive ownership of shares leads to a larger amount of dividends. Importantly, this effect is not only significantly different from zero, but it is also significantly different from the effect of executive ownership on the amount of dividend increases in the earlier decade. Indeed, in unreported results, a Tobit model estimated over the pre-tax cut period yields a statistically insignificant, close to zero, effect of executive ownership.

In column 2, we report a similar specification, but this time replace the increase in dividends with the increase in total payouts (dividends plus repurchases) as the dependent variable, with the increase in payouts normalized by assets. We find that while greater executive share ownership translates into a higher level of dividends, it does not lead to greater total payouts. These results suggest that firms with executive-ownership-induced dividend initiations in response to the 2003 tax cut often engaged in dividend substitution (i.e., often did not boost total payouts to shareholders as a result of the new dividend program). In unreported results, a Tobit model estimated over the pre-tax cut period also yields a statistically insignificant, close to zero, effect of executive ownership on total payouts. Thus, unlike the dividends result, the relation between executive holdings and total payouts do not seem to change in 2003.

In columns 3 and 4, the exercise is repeated for those firms that did not previously pay dividends. We find a highly significant positive relation between the executive share ownership variable and the amount of a dividend initiation. This relation does not, however, exist for total payouts. Again, this is evidence that those firms that initiated dividends due to executive ownership considerations did not always experience a comparable increase in total payouts.

These findings on dividend substitution complement prior studies that support substitution between dividends and share repurchases. Grullon and Michaely (2002) find higher share repurchases by firms whose dividend increases are less than what would be predicted by a model of firm-level dividend changes, and Dittmar (2000) has similar findings based on an aggregate-level analysis. Our study, which benefits from the exogenous change in the tax rate on dividends, provides evidence of payout substitution in the other direction. Specifically, we find that shareholder taxes are a factor in the choice of payout mechanism and that when the tax rates are more closely aligned, firms exhibit some substitutability between the two (i.e., increasing dividends, at least in part, by reducing stock buybacks).

5. Evidence from the Market Reaction to the Dividend Tax Cut Announcement

We have shown that a firm's ownership structure and the composition of its executive holdings influenced the change in payout policy following the dividend tax cut. This raises the possibility that, to the extent that the financial markets anticipated these responses, one might expect a differential market response to the dividend tax cut based on these characteristics. Here, we explore whether the market anticipated that at firms with large management stock holdings, the tax cut would lead to a substitution of dividends for tax-advantaged share repurchases, and thus perhaps raise the average tax burden on total distributions, at least for individual shareholders. This analysis can be thought of as an indirect test of whether the compensation contract for executives results in agency problems between executives and shareholders.

As with any event study, the power of the test depends on how accurately one can identify the actual date on which the value-relevant information was released to the financial markets. While an ideal event study has a very well defined event window, for legislative events the release of information is often spread out over a long legislative process, including, at minimum, an initial announcement of intent, committee hearings and votes, and votes by each house of Congress prior to final Presidential approval. Despite the difficulties, there is a long history of research examining the effect of legislative events on stock prices.29 The legislative process surrounding the 2003 dividend tax cut includes the possible release of information on multiple dates. For purposes of this section, we focus on eight event windows, each consisting of five trading days (a +/-2 day window around each event). These eight event windows are based on the careful analysis of news events between December 2002 and the May 2003 passage of the dividend tax cut conducted by Auerbach and Hassett (2005).30 These eight event windows, combined spanning 40 trading days, are meant to capture the market reaction from the initial announcement of the tax cut proposal by the White House through the final passage of the tax cut in the House and Senate.31

The average stock return for our sample of firms, compounded over the eight event windows, is 9.9 percent, with a median of 6.4 percent. Because a standard OLS regression of returns will be sensitive to outliers (some sample firms had extreme performance over these 40 days as returns varied from a high of over 200 percent to a low of -44 percent), we estimate a robust regression and a median regression.

Given that the dividend tax cut applied only to individual investors, we have two predictions for the stock price reaction of firms to the dividend tax cut. First, returns should be higher for those firms with higher individual ownership (the group that gains from the reduction in individual tax rates) and that also have historically paid more. This implies that the coefficient on the interaction of individual ownership and the prior year dividends-to-asset ratio should be positive. This simply reflects the fact that, holding payout policy constant, the dividend tax cut is more valuable for firms with higher levels of dividends (as opposed to share repurchases).

Our second prediction is the most important for investigating the role of executive share ownership. To the extent that the markets anticipated that some of the firms that initiated or increased dividends were more likely to reduce share repurchases (less likely to boost total payouts) in 2003 than in prior years, thus possibly increasing the overall tax burden for the typical individual shareholder,32 we would expect a negative coefficient on the interaction of the level of individual ownership and executive holdings. The intuition is as follows: if a firm has a higher level of individual ownership, which leads shareholders to care more about dividend taxes, and also has a higher level of executive ownership, which leads to a greater likelihood of dividend substitution and greater individual tax burden, then relative to other firms there should be a negative stock price reaction. In a sense, this interaction of executive holdings with the share of individual ownership provides a way of quantifying the potential agency issues between management and shareholders. If the tax cut induces executives with wealth tied up in company stock to boost or initiate dividend payments, even though the non-executive individual shareholders with far less concentrated portfolios would still prefer receipt of capital gains via earnings retention or stock buybacks to dividends even after the tax cut, this would be indicative of agency issues. Thus, the more negative is the coefficient on this interaction term, the greater the agency costs.

As shown in table 7, the results are supportive of both hypotheses. Consistent with the first hypothesis, we find that the interaction of a firm's dividend-to-asset ratio in 2002 with the individual investors' share of ownership is positive and significant. It indicates that for a firm with a dividend yield of two percent, a one-standard-deviation increase in individual ownership corresponds to a 1.0 percentage point higher stock return during the eight tax-cut events. These results are consistent with Perez-Gonzalez (2003) who finds that dividend valuation increased when dividends were less tax disadvantaged, but only for firms with large individual shareholders.

We also find evidence supportive of our second hypothesis. Specifically, the coefficient on the interaction of executive stock ownership with the individual ownership share is significant and negative. We find that for firms primarily owned by institutions, the executives' stock holdings do not influence how the market reacted to the tax cut (i.e., the executive ownership coefficient is small in magnitude and insignificant). However, firms with higher individual ownership and high executive ownership actually declined in value. Specifically, for a firm with the average level of individual ownership, a one-standard-deviation increase in executive ownership leads to a 1.7 percentage point lower return.33 This is consistent with the view that the markets anticipated the potential agency conflicts between executives and other individual shareholders. Further, this negative price reaction is suggestive that, at least for some firms, the compensation contract in place for top executives may not lead to optimal payout policy decisions from the shareholders' perspective under a lower dividend-tax regime. The right panel of table 7 repeats these specifications using returns in excess of Fama-French benchmarks and the results are nearly identical.

These results are suggestive of potential agency problems within some firms. Ex post, we found that firms whose executives had large ownership shares were more apt to increase or initiate dividends, often by at least partial substitution with share repurchases. Even after the tax cut, retained earnings and share repurchases, which distribute capital gains, are likely taxed somewhat less heavily than dividends since the gains are taxed on a realization basis. Thus, at least in part, the market seems to have capitalized the likely payout-policy response by firms based on the incentives provided by executives' share ownership.

6. Summary and Conclusions

The 2003 tax cut provides a unique laboratory to test how a large reduction in the individual dividend tax rate influences corporate payout policy. We provide evidence that top executive holdings of company stock significantly influence a firm's choice of payouts. We find that top executive holdings of company stock has a substantial impact on whether a firm increased or initiated dividends in response to the reduction in the tax-cost of paying dividends.

Unlike past studies in this area that identify results off of cross-sectional correlations, the unexpected and exogenous change in the after-tax value of dividends allows us to directly address the usual criticism that a cross-sectional relation between executive holdings and payout policy may simply reflect unobservable characteristics, such as managerial quality or corporate governance, that generate both option compensation and low dividends.

We find that in 2003, especially in the months following the passage of the May tax cut, a firm was much more likely to increase dividends if the executives owned a larger fraction of the outstanding shares. This correlation between executive ownership and payout policy is significantly different in 2003 than in prior years. In contrast, while other factors, such as cash flow, leverage, past firm performance, executive stock option holdings, and institutional ownership are important determinants of dividend policy in general, their effect on dividend policy did not change in 2003. Because only the effect of executive stock holdings changed significantly with the change in tax regime, we interpret this as strong evidence of a tax effect upon payout policy.

Our work also indicates that, at least for dividend initiations, taxes are a factor in the choice of dividends versus share repurchases and that when tax rates are more closely aligned, firms exhibit some substitutability between the two. We also provide evidence that the markets may have at least partially anticipated these effects, leading to differential stock price responses to key events leading up to the passage of the tax cut.

This paper raises a particularly interesting avenue for future research. The main finding of this paper is that personal financial incentives for executives clearly matter for firm payout behavior. This finding is consistent with a standard agency theory perspective that, rather than operating the firm solely in the best interests of shareholders who may still prefer share repurchases or earnings retention to dividends even after the tax cut, managers are inclined to also incorporate their own financial incentives in corporate decisions. The results in this paper, particularly those concerning the stock price reaction to the tax cut, suggest there may be an agency problem between management and outside shareholders that should be considered when structuring management compensation contracts. The relation between firm actions (e.g., payout policy, capital structure, investment decisions, etc.) and the incentives provided by executive holdings to undertake these actions, and whether the compensation package is structured a priori by the firm to encourage these reactions by managers remains an interesting area for further research.

References

Almeida, H., M. Campello, and M. Weisbach, 2004, "The Cash Flow Sensitivity of Cash," Journal of Finance 59, 1777-1804.

Amromin, G., P. Harrison, and S. Sharpe, 2005, "How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?," FEDS Working Paper 2005-61.

Auerbach, A., and K. Hassett, 2005, "The 2003 Dividend Tax Cuts and the Value of the Firm: An Event Study," NBER Working Paper 11449.

Baker, G., and B. Hall, 2004, "CEO Incentives and Firm Size," Journal of Labor Economics 22 (4), 767-798.

Bettis, C., Bizjak, J., and M. Lemmon, 2001, "Managerial Ownership, Incentive Contracting, and the Use of Zero-Cost Collars and Equity Swaps by Corporate Insiders," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36 (3), 345-370.

Blouin, J. L., J. S. Raedy, and D. Shackelford, 2004, "The Initial Impact of the 2003 Reduction in the Dividend Tax Rate," unpublished working paper.

Boyle, G. W., and G. A. Guthrie, 2003, "Investment, Uncertainty and Liquidity," Journal of Finance 58, 2143-2166.

Brav, A., J. Graham, C. Harvey, and R., Michaely, 2005, "Payout Policy in the 21^{st} Century," Journal of Financial Economics 77 (3), 483-527.

Brown, J. R., J. D. Cummins, C. Lewis, and R. Wei, 2004, "An Empirical Analysis of the Economic Impact of Federal Terrorism Reinsurance," The Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 861-898.

Chetty, R., and E. Saez, 2005, "Dividend Taxes and Corporate Behavior: Evidence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut," Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (3), 791-833.

Core, J., and W. Guay, 1999, "The Use of Equity Grants to Manage Optimal Equity Incentive Levels," Journal of Accounting and Economics 28, 151-184.

Cornett, M. M, and H. Tehranian, 1990, "An Examination of the Impact of the Garn-St. Germain Depository Institutions Act of 1982 on Commercial Banks and Savings and Loans," Journal of Finance 45, 95-111.

Cutler, D. M., 1988, "Tax Reform and the Stock Market" An Asset Price Approach," American Economic Review 78, 1107-1117.

DeAngelo, H ., L. DeAngelo and D. Skinner, 2000, "Special Dividends and the Evolution of Dividend Signalling," Journal of Financial Economics 57, 309-354.

Dittmar, A., 2000, "Why do Firms Repurchase Stock," Journal of Business 73, 321-356.

Fama, E., and K. French, 1992, "The Cross Section of Expected Returns," Journal of Finance 47, 427-465.

Fama, E., and K. French, 2001, "Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics of Lower Propensity to Pay?," Journal of Financial Economics 60, 3-44.

Fenn, G., and N. Liang, 2001, "Corporate Payout Policy and Managerial Stock Incentives," Journal of Financial Economics 60, 45-72.

Gillan, S., and L. T. Starks, 1998, "A Survey of Shareholder Activitism Motivation and Empirical Evidences," Contemporary Finance Digest 2 (3), 10-34.

Grullon, G., and R. Michaely, 2002, "Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis," Journal of Finance 57, 1649-1684.

Jagannathan, M., C. Stephens, and M. Weisbach, 2000, "Financial Flexibility and the Choice Between Dividends and Share Repurchases," Journal of Financial Economics 57, 355-384.

James, C., 1983, "An Analysis of Intra-Industry Differences in the Effect of Regulation: The Case of Deposit Rate Ceilings," Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 417-432.

Jensen, M. C., 1986, "Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers," American Economic Review 76 (2), 323-329.

Jolls, C., 1998, "Stock Repurchases and Incentive Compensation," NBER Working Paper 6467.

Julio, B., and D. Ikenberry, 2005, "Reappearing Dividends," forthcoming in Journal of Applied Corporate Finance.

Kahle, K., 2002, "When a Buyback isn't a Buyback: Open-market Repurchases and Employee Options," Journal of Financial Economics 63, 235-261.

Lambert, R., W. Lanen and D. Larcker, 1989, "Executive Stock Option Plans and Corporate Dividend Policy," Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis 24 409-425.

Lintner, J., 1956, "Distributions of Incomes of Corporations Among Dividends, Retained Earnings, and Taxes," American Economic Review, 46, 96-114.

Murphy, Kevin, 1999, Executive Compensation, " In Ashenfelter, O., Card, D., (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3B, North Holland, Amsterdam.

Nam, N., J. Wang, and G. Zhang, 2004, "The Impact of Dividend Tax Cut and Managerial Stock Holdings on Firm's Dividend Policy," Working Paper, Lubin School of Business, Pace University.

Perez-Gonzalez, F., 2003, "Large Shareholders and Dividends: Evidence from U.S. Tax Reforms," Columbia University working paper.

Schumann, L., 1988, "State Regulation of Takeovers and Shareholder Wealth: The Case of New York's 1985 Takeover Statutes," RAND Journal of Economics 19, 557-567.

Shefrin, H. M., and M. Statman, 1984, "Explaining Investor Preference for Cash Dividends," Journal of Financial Economics 13, 253-282.

Weisbenner, S., 2000, "Corporate Share Repurchases in the Mid-1990s: What Role Do Stock Options Play?" Working Paper, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

Table 1: Summary Statistics for Dividend Policy, Stock and Option Holdings, and Firm Characteristics, S&P 1500 Sample

The table provides summary statistics of changes in dividend policy during 2002 and 2003 for the firms in Execucomp (roughly the S&P 1500). A dividend increase is defined as a rise in ordinary dividends per share (adjusted for stock splits), based on dividend announcements in CRSP. The table also provides summary statistics, as of the end of 2002, regarding stock and option holdings of a firm's top five executives and various firm financial characteristics. Unless stated otherwise, variables are measured in percent.


Table 1:
  Mean Median 25^{th} - 75^{th} %
Dividend Policy (2002 & 2003)
Probability Increase Dividends in 2003
28.7 0.0 0 .0 - 100
Dividend Policy (2002 & 2003)
Probability Increase Dividends in 2002
22.0 0.0 0.0 - 0.0
Dividend Policy (2002 & 2003)
Probability Initiate Dividends in 2003
5.9 0.0 0.0 - 0.0
Dividend Policy (2002 & 2003)
Probability Initiate Dividends in 2002
1.2 0.0 0.0 - 0.0
Stock Holdings (end of 2002)
Percent of Shares Held by Top Five Executives
3.8 0.8 0.3 - 3.2
Stock Holdings (end of 2002)
Value of Stock Held by Top Executives ($M)
142.1 11.7 3.3 - 40.0
     
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Options Held by Top Five Executives Normalized by Shares Outstanding
3.2 2.6 1.3 - 4.4
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Market-to-Book Ratio
1.6 1.3 1.1 - 1.8
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Free Cash Flow / Assets
6.3 7.1 2.5 - 11.9
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Cash on Hand / Assets
14.9 7.2 2.3 - 21.9
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Debt / Assets
24.0 22.4 6.1 - 36.0
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Five-Year Stock Return
-1.9 0.8 -10.0 - 9.3
Other Variables (end of 2002)
Monthly Stock Return Volatility

(past 24 months)

14.4 11.9 8.6 - 18.0


Table 2: Regression of Likelihood of Dividend Increase (in percent) on Executive Stock Holdings and Firm Characteristics, Comparison of 2003 with Earlier Years

The table presents linear model (the left panel) and Probit model (the right panel) regressions of whether a firm increases dividends in 2003. A dividend increase is defined as a rise in ordinary dividends per share (adjusted for stock splits) based on dividend announcements in CRSP. Throughout the tables, the dependent variable is measured in percentage points, while the explanatory variables are expressed as raw ratios (i.e., not in percentage points), unless stated otherwise. Thus, the dependent variable in this table takes on values of either 0 (did not increase dividends) or 100 (did increase dividends). The likelihood of a dividend increase is related to the top five executive stock and options (both normalized by total firm shares outstanding) as well as the firm's market-to-book ratio, free cash flow-to-assets (where free cash flow is defined as operating income before depreciation minus capital expenditures), cash on hand-to-assets, debt-to-assets (where debt is long-term debt), past five-year stock return, monthly stock volatility (based on the past 24 months), log of market value, firm age indicator variables (1-5, 6-10, 11-15, 16-20, and 21 or more years), and industry indicator variables. The top five executive stock and option variables are obtained from Execucomp, the firm financial characteristics are obtained from Compustat, and the past five-year stock return and monthly stock volatility are obtained from CRSP. The table presents regressions of whether a firm increases dividends in the 2003 (leftmost column of each panel), the 1993-2002 period pooled (middle column of each panel), and the difference between the coefficients over the two time periods (rightmost column of each panel). Specifically, a regression is estimated across the pooled sample 1993-2003, with an indicator variable for 2003 interacted with all the explanatory variables (interaction terms shown in far right column) to test whether the effect of a variable on the likelihood of a dividend increase is different in 2003 relative to earlier years (i.e., the period 1993-2002). Marginal effects evaluated at the sample mean are presented for the Probit model. The standard errors, given in parentheses, account for heteroskedasticity (i.e., robust standard errors), and, in the pooled regressions, correlation across observations of the same firm over time (i.e., clustering on firm).

Table 2: Regression of Likelihood of Dividend Increase (in percent) on Executive Stock Holdings and Firm Characteristics, Comparison of 2003 with Earlier Years (continued)


Table 2:
  OLS
2003
OLS
1993-2003

Sample Pooled

1993-

2002

OLS
1993-2003

Sample Pooled

2003 relative to 1993-2002
Marginal Effects from Probit Model
2003
Marginal Effects from Probit Model
1993-2003

Sample Pooled


1993-

2002

Marginal Effects from Probit Model
1993-2003

Sample Pooled


2003 relative to 1993-2002
Fraction of Shares Held by

Top Five Executives

54.0 ***

(15.5)

6.3

(8.5)

47.7 ***

(15.3)

57.4 ***

(15.7)

11.2

(9.6)

56.3 ***

(17.3)

Options Held by Top Five Executives Normalized by

Shares Outstanding

-96.0**

(42.4)

-103.0 ***

(25.7)

7.0

(42.4)

-161.9 ***

(57.2)

-171.8 ***

(44.6)

-18.6

(67.3)

Market-to-Book Ratio 0.8

(1.5)

0.1

(0.5)

0.7

(1.4)

-6.1 ***

(1.9)

-2.9 ***

(0.8)

-4.3*

(2.3)

Free Cash Flow / Assets 11.2

(10.7)

22.6 ***

(6.8)

-11.3

(10.2)

107.7 ***

(23.0)

96.0 ***

(10.2)

30.7

(29.4)

Cash on Hand / Assets -7.1

(6.9)

-13.5 ***

(5.2)

6.5

(7.0)

-13.9

(8.8)

-29.3 ***

(8.0)

12.9

(10.4)

Debt / Assets -8.7

(5.6)

-12.4 ***

(4.1)

3.6

(5.7)

-14.5**

(6.8)

-17.7 ***

(5.2)

0.6

(8.2)

Past Five-Year Stock Return 16.8**

(7.4)

15.1 ***

(3.5)

1.7

(7.6)

32.4 ***

(8.9)

38.2 ***

(4.5)^{ }

-0.1

(11.0)

Monthly Stock Volatility -120.6 ***

(16.9)

-121.8 ***

(12.1)

1.1

(18.4)

-184.6 ***

(31.8)

-262.8 ***

(23.7)

45.7

(44.8)

Log (Market Value) 4.2 ***

(0.9)

3.9 ***

(0.6)

0.3

(0.9)

4.3 ***

(0.9)

3.3 ***

(0.7)

1.7

(1.1)

p-value for joint test of significance of non-exec ownership coefficients 0.00 *** 0.00 *** 0.85 0.00 *** 0.00 *** 0.53
Firm Age and Industry Effects? Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R^{2} 0.203 0.219 0.262 0.247
Number of Observations 1,356 12,618 1,356 12,618

 

Table 3: Examination of Timing of Relation Between Executive Ownership and Dividend Increases and Initiations

The table presents linear regressions of whether a firm increases dividends in 2003. A dividend increase is defined as a rise in ordinary dividends per share (adjusted for stock splits) based on dividend announcements in CRSP. These regressions are estimated over two pre-tax cut periods (1993-2002 pooled and 2002), the full 2003 year, the portion of 2003 prior to the signing of the dividend tax cut on May 23, and the portion of 2003 after the tax cut was signed (after May 23). The analysis is done separately for all firms (row 1), firms that did not pay dividends in the prior year and thus for whom a dividend increase represents an initiation (row 2), and firms that paid dividends in the prior year (rows 3 and 4). Throughout the tables, the dependent variable is measured in percentage points, while the explanatory variables are expressed as raw ratios (i.e., not in percentage points), unless stated otherwise. Thus, the dependent variable in this table takes on values of either 0 (did not increase dividends) or 100 (did increase dividends). Only the coefficients on the stock holdings of the top five executives (normalized by total firm shares outstanding) are reported. Other variables included in the regression, but not reported, are the stock options held by top executives, market-to-book ratio, free cash flow-to-assets, cash on hand-to-assets, debt-to-assets, past five-year stock return, monthly stock volatility, log of market value, and firm age and industry indicator variables (as in the table 2 regressions). The standard errors, given in parentheses, account for heteroskedasticity (i.e., robust standard errors), and, in the pooled regressions, correlation across observations of the same firm over time, i.e., clustering on firm.


Table 3:
LHS Variable Pre-2003 Dividend Tax Cut
1993 to 2002

(pooled)

Pre-2003 Dividend Tax Cut
2002
2003
Full Year
2003
Portion Prior

to Tax Cut

Signed May 23

2003
Portion After

Tax Cut

Signed May 23

Probability Increase Dividends 6.3

(8.5)

7.1

(12.0)

54.0 ***

(15.5)

18.0

(12.1)

43.3 ***

(15.0)

Probability Initiate Dividends 6.2

(3.9)

-3.6

(3.2)

37.8**

(15.6)

1.3

(4.2)

37.1**

(15.5)

Probability Increase Dividends given already pay dividends 13.3

(10.1)

36.0

(26.0)

72.6 ***

(22.0)

40.6

(25.3)

49.0*

(28.1)

Probability Increase Dividends at least 25% given already pay dividends 12.9 ***

(5.1)

-1.3

(14.0)

64.9 ***

(22.7)

34.4

(22.5)

37.1*

(22.5)


Table 4: Relation Between Likelihood of Dividend Increases and Initiations (in percent) and Holdings of Various Shareholders, Comparison of 2003 with Earlier Years

The table presents linear regressions of whether a firm increases dividends in the 2003 (leftmost column of each panel), the 1993-2002 period pooled (middle column of each panel), and the difference between the coefficients over the two time periods (rightmost column of each panel). Specifically, a regression is estimated across the pooled sample 1993-2003, with an indicator variable for 2003 interacted with all the explanatory variables (interaction terms shown in far right column) to test whether the effect of a variable on the likelihood of a dividend increase is different in 2003 relative to earlier years (i.e., the period 1993-2002). Regressions are estimated for all firms in the left panel and the subset of firms that did not pay dividends over the previous year in the right panel (for which an increase represents an initiation). A dividend increase is defined as a rise in ordinary dividends per share (adjusted for stock splits) based on dividend announcements in CRSP. Throughout the tables, the dependent variable is measured in percentage points, while the explanatory variables are expressed as raw ratios (i.e., not in percentage points), unless stated otherwise. Thus, the dependent variable in this table takes on values of either 0 (did not increase dividends) or 100 (did increase dividends). Relative to table 2, these specification add the fraction of shares held by individuals directly (outside of the top executives) and by non-mutual fund institutions. Thus, in this case, the omitted category is the fraction of shares held by mutual funds. The institutional ownership data is obtained from CDA Spectrum. Individual ownership is defined as the fraction of shares that remains after accounting for executive and institutional ownership. Only the coefficients on the stock holdings of the top five executives (normalized by total firm shares outstanding) and the ownership of non-executive individuals and non-mutual fund institutions are reported. Other variables included in the regression, but not reported, are the stock options held by top executives, market-to-book ratio, free cash flow-to-assets, cash on hand-to-assets, debt-to-assets, past five-year stock return, monthly stock volatility, log of market value, and firm age and industry indicator variables (as in the table 2 regressions). The standard errors, given in parentheses, account for heteroskedasticity (i.e., robust standard errors), and, in the pooled regressions, correlation across observations of the same firm over time (i.e., clustering on firm).


Table 4:
  All Dividend Increases
2003
All Dividend Increases 1993-2003

Sample Pooled


1993-

2002

All Dividend Increases 1993-2003

Sample Pooled


2003 relative to 1993-2002
Dividend Initiations
2003
Dividend Initiations 1993-2003

Sample Pooled


1993-

2002

Dividend Initiations 1993-2003

Sample Pooled


2003 relative to 1993-2002
Fraction of Shares Held by Top Five Executives 98.2 ***

(20.9)

50.8 ***

(11.8)

47.4**

(20.2)

39.7**

(18.4)

6.3

(4.1)

33.4*

(18.7)

Fraction of Shares Held By Individuals Directly (excluding Top Executives) 59.5 ***

(13.5)

59.4 ***

(7.8)

0.1

(13.3)

3.0

(12.3)

0.9

(1.8)

2.1

(12.2)

Fraction of Shares Held by

Non-Mutual Fund Institutions

74.3 ***

(18.7)

66.2 ***

(10.8)

8.1

(18.3)

12.0

(15.4)

3.2

(2.9)

8.8

(15.3)

Adjusted R^{2} 0.218 0.232 0.066 0.060
Number of Observations 1,245 12,087 605 4,491

 

Table 5: Payout Substitution? Change in Share Repurchases and Total Payouts for Various Firms

The table summarizes payout policy for firms that increase dividends per share, previous non-dividend payers that initiate dividends, and firms that do not increase dividends. Data on dividends and share repurchases paid (and thus total payouts) are obtained from Compustat.


Table 5: S&P 1500 Firms (Execucomp), Likelihood of Payout Policy in percentage points
Sample Repurchased Shares

Last Year?

1993-2002
Repurchased Shares

Last Year?

2002
Repurchased Shares

Last Year?

2003
Decrease Repurchases given Repurchased Last Year

(i.e., RP/ASSET \downarrow )?

1993-2002
Decrease Repurchases given Repurchased Last Year

(i.e., RP/ASSET \downarrow )?

2002
Decrease Repurchases given Repurchased Last Year

(i.e., RP/ASSET \downarrow )?

2003
Increase Total Payouts

(i.e., PAY/ASSET \uparrow )?

1993-2002
Increase Total Payouts

(i.e., PAY/ASSET \uparrow )?

2002
Increase Total Payouts

(i.e., PAY/ASSET \uparrow )?

2003
Firm Increases Dividends

(All Firms)

65 71 67 55 60 64 56 53 52
Firm Initiates Dividends 38 54 68 56 57 78 89 92 66
Firm Does Not Increase Div. 44 51 50 63 58 64 30 37 30
Payout Policy the Year of the Dividend Initiation (in percentage points)
  Dividend / Assets
Mean
Dividend / Assets
25^{th} %
Dividend / Assets
Median
Dividend / Assets
75^{th} %
Change in

(Share Repurchase / Assets)

Mean
Change in

(Share Repurchase / Assets)

25^{th} %
Change in

(Share Repurchase / Assets)

Median
Change in

(Share Repurchase / Assets)

75^{th} %
Change in

(Total Payouts / Assets)

Mean
Change in

(Total Payouts / Assets)

25^{th} %
Change in

(Total Payouts / Assets)

Median
Change in

(Total Payouts / Assets)

75^{th} %
1993-2002 Dividend Initiators 3.1 0.2 0.6 1.3 1.4 0.0 0.0 0.3 4.5 0.2 0.7 2.8
2003 Dividend Initiators 2.2 0.4 0.8 1.5 -1.6 -3.2 -0.1 0.2 0.6 -1.5 0.4 1.8

Bold indicates statistic in earlier period (i.e., 2002 or 1993-2002) is different from comparable 2003 statistic at the 5% level.

Table 6: Amount of Increase in Dividends and Total Payouts in 2003, Tobit Model

The table presents estimated coefficients from a Tobit model for both the amount of the increase in dividends and the amount of the increase in total payouts (dividends plus share repurchases), both normalized by total assets. For firms whose dividends-to-assets or total payouts-to-assets fell, the amount of the increase is set to zero. The left panel focuses on the full sample of firms, while the right panel focuses on the subsample of firms that did not pay dividends in 2002 (and hence an increase in dividends represents a dividend initiation). Data on dividends and share repurchases (and hence total payouts) paid during the year are obtained from Compustat. Regressions also include indicator variables for the age of the firm. Standard errors are given in parentheses.

 

 
  Tobit Model of Increase in Dividends/Assets

and Total Payouts/Assets in 2003

All Firms
Max

(Change in

Div / Assets, 0)

Tobit Model of Increase in Dividends/Assets

and Total Payouts/Assets in 2003

All Firms
Max

(Change in

Total Payout / Assets, 0)

Tobit Model of Increase in Dividends/Assets

and Total Payouts/Assets in 2003

No Dividend in 2002 Firms
Increase in

Div / Assets in 2003

Tobit Model of Increase in Dividends/Assets

and Total Payouts/Assets in 2003

No Dividend in 2002 Firms
Max

(Change in

Total Payout / Assets, 0)

Fraction of Shares Held by Top Five Executives 4.4 ***

(1.4)

1.0

(2.4)

21.4 ***

(6.2)

2.3

(4.3)

Options Held by Top Five Execs Normalized by Shares Outstanding -11.8**

(5.6)

6.6

(8.1)

-42.0

(26.4)

13.2

(13.8)

Market-to-Book Ratio -0.9 ***

(0.2)

-0.1

(0.3)

-3.5 ***

(1.1)

-0.3

(0.6)

Free Cash Flow / Assets 11.7 ***

(2.0)

13.9 ***

(2.8)

44.9 ***

(10.2)

15.4 ***

(4.8)

Cash on Hand / Assets 3.6 ***

(0.9)

4.9 ***

(1.4)

14.3 ***

(3.8)

3.3

(2.4)

Debt / Assets 0.2

(0.7)

-2.7**

(1.2)

0.1

(3.7)

-8.1

(2.3)

Past Five-Year Return -0.6

(1.0)

-1.6

(1.5)

-7.1

(4.7)

-3.8

(2.6)

Monthly Stock Volatility -12.4 ***

(2.7)

-9.0**

(3.7)

-37.5 ***

(12.4)

-12.9**

(6.4)

Log (Market Value) 0.2

(0.1)

0.2

(0.2)

1.5 ***

(0.6)

0.9 ***

(0.3)

Pseudo R^{2} 0.053 0.022 0.118 0.031
Number of Observations 1,319 1,169 683 577

Table 7: Cumulative Stock Return over Announcement of Dividend Tax Cut Proposal by White House, Introduction of Bill in Congress, and Final Package of Tax Cut--Relation with Dividend Payout Policy in 2002, Individual Ownership, and Executive Holdings (returns in percentage points)

The table reports regressions of the compounded stock returns over the eight event windows (40 trading days) surrounding the proposal and passage of the 2003 dividend tax cut upon the stock holdings of the top five executives (normalized by total firm shares outstanding), the stock options held by top executives (normalized by total firm shares outstanding), the share of individual ownership in the firm, and prior firm dividend policy. We focus on eight event windows, each consisting of five trading days (a +/-2 day window around each event), that were first used by Auerbach and Hassett (2005). We report robust regression and median regression results. The left panel reports results using raw returns, while the right panel reports results using excess returns. To calculate the excess returns over the 40 days, we subtract from the compounded raw returns over the eight event windows the appropriate Fama-French (1992) benchmark returns, compounded over these eight event windows, formed according to two size and three book-to-market groupings. All returns are expressed in percentage points. Standard errors are given in parentheses.


 
  Dependent Variable =

Cumulative Return Over the Eight Five-Day Windows

Raw Return
Robust Regression
Dependent Variable =

Cumulative Return Over the Eight Five-Day Windows

Raw Return
Median Regression
Dependent Variable =

Cumulative Return Over the Eight Five-Day Windows

Excess Return Relative to

Fama-French Size and

Book-to-Market Portfolios

Robust Regression
Dependent Variable =

Cumulative Return Over the Eight Five-Day Windows

Excess Return Relative to

Fama-French Size and

Book-to-Market Portfolios

Median Regression
Individual Investors' Share of Ownership 0.9

(3.4)

1.2

(3.7)

0.2

(3.5)

1.2

(3.7

Executive Shares /

Firm Shares

0.1

(7.6)

-3.8

(7.9)

-2.0

(7.7)

-6.1

(7.8)

(Exec Shares / Firm Shares) * Indiv Share -81.4**

(35.6)

-60.4*

(36.4)

-84.4**

(36.1)

-52.7

(35.8)

Executive Options /

Firm Shares

-0.3

(21.7)

5.4

(23.2)

-7.4

(21.9)

-10.2

(22.7)

(Exec Options / Firm Shares) *Indiv Share 6.0

(62.4)

-6.9

(66.8)

-13.1

(63.2)

30.5

(66.1)

Dividend/Asset 2002 -139.4**

(60.2)

-123.7*

(64.9)

-104.9*

(61.0)

-109.3*

(64.4)

Dividend/Asset *

Individual Share

271.7*

(152.4)

230.3

(155.2)

266.8*

(154.7)

259.6*

(154.0)

Constant 7.1 ***

(1.1)

6.9 ***

(1.2)

0.1

(1.1)

-0.3

(1.2)

Adjusted / Pseudo R^{2} NA 0.007 NA 0.007
Number of observations 1,477 1,477 1,477 1,477



Footnotes

***, **, and ^{\ast } denote significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively.Return to Text

1. While Julio and Ikenberry (2005) have argued that the up-tick in dividend activity started before the 2003 tax cut, Chetty and Saez (2005) subsequently showed that this result was due to issues with sample construction, and that the tax cut was indeed responsible for an increase in dividend activity in 2003. Return to Text
2. The 2003 tax change also reduced the top marginal tax rate on ordinary income from 38.6 to 35 percent, and reduced the statutory long-term capital gains tax rate from 20 to 15 percent. Repurchases still are tax-preferred because, though subject to the same rate as dividends, the tax is deferred until the capital gains are realized at the time the shares are sold (and may go untaxed through basis step-up at death). However, this preference shrunk substantially with the dividend tax cut. Return to Text
3. While executives are not allowed to short their own company stock, Bettis, Bizjak, and Lemmon (2001) show that some executives hedge the idiosyncratic risk of their portfolios through collars and equity swaps. Managers also could pre-commit to a regular pattern of stock sales to try to avoid sending a negative signal to the market when their stock is sold. To the extent any of these diversification strategies occur will make it more difficult to find a relation between executive ownership and the likelihood of a dividend increase in 2003. Return to Text
4. The Nam, Wang and Zhang (2004) is much more limited in scope, in that it examines only S&P 1500 firms with ongoing dividend programs and thus misses the important effects of the tax cut on dividend initiations. Return to Text
5. Auerbach and Hassett (2005) and Amromin, Harrison, and Sharpe (2005) find that high dividend-paying stocks earned excess returns of a few percentage points around the period of the tax cut. Neither of these two studies, however, examined the firm-level variation in excess returns. Return to Text
6. In our regressions, we have approximately 1,350 firms represented each year because roughly 350 firms are dropped each year due to missing values for some explanatory variables. Return to Text
7. As we discuss below, our results are robust to the inclusion of special dividends in addition to ordinary dividends. Return to Text
8. We do not examine the dividend tax rate cut in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 for three reasons. First, we lack the extensive data on the stock ownership of top executives during this time period. Second, this act included numerous other changes in the relative tax treatment of corporate and individual income that would make it difficult to isolate the effect of the dividend tax cut. Third, the 1986 Act was the outcome of a much longer political and legislative process, making it less plausible that the 1986 tax cut was a surprise to the market. In addition, the top marginal rate applicable to dividends was cut by the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, but the cut was very small (from 39.6 percent in 2000 to 38.6 percent in 2001, and to 37.6 percent in 2004 if the JGTRRA, which cut the dividend tax rate to 15 percent and is the focus of this study, had not passed in 2003), and likely was not large enough to elicit a noticeable response from firm executives. Return to Text
9. Auerbach and Hassett (2005) provide a very careful chronology of the events leading to the tax cut and confirm that there was very little, if any, information released prior to the announcement of the tax cut. Return to Text
10. Unless stated otherwise, when referring to dividend increases we include both initiations as well as increases for prior dividend payers. In table 3 we will analyze initiations as well as increases for prior dividend payers separately. Return to Text
11. Industry groups are as follows: mining, oil and gas, construction, food, basic materials, biotech/medical, manufacturing, transportation, telecom, utilities, retail/wholesale trade, financial, technology, and other. Return to Text
12. Throughout the tables, our dependent variable is measured in percentage points, while our explanatory variables are expressed as raw ratios (i.e., not in percentage points). Return to Text
13. The first year we can relate a change in dividend payouts to executive holdings at the prior year-end is 1993 because the Execomp database starts in 1992. Return to Text
14. Note that, unlike the linear probability model, the marginal effects of 1993-2002 and 2003 separately need not add up to the marginal effect over the entire 1993-2003 period. This is because in a non-linear model, the marginal effects are evaluated at the sample means, which themselves differ slightly in the different time periods. Return to Text
15. The negative relation with cash on hand likely reflects that firms with greater needs to hold cash balances, because of higher transaction costs or precautionary demands (Boyle and Guthrie, 2003; Almeida, Campello and Weisbach 2004) are less likely to commit to paying or increasing dividends. In addition, firms with greater debt ratios, and likely higher claims from interest expense on their earnings, are less likely to pay dividends as well. Leverage may also substitute for dividends as a way to reduce agency problems (Jensen, 1986). Return to Text
16. As with the results of Table 2, the magnitude of the marginal effect of executive share ownership from a Probit model is nearly identical to that of the linear probability model. Return to Text
17. These coefficient estimates are available from the authors by request. Return to Text
18. While 53.5 percent of prior dividend payers increase ordinary dividends per share in 2003, only 13.8 percent increase them by more than 25% over their prior level. For comparison, in 2002, while 43.3 percent of prior dividend payers increased dividends, only 5.5 percent increasing them by more than 25% over their prior level. Thus, most of the rise in dividend increases among dividend payers following the tax cut seems to be concentrated among the larger increases. Return to Text
19. While not all stocks held by individuals are in taxable accounts (e.g., some stocks are owned through tax deferred accounts such as IRAs), the fraction of direct stock ownership held in taxable accounts is higher than the fraction of mutual fund assets held in taxable accounts. Return to Text
20. In contrast to the results from Table 2 where the omitted group was total non-executive ownership, here the omitted group is mutual funds. As such, the coefficient on executive ownership during the pre tax cut period (1993-2002) changes from 6.3 to 50.8. What matters for our hypothesis, however, is that the difference in the executive ownership coefficient for 2003 vs. earlier years is nearly identical in each specification. Return to Text
21. This ongoing demand for dividends by individuals is consistent with Shefrin and Statman (1984) who argue that individuals may prefer dividends despite their tax disadvantage because it helps them to solve a self-control problem. That is, by committing to consume only out of dividends, investors avoid deciding how many shares to sell and how much to consume, and thus commit themselves not to consume too much. Return to Text
22. Because total options outstanding, and hence the difference between total and top executive option holdings, had to be collected by hand, we collected these data for year-end 2001 and 2002, and related non-executive options, along with other variables, to dividend changes in the next year. Thus, our comparison of 2003 with earlier years is limited to a comparison of 2003 with 2002 when this variable is included in the regression. The coefficient on the variable non-executive options-to-total firm shares outstanding is significantly negative in both years (-36.4 in 2002 and -50.7 in 2003), with the difference in coefficients statistically insignificant. Return to Text
23. In the interest of space, we do not report the coefficients from all the specification checks. These results, and others, are available from the authors upon request. Return to Text
24. This large special dividend by Microsoft does not fall within our sample period. Return to Text
25. We also estimated a specification using another possible definition of a "dividend increase," namely an increase in the amount of dividends paid relative to firm size (e.g., an increase in the dividends-to-assets ratio), and found similar results. For example, the coefficient on executive share ownership is 44.8 in 2003, with a difference of 42.4 between the 2003 coefficient and that from the pre-tax cut period 1993-2002. Return to Text
26. We report results for the Execucomp sample (roughly the S&P 1500). An analysis of all firms in Compsutat yields qualitatively similar results. Return to Text
27. It is possible that an increase in dividends per share need not increase the dividends-to-assets ratio, and thus not increase total payouts. To address this possibility, we also redefined a "dividend increase" as an increase in the amount of dividends paid relative to firm size (i.e., an increase in the dividends-to-assets ratio). With this alternative definition, we find the following patterns in payout policy for those firms that boosted dividends-to-assets: (i) the fraction of dividend increasers in 2003 that had previously repurchased shares (62%) was identical to that of the prior decade; (ii) among those that had repurchased shares in 2002, 65% reduced repurchases in 2003 while only 53% did in the prior decade, a statistically significant difference; (iii) the net result is that 66% of dividend increasers actually increased total payouts in 2003, significantly less than the 73% over the prior pre-tax period. Note that for dividend initiations, the two measures of a "dividend increase" are identical. Return to Text
28. We also compared share repurchases and payouts during the year a firm increased dividends to the firm's average level of dividends and share repurchases over the past three years (as opposed to just the prior year). The results regarding dividend substitution are very similar. For example, only 58% of dividend-initiators in 2003 increased total payouts above their average payout-to-assets ratio over the past three years (79% of dividend-initiators over the period 1993-2002 increased payouts relative to the prior three-year average). Return to Text
29. Some examples include the effect of the 1986 tax reform act (Cutler 1988), financial services deregulation (James, 1983; Cornett and Tehranian, 1990), regulation of the market for corporate takeovers (Schumann 1988), and the passage of the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (Brown, Cummins, Lewis, and Wei 2004). Return to Text
30. More detail on the eight event windows, and how they were independently constructed by the staff of the House Ways and Means Committee, can be found in Auerbach and Hassett's paper. Return to Text
31. By using all eight event windows, we are taking the conservative approach in that we are biasing ourselves against finding a significant effect. This is because a few of the 8 events have been shown by Auerbach and Hassett to be less informative to the market than the others. By restricting ourselves to the more salient news days, our results are even more highly significant. Return to Text
32. As mentioned earlier, the 2003 tax change also reduced the statutory long-term capital gains tax rate from 20 to 15 percent, the same as the new top marginal rate on dividends. Repurchases still are tax-preferred because the tax is deferred until the capital gains are realized at the time the shares are sold (and may go untaxed through basis step-up at death), though the preference shrunk substantially with the dividend tax cut. Return to Text
33. However, the interaction of the individual ownership share with the amount of executive stock options had no effect on the market reaction to the tax cut (recall that the effect of dividends on stock option value did not change with the tax cut, thus whether the executives had a lot of stock options would not lead to a change in payout policy after the tax cut relative to earlier years, as confirmed in our earlier dividend policy regressions). Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. A printable pdf version is available.