The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2007-36 Screen Reader version

Why Do Firms Offer Risky Defined Benefit Pension Plans?

David A. Love*
Paul A. Smith*
David Wilcox*

Keywords: Pensions, risk, compensation, corporate finance

Abstract:

Even risky pension sponsors could offer essentially riskless pension promises by contributing a sufficient level of resources to their pension trust funds and by investing those resources in fixed-income securities designed to deliver their payoffs just as pension obligations are coming due. However, almost no firm has chosen to fund its plan in this manner. We study the optimal funding choice for plan sponsors by developing a simple model of pension financing in which the total compensation offered to workers must clear the labor market. We find that if workers understand the implications of pension risk, they will demand greater compensation for riskier pension promises than for safer ones, all else equal. Indeed, in our model, pension sponsors maximize their value by making their pension promises free of risk. We close by positing some explanations for why no real-world firm follows the prescription of our model.

1 Introduction

In the aggregate, private defined-benefit pension plans in the United States are underfunded by a considerable margin. The Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation, the federal insurer of such plans, puts the aggregate shortfall of assets from liabilities among insured single-employer plans at about $350 billion as of September 30, 2006 (PBGC 2006, p. 8). In addition, the characteristics of the assets that these plans hold are very different from the characteristics of their liabilities. Coronado and Liang (2006) find that the typical pension trust holds 60 percent to 70 percent of its value in equities. In contrast, by at least one definition, liability is fixed and known with certainty in nominal terms.1 These two factors--the substantial shortfall of assets from liabilities and the mismatch between assets and liabilities--imply that private DB plans are a risky proposition for both workers and firms.2

As Bodie (1990) and others have pointed out, even risky firms could greatly reduce the risk of their pension promises by contributing a sufficient level of resources to their pension trust funds and by investing those resources in fixed-income securities designed to deliver their payoffs just as pension obligations are coming due. This strategy would immunize the pension fund from market fluctuations, because stock returns would be irrelevant and interest-rate changes would affect pension assets (through bond values) and liabilities (through the present value of future obligations) at the same time and by the same amounts.3 Despite this possibility, almost all firms choose to make their pension promises risky.4 Thus the question motivating this paper: Is it optimal for firms to introduce more than the minimum amount of risk into their pension promises? In particular, can firms really gain value by making their pension promises risky rather than free of risk? In this paper, we develop a model of pension financing in which the total compensation offered to workers must clear the labor market, an approach that formalizes some of the ideas suggested by Bulow (1982) and Bodie (1988, 1990, inter alia). The firms in our model maximize their value by making their pension promises free of risk.

Many readers will find this conclusion to be highly counterintuitive. How could a firm improve its financial position by offering a riskless pension promise rather than a risky one? Aren't risky promises discounted at higher rates of return than riskless ones, ensuring that the present-discounted value (PDV) of a riskless promise exceeds the PDV of a risky one? By making the pension promise riskless, won't firms therefore be taking on additional cost?

The answer is yes, firms that eliminate the risk from previously risky pension promises will take on additional pension cost. But minimizing pension cost alone is not the appropriate objective for firms to pursue: Firms should aim to minimize the market value of total compensation cost, not pension cost in isolation (holding the real activity of the firm constant). We show that if workers understand the implications of pension risk, they will demand greater compensation for riskier pension promises than for safer ones, all else being equal. Thus while riskier pension promises may reduce pension cost, they do not reduce the total compensation cost of the firms in our model.

One way to see the economic intuition for this result is to think of workers as disadvantaged bondholders of the firm--"bondholders" because they hold promises of future payments just as ordinary bondholders do, but "disadvantaged" because, unlike ordinary bondholders, workers are assumed to be unable to diversify away the company-specific risk to which they are exposed through risky pension promises. In return for the promise of a risky DB pension, workers offer their employers a lower "pric" (in the form of wage concessions) than the employers could obtain from bond-market investors in return for the same promised cash flows. Thus, we generate a violation of the standard Modigliani-Miller result that purely financial operations do not affect the value of the firm: Firms that offer a risky pension plan are committing a form of financial inefficiency because they are obtaining part of their financing on worse-than-market terms. The more they avail themselves of this source of financing, the more they reduce their own value. Taking the risk out of the pension promise eliminates the financial inefficiency because in that case--and that case only--workers are willing to provide financing on terms that are as good as the ones that the firm could obtain from financial markets.

This paper is only a first step because, for the sake of transparency and simplicity, we focus explicitly on a single source of pension risk--the employer's funding (i.e., contribution) decision, abstracting from the portfolio allocation decision. In addition, we suppress a number of important features of the pension landscape, some of which would reinforce the argument in favor of making the pension promise riskless, and some of which would weaken it. One of these factors is the PBGC, which offers insurance against downside risk, and--in return--charges premiums far below the economically fair level. Another factor that we suppress is the tax code, and its associated influence on portfolio allocation. A third factor is the empirical regularity--noted by Bodie (1990), that workers seem to hold a call option on part of the surplus in pension trust funds. The way for firms to minimize the market value of this call option is to eliminate the upside potential associated with the trust fund; this, in turn is accomplished by matching the characteristics of the assets in the trust fund to the characteristics of the plan's liabilities. So again, this consideration strengthens the argument for making the pension promise free of risk. In work in progress, we are extending the model to include the portfolio allocation decision, and to capture some of the additional factors omitted here.

Our paper proceeds as follows: In the next section, we briefly review the literature that has considered whether firms should offer a risky pension promise or one that is free of risk. Then we present a bare-bones model with a consumer that lives for two periods, earning cash wages when young and a pension when old. We find that, in this model, the firm's optimal strategy is to fund the pension promise fully. We also begin the process of exploring the robustness of this result to variations in model specification and calibration. We close by revisiting the question of why no real-world firm follows the prescription of our model.

3 The model

The representative worker in our model lives for two periods. The worker consumes in both periods, and supplies one unit of labor when young. Compensation comes in two forms: wages, denoted by  w, received when the worker is young, and benefits, denoted by  \tilde{b}, received when the worker is old.8 The budget constraint is given by:

\displaystyle c_2=(1+r)(w-c_1)+\tilde{b}    

where  c_1 and  c_2 are first- and second-period consumption, respectively, and  r is a risk-free rate.

The firm that employs the representative worker is at risk of declaring bankruptcy at the end of the first period; let  \pi be the probability that bankruptcy occurs. In general, the probability of bankruptcy is correlated with the state of the macroeconomy and hence with the performance of the risky asset; when times are good and the risky asset enjoys a high return, the probability of bankruptcy presumably is relatively low, on average. To simplify the model, however, we assume that the probability of bankruptcy of the firm we study is uncorrelated with the state of the economy.9

The level of benefits actually received,  \tilde{b}, depends on the level of benefits promised,  b^*; the amount that the firm contributes into the trust fund in the first period,  d; and the stochastic characteristics of bankruptcy. If the firm survives into the second period, the worker receives the full amount of promised benefits. From the worker's perspective, this implies:

\displaystyle \tilde{b}=b^*;    

From the firm's perspective, it implies that if the firm survives and the value of the trust fund falls short of  b^*, the firm must contribute enough to make up for the shortfall in the trust fund. On the other hand, if the value of the trust fund exceeds  b^*, the surplus reverts to shareholders.10 Thus, assuming the firm survives, its compensation costs will consist of  w+d paid in the first period plus
\displaystyle \max \{ b^* - (1 + r)d,\;0\} - \max \{ (1 + r)d - b^* ,\;0\}    

paid in the second period.

On the other hand, if the firm declares bankruptcy at the end of the first period, the worker receives whichever is the lesser of the promised benefit and the proceeds of the trust fund:

\displaystyle \tilde{b} = \min [b^* ,\;\;(1 + r)d]    

In this case, the firm's compensation costs are still reduced by any surplus in the trust fund over promised benefits; but a consequence of declaring bankruptcy is that the firm escapes responsibility for making up any shortfall in trust-fund assets. Thus, when the firm goes bankrupt in the second period, its total compensation costs consist of  w+d paid in the first period minus
\displaystyle \max \{ (1 + r)d - b^*,\;0\}    

paid in the second period.

Note that even though, in this simplified version of the model, the firm is compelled to invest the trust fund entirely in the risk-free asset, the pension benefit is certain only if the firm contributes enough to the pension trust in the first period to fully prefund the pension liability at the risk-free rate (  d \ge b^* /(1 + r)). If the firm contributes less than enough to fund the promised pension benefit at the risk-free rate, the benefit is at risk because the firm might declare bankruptcy and therefore fail to top up the pension trust in the second period.

Let the period utility function be denoted by  u(.). Expected lifetime utility is given by:

\displaystyle u\left( {c_1 } \right) + \left( {\frac{1}{{1 + \delta }}} \right)E\;u\left( {c_2 } \right) (1)

where  \delta is the subjective rate of discount.

The worker chooses  c_1 and  c_2 to maximize expected utility. The first-order conditions for consumption imply:

\displaystyle u'(c_1 ) = \left( {\frac{{1 + r}}{{1 + \delta }}} \right)E\;u'(c_2 ) (2)

A critical assumption is that the labor market is perfectly competitive and that workers fully understand the implications of the risk embedded in the promised pension benefit for their expected utility. As a result of that understanding, firms are unable to employ any workers unless the compensation package they offer provides the market-clearing level of expected utility.

The firm minimizes the market value of compensation. The firm's choice variables are the wage paid in the first period, the promised benefit paid in the second period, and the contribution into the trust fund in the first period.

\begin{displaymath}\begin{array}{l} \mathop {\min }\limits_{w,\;b^* ,\;d} \;w + d - PDV(\max \{ (1 + r)d - b^* ,\;0\} \left\vert {survival} \right.) \quad \quad \quad \quad \;\;\; + PDV(\max \{ b^* - (1 + r)d,\;0\} \left\vert {survival} \right.) \quad \quad \quad \quad \;\;\; - PDV(\max \{ (1 + r)d - b^* ,\;0\} \left\vert {bankruptcy} \right.) \end{array}\end{displaymath} (3)

The expression can be simplified by noting that the trust-fund surplus, if any, reverts to the plan sponsor regardless of whether the firm declares bankruptcy. Thus, the cost minimization problem can be stated as:
\begin{displaymath}\begin{array}{l} \mathop {\min }\limits_{w,\;b^* ,\;d} \;w + d - PDV(\max \{ (1 + r)d - b^* ,\;0\} ) \quad \quad \quad \quad \;\;\; + PDV(\max \{ b^* - (1 + r)d,\;0\} \left\vert {survival} \right.) \end{array}\end{displaymath} (4)

Because the cash flow associated with the first maximum term is known with certainty once the firm chooses  b^* and  d, it can be discounted at the risk-free rate, and the term can be simplified as follows:

\displaystyle PDV(\max \{ (1 + r)d - b^* ,\;0\} )\; = \left\{ {\begin{array}{lll} d - \frac{b^* }{1 + r}&\text{if} & d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} \ge 0 \ 0 & \text{if} & d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} < 0 \ \end{array}} \right.
The valuation of the second maximum term is more complicated because it is a claim that is exercised only when the firm survives into the second period; that is, it does not have the usual structure of a put option. Nonetheless, we can value it using a standard binomial approach.11 As we demonstrate in the appendix, we find:
\displaystyle PDV(\max \{ b^* - (1 + r)d,\;0\} \left\vert {survival} \right.) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{lll} 0&\text{if}&d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} \ge 0 (1 - \pi )\left( {\frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} - d} \right)&\text{if}&d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} < 0 \end{array}} \right. (5)

Collecting terms, we have:
\displaystyle \mathop {\min }\limits_{w,\;b^* ,\;d} \left\{ {\begin{array}{lll} w + \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} & \text{if}&d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} \ge 0 w + d + (1 - \pi )\left( {\frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} - d} \right)&\text{if}&d - \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} < 0 \end{array}} \right. (6)

Note that the direct incentive to the firm, ignoring any adjustment in the compensation demands of the worker, is to minimize the prefunding of the pension obligation by setting  d as low as possible. We shall see, however, that the response from the worker is so strong as to overwhelm these direct effects.

The firm conducts this cost minimization subject to the constraint that the compensation it pays must provide the market-clearing level of utility.12 The firm also assumes that the worker arranges consumption in the optimal manner between the first and second period, and that the budget constraint is binding. For convenience, we record these constraints here:

Minimum utility:

\displaystyle u\left( {c_1 } \right) + \left( {\frac{1}{{1 + \delta }}} \right)E\;u\left( {c_2 } \right) = \underbar{u}

Optimal saving/consumption decision:

\displaystyle u'(c_1 ) = E\left[ {\frac{{(1 + r)}}{{1 + \delta }}} \right]\;u'(c_2 )

Budget constraint:

\displaystyle c_2=(1+r)(w-c_1)+\tilde{b}

4 Results

We find that the firm minimizes its total compensation cost by contributing at least the full amount of the promised benefit in the first period,  d \ge b^* /(1 + r). In this case, the firm's minimized cost is given by:

\displaystyle w + \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}}

We demonstrate this result both numerically and analytically. To show the result numerically, we implement and solve a simple numerical model. In this model, utility exhibits exhibit constant relative risk aversion and the subjective rate of discount is assumed to be equal to the interest rate. To solve the model, we first compute the level of utility associated with an initial set of compensation parameters  w,  d, and  b^* and then search for the combination of  w and  d that minimizes costs for a given pension obligation  b^* and subject to the constraint that utility equals  \underbar{u}. We solve the model for both plausible and extreme specifications of risk aversion and the risk-free return,13 and with the exception of linear utility, all of our specifications produce the same result: The firm optimally selects  d \ge b^* /(1 + r).

We can also demonstrate the result analytically. If the firm makes the pension benefit risky, the worker will receive (in present-value terms)  b^* /(1 + r) with probability  1-\pi and  d with probability  \pi. Of course, this is an inferior offer from the worker's perspective relative to receiving  b^* /(1 + r) with certainty, and the worker will demand to be compensated for that loss. Does any level of compensation exist that both (a) the firm would be willing to pay in return for being allowed to make the pension promise risky, and (b) the worker would see as sufficiently generous as to rationalize accepting a risky promise rather than a risk-free one? At most, the firm would be willing to pay  \pi (b^* /(1 + r) - d) because that is the market value of the direct financial benefit to the firm from making the benefit risky rather than risk-free (as can be seen from equation (6)). To see whether the firm could ever get workers to accept a risky benefit, consider the extreme case in which the firm transfers all of that value back to workers with certainty, in return for being allowed to make the pension promise risky. In that case, the payments to the worker would have the following structure:  \pi \left( {b^* /(1 + r) - d} \right) with certainty, plus  b^* /(1 + r) when the firm does not declare bankruptcy--that is, in  100(1-\pi percent of the outcomes in the second period, and  d in the other  100\pi percent of the outcomes. From the perspective of the worker, the deficiency of this even this offer--the most generous one the firm would be willing to make--is clear: Even with the greatest compensation the firm would be willing to make, the expected value of the payment to the worker is only  b^* /(1 + r) ; but the payment under this risky approach has positive variance, a characteristic that makes the proposition strictly inferior to receiving  b^* /(1 + r) for sure. In other words, the firm is offering the worker a lottery that has an expected value of zero. A straightforward application of Jensen's inequality demonstrates that as long as utility is strictly concave, this lottery must decrease utility.14 To make the worker indifferent between this lottery and a fully funded pension with  d = b^* /(1 + r), the firm would therefore have to increase compensation by more than  \pi \left( {b^* /(1 + r) - d} \right), the value of the cost reduction. We conclude that the firm cannot reduce total costs by underfunding its pension.

The analytical and numerical results follow inevitably from the curvature of the utility function and from the fact that the worker is unable to diversify away the idiosyncratic risks associated with bankruptcy. The concavity of utility implies that workers are risk averse, and the inability to diversify away the idiosyncratic risk means that the worker will demand a wage premium in excess of what would be required by participants in the bond market who can, by hypothesis, diversify away all idiosyncratic risk. Thus, the most efficient funding strategy for the firm must be to contribute the full present discounted value of promised benefits.

5 Interpretation

Our model provides a clear result that firms minimize their costs when they fully fund their pension promise (and preliminary work underway suggests an equally clear result that the cost-minimizing investment strategy is an all-bond portfolio). While these results may be consistent with some of the prior literature, they are unquestionably at odds with the current practice of private DB funds. This gap raises the question of what elements of reality are missing from our model. In this section we consider a few of the leading possibilities.

The frictions we examine can be summarized by a simple taxonomy: one or more of the key players in the model (employees, employers, shareholders, or taxpayers) face informational or other barriers that prevent the equilibrium result from obtaining. We examine these possibilities one at a time.

Employees. A key assumption of our model is that employees fully understand and value the effects of the risk characteristics of the pension plan on their own utility. If informational costs or other frictions prevent workers from demanding additional compensation when the risk of their DB promise goes up, then our result will not hold. Prior to the recent spate of DB terminations and freezes, plan failures were quite rare, so it is plausible that many workers were not accustomed to thinking of a pension promise as a risky asset.15

An additional possibility is that employees understand but do not value the pension risk in the way that we model. For example, perhaps workers are indifferent toward a risky pension promise because they are also shareholders and they feel that whatever is good for the company is good for them (despite the undiversifiable risk they face from the firm's fortunes).16

Employers. Even if employees understand and value the risk they face from their pension promise, the mechanism may break down if employers face institutional rigidities or other considerations in managing their pension funds. For example, debt instruments do not go out as many years into the future as pension liabilities do, making it impossible to literally immunize all pension liabilities. These rigidities may prevent firms from offering risk-free pension promises even when it is in their long-term interest to do so.17 Over time, firms might offer more debt at very long maturities if they perceived the market as demanding it.

Shareholders. Another key assumption in the model is that firms are minimizing costs in order to maximize shareholder value. If informational costs prevent shareholders from properly assessing the risk of the pension promise (and hence the total economic costs facing the firm), then again the mechanism cam break down and the result may not hold. The most likely margin for this scenario to take place in reality is related to the arcane and difficult set of accounting rules that apply to pension obligations. As we noted in the introduction, current accounting rules allow firms to book expected pension fund earnings as income, while smoothing any discrepancy between expected and actual earnings over five years. This treatment effectively allows firms to book the equity premium as an asset while displaying only a fraction of the associated variance in its reported earnings, providing an incentive to invest the pension fund significantly in risky assets. While market values of pension assets and liabilities are reported in footnotes, Coronado and Sharpe (2003) show that investors appear to be fooled by the balance sheet and income statements and to factor in only a portion of the detail provided in the footnotes. The Financial Accounting Standards Board is currently undertaking a long-term project to revisit pension accounting, so this informational friction may be reduced in the relatively near future.

Taxpayers. Finally, an additional breakdown of the model can occur through the last key economic player, which is the taxpayer. Our current model provides no role for taxpayers because there is no pension insurance. Our result would disappear if employees were fully insured against the loss of benefits in the event of bankruptcy, because in that case, worker compensation would not depend on the firm's pension funding policy and the firm would be either indifferent over funding strategies (if PBGC premiums were economically fair) or would strictly prefer a risky funding strategy (if PBGC premiums were less than economically fair). In reality, the PBGC does not fully insure pension benefits (giving workers an incentive to monitor funding strategies), but their premiums are not fairly priced, both because they are too low in general (CBO, 2005), and because they do not depend on the risk of the pension promise.18 In principle, the mispricing could be severe enough to cause the firm in our model to prefer a risky pension promise--despite the surcharge assessed by workers--because some of the risk is shared with taxpayers.

6 Conclusion

It has long been recognized that underfunded pensions allow firms to shed cost in times of bankruptcy. At first blush, this form of implicit insurance seems to raise the possibility of moral hazard, with firms maximizing pension risk at the employees' expense. In the model we present here, the firm's optimal pension funding strategy is not to shift pension risk to employees, but rather to structure the pension fund so that it will deliver promised benefits in all states of the world. Our argument relies entirely on the principle that workers will demand to receive sufficient total compensation to allow them to achieve a market-clearing level of utility. In our model, risk-averse workers faced with a risky pension will bargain for a wage increase that ends up costing the firm more than the reduction in the market value of pension costs due to underfunding.

In work underway, we are extending our model to generalize the asset-pricing assumptions we use here, incorporate a portfolio-allocation decision by the pension fund, and allow additional richness such as mispriced PBGC insurance. In addition, we seek to explore conditions under which risky pensions could be part of an equilibrium compensation package.


Bibliography

Bader, Lawrence
"The Case against Stock in Corporate Pension Funds," Pension Section News (Society of Actuaries), 2003, pp. 17-19.
Black, Fischer
"The Tax Conequences of Long-Run Pension Policy," Financial Analysts Journal, 1980, 36, 21-29.
Bodie, Zvi
"Pension Fund Investment Policy," NBER Working Paper No. 2752, 1988.
_________
"The ABO, the PBO, and Pension Investment Policy," Financial Analysts Journal, 1990, 41, 10-16.
Bulow, Jeremy
"What are Corporate Pension Liabilities?," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1982, 97, 435-452.
CBO
"The Risk Exposure of the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporations," 2005. Congressional Budget Office.
Coronado, Julia and Nellie Liang
"The Influence of PBGC Insurance on Pension Fund Finances," in David Blitzstein, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Stephen P. Utkus, eds., Restructuring Retirement Risks, New York: Oxford University Press Inc., 2006, pp. 88-108.
_________ and Steven A. Sharpe
"Did Pension Plan Accounting Contribute to a Stock Market Bubble?," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2003, 1, 323-359.
Gold, Jeremy and Nick Hudson
"Creating Value in Pension Plans (or, Gentlemen Prefer Bonds)," Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 2003, 15, 51-57.
Harrison, J. and William Sharpe
"Optimal Funding and Asset Allocation Rules for Defined Benefit Pension Plans," in Zvi Bodie and John Shoven, eds., Financial Aspects of the U.S. Pension System, University of Chicago Press, 1983, pp. 92-106.
John, Cliff Speed Ralfe and Jon Palin
"Pensions and Capital Structure: Why Hold Equities in the Pension Fund?," North American Actuarial Journal, 2004, 8, 103-113.
Kimball, Miles
"Precautionary Saving in the Small and in the Large," Econometrica, 1990, 58 (1), 53-73.
Lucas, Deborah and Stephen Zeldes
"Valuing and Hedging Defined Benefit Pension Obligations--The Role of Stocks Revisited," 2006. Working Paper, Northwestern University.
PBGC
"PBGC's Guarantee Limits: An Analysis of Benefits Received by Participants in Selected PBGC-Trusteed Plans," Pension Insurance Data Book 1999, 2000. http://www.pbgc.gov/docs/1999databook.pdf.
_________
Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation Annual Management Report, Fiscal Year 2006,
http://www.pbgc.gov/docs/PBGCAMR.pdf, 2006.
Pennacchi, George
"Deposit Insurance, Bank Regulation, and Financial System Risks," Journal of Monetary Economics, 2006, 53 (1), 1-30.
Rauh, Joshua
"Risk Shifting versus Risk Management: Investment Policy in Corporate Pension Plans," 2006. Working Paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago.
Sharpe, William
"Corporate Funding Policy," Journal of Financial Economics, 1976, 3, 183-193.
Tepper, Irwin
"Taxation and Corporate Pension Policy," Journal of Finance, 1981, 36 (1), 1-13.
Treynor, Jack
"The Principles of Corporate Pension Finance," Journal of Finance, 1977, 32 (2), 627-638.
Walsh, Mary Williams
"How Wall Street Wrecked United's Pension," The New York Times, 2005. Section 3 (Sunday Business), page 1.
Wilcox, David
"Reforming the Defined-Benefit Pension System," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2006, 1, 235-304.


Appendix

The value of the pension put can be calculated using standard binomial methods. To price the option, it turns out to be helpful to distinguish between two regimes: one where the firm contributes an amount to the pension fund sufficient to guarantee promised benefits in all states, and one where the pension fund will always fall short of promised benefits if the firm goes bankrupt. In the first case, the value of the pension put is simply 0 since the contingent liability does not alter the firm's costs. In this case, total compensation costs are simply given by

\displaystyle w + \frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}}.
The second regime, where  b^* - (1 + r)d > 0, is more interesting. In this case, the firm only makes up for the pension shortfall when it is solvent. The firm's obligation is
\begin{displaymath} \begin{array}{ll} b^* - (1 + r)d > 0 & \text{if the firm is solvent} \ 0 & \text{if the firm goes bankrupt} \ \end{array}\end{displaymath}
To keep things simple, we assume that the firm has debt outstanding with return denoted by  \tilde r_d . Further, we assume that  \tilde r_d can take on two values:  r_d^h and  r_d^l , with  r_d^l < r_d^h . Given two payoffs (given above) and two assets (own-firm debt and the risk-free asset), we can solve for the replicating portfolio that generates the payoffs in all states of nature. The portfolio amounts  \omega _1 and  \omega _2 can be found by solving the following equation.
\displaystyle \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {b^* - (1 + r)d} \ 0 \ \end{array}} \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {1 + r} & {1 + r_d^h } \ {1 + r} & {1 + r_d^l } \ \end{array}} \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\omega _1 } \ {\omega _2 } \ \end{array}} \right]
The replicating portfolio amounts are given by
\displaystyle \omega _1 = \frac{1}{{1 + r}}\left( {\frac{{1 + r_d^l }}{{r_d^l - r_d^h }}} \right)\left( {b^* - (1 + r)d} \right)
\displaystyle \omega _2 = - \frac{1}{{1 + r}}\left( {\frac{{1 + r}}{{r_d^l - r_d^h }}} \right)\left( {b^* - (1 + r)d} \right)
The value of the portfolio can be found by summing  \omega _1 and  \omega _2 :
\displaystyle \frac{1}{{1 + r}}\left( {\frac{{r - r_d^l }}{{r_d^h - r_d^l }}} \right)\left( {b^* - (1 + r)d} \right)
The ratio  \left( {r - r_d^l } \right)/\left( {r_d^h - r_d^l } \right) can be interpreted as the risk-neutral probability associated with an "up" movement in the own-firm debt return. As a simplification, we assume that own-firm debt is uncorrelated with the market return and in expectation earns zero excess returns over the risk-free rate. According to the standard CAPM formula,
\displaystyle \tilde r_d - r = \beta \left( {\tilde r - r} \right) + \varepsilon _d,
where  \tilde{r} is the market rate of return,  \beta is the beta coefficient (which is zero by assumption), and  \varepsilon _d is assumed to be a mean-zero error term.

We assume that own-firm debt pays  r_d^h if the firm remains solvent and  r_d^l if the firm goes bankrupt. The mean-zero error term can therefore take on the following two values. The mean-zero error term can therefore take on the following two values.

\displaystyle \varepsilon _d = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} \varepsilon _d^h & \text{if the firm remains solvent} \ \varepsilon _d^l & \text{if the firm enters bankruptcy} \ \end{array}} \right.
Given a probability of bankruptcy of  \pi and our assumption that  \varepsilon _d has a mean of zero, the expected value of the shock is given by
\displaystyle (1 - \pi )\varepsilon _d^h + \pi \varepsilon _d^l = 0
Substituting  r_d^h = r + \varepsilon _d^h and  r_d^l = r + \varepsilon _d^l into  \left( {r - r_d^l } \right)/\left( {r_d^h - r_d^l } \right) and rearranging, we find
\displaystyle \frac{{r - r_d^l }}{{r_d^h - r_d^l }} = \pi
The value of the pension put in the underfunding regime is therefore given by
\displaystyle \pi \left( {\frac{{b^* }}{{1 + r}} - d} \right),
which added to  w + b^* /(1 + r) yields the result in equation (5) in the text.


Footnotes

* Dept. of Economics, Williams College, Williamstown, MA 01267, [email protected] Return to Text
* Federal Reserve Board, 20th and C St., NW, Washington, DC 20551, [email protected] Return to Text
* Federal Reserve Board, 20th and C St., NW, Washington, DC 20551, [email protected]. We are grateful to Sean Campbell and Mike Gibson for helpful conversations. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily shared by the Board of Governors or the other members of the staff of the Federal Reserve System. Return to Text
1. The definition of liability that we have in mind here is known as the Accumulated Benefit Obligation, or ABO. Return to Text
2. Another key ingredient in the mix is the fact that the PBGC insurance is subject to certain limitations; as a result, workers bear some risk even with the Federal backstop. See PBGC (2000) for a helpful description and analysis of these benefit limitations. Return to Text
3. As a practical matter, firms could not literally eliminate the risk in their pension promises because those promises extend 50 years or more into the future--much further than the current reach of fixed-income markets with reasonable liquidity. Even so, it seems clear that firms could come much closer to immunizing their liabilities if they wanted to. Return to Text
4. We are aware of only one firm in the United States having ever made its pension promises close to risk-free: According to Walsh (2005), United Airlines invested its pension trust entirely in fixed-income securities designed to immunize its pension obligations until a change in policy occurred in 1987. In England, Boots Pharmaceutical also reportedly held its pension trust entirely in fixed-income securities from 2001 to 2004 (Ralfe, 2004), but has since partially backed away from that position. Return to Text
5. This framework ignores the PBGC, which covers unfunded benefits in the event of bankruptcy. In a framework that includes the PBGC, the firm can put its unfunded obligations to the PBGC (rather than to employees). However, the value of the put option to the PBGC is reduced by the premiums that firms must pay to the PBGC while the plan is healthy. If the premiums are fairly priced, the value of the put is reduced to zero; while if the insurance is under-priced, the put option retains some value. Return to Text
6. Just as employees must receive additional compensation to remain indifferent to larger values of the firm's pension put, they presumably value the call option on the trust fund surplus. If employees were risk neutral, they would value the increased call just enough to accept lower compensation that would leave the firm in a financial position that is neither better nor worse. But if utility is concave, workers will presumably value the call option by less than the market value loss to the firm. Return to Text
7. Future work will extend the model to include the investment decision. Return to Text
8. Throughout, tildes denote variables that are random from the perspective of the first period. Return to Text
9. We believe that the central result in this paper is not sensitive to this simplification. Return to Text
10. Literally speaking, the surplus value could remain in the trust fund for a time, and be recouped by shareholders over time in the form of reduced contributions into the trust fund. Return to Text
11. For an example of a similar application of this method, see Pennacchi (2006), pages 16 and following. Return to Text
12. This is a labor-market equilibrium constraint. One way to think about this is to imagine that workers compare the utility of risky compensation offers to a reference level of utility from a risk-free compensation package. Thus, a risk-averse worker would prefer a risk-free compensation package to a risky one that provides the same expected value. Return to Text
13. We solved the model for CRRA coefficients between 0 and 30, and for risk-free returns between 0 and 300 percent. Return to Text
14. If  u'(.) is convex, which corresponds to Kimball's (1990) notion of "prudence,"then Jensen's inequality implies that a mean-preserving spread of pension benefits must increase the right-hand side of the consumer's Euler condition, given by equation (2). First-period consumption must fall to rebalance the equation, with the result that the marginal utility of consumption will be higher in both periods relative to the case of a certain pension benefit. Since utility in each period is strictly increasing, expected lifetime utility must be lower in the presence of the lottery. Return to Text
15. When plan failures did occur, they were mostly in large industrial sectors such as steel and airlines, in which labor markets were dominated by union negotiations. In this context, negotiations sometimes involved the workers' accepting current wage concessions in exchange for (clearly risky) future pension increases--an environment in which workers in struggling industries were essentially forced by structural forces in the economy to accept lower total compensation. Return to Text
16. This situation would be somewhat analogous to 401(k) participants who hold large shares of their retirement accounts in company stock, against the advice of most financial advisors. Return to Text
17. Indeed the lack of long-dated fixed-income securities was a key reason cited by Boots for its retreat from an all-bond portfolio in 2004. Return to Text
18. The premium can increase with underfunding, but does not vary according to the financial health of the firm or the extent to which the assets of the trust fund have been invested to immunize the risk of the liabilities. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text