Abstract:
Leveraged and inverse exchange-traded funds (ETFs) seek to track a multiple of the performance of an underlying index, commodity, currency, or some other benchmark over a specified time frame, which is usually one day. These products have been heavily criticized based on the belief that they
exacerbate volatility in financial markets. Commentators have referred to them as "weapons of mass destruction" and claim that they pose "serious threats to market stability" because they "have turned the market into a casino on steroids."1 Others have claimed that leveraged ETFs "could send volatility through the roof, and prices through the floor[.]"2 It appears as though policy makers are also concerned about these products, as the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) has issued a moratorium on approving exemptive requests for new leveraged and inverse ETFs.3
The basis of the commentators' concerns seems to be a common perception that leveraged and inverse ETFs must rebalance their portfolios in the same direction as the contemporaneous return on their underlying assets in order to maintain a constant leverage ratio. Conventional thinking suggests that
by purchasing assets following positive returns and selling assets following negative returns, these types of financial products exert additional upward price pressure on the underlying assets following positive returns and additional downward pressure following negative returns (see, e.g.,
Cheng & Madhavan (2009), Bai et al. (2014), Tuzun (2014), and Shum et al. (2014)). However, such reasoning is incomplete because it overlooks the effects of capital
flows.
We demonstrate theoretically that capital flows can either increase or decrease ETF rebalancing demand because flows alter the size of an ETF, which in turn affects the amount of additional leverage the ETF requires to maintain its target leverage ratio. More specifically, capital flows reduce
rebalancing when the flows offset the change in the ETF's assets under management (AUM) that arises from the one-day return on the ETF's underlying portfolio, but flows intensify rebalancing when they occur in the opposite direction. From a theoretical perspective, then, capital flows can either
increase or decrease the potential for these types of products to amplify volatility.4
Empirically, we find that capital flows diminish the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility. Using a sample of large U.S. equity-based ETFs, we find that capital flows occur frequently and tend to offset the need for ETFs to rebalance their portfolios. Furthermore, the
effect of flows on ETF rebalancing demand is strongest when returns are large in magnitude, which is important because ETFs would presumably be most prone to amplify market movements in these cases.
Because ETF rebalancing is likely to have the greatest effect on volatility when the magnitudes of the underlying returns are large, we partition the data according to the size of the daily return on the underlying assets and analyze the relations between returns, capital flows, and ETF rebalancing
demand. When returns are large in magnitude, the correlations between capital flows and returns suggest that flows tend to mitigate ETF rebalancing demand. Moreover, estimates from ordinary least squares regressions over the quintiles of returns indicate that, when returns are large in magnitude,
the returns on the underlying assets should exert much less influence over ETF rebalancing demand than previously thought. By some estimates, returns generate up to 74% less rebalancing by leveraged and inverse ETFs once capital flows are taken into account. As a consequence, the potential for
these types of products to exacerbate volatility should be much lower than many claim.
We also examine the relations between returns, capital flows, and ETF rebalancing demand over different parts of the distributions of capital flows and rebalancing demand. When capital flows occur, the correlations between flows and returns suggest that both capital inflows and outflows tend to
mitigate the need for ETFs to rebalance. Furthermore, estimates from quantile regressions over different percentiles of the rebalancing-demand distribution indicate that, when rebalancing demand is strongest, the relation between returns and rebalancing demand is much weaker than it would otherwise
be in the absence of capital flows. In some cases, returns wield up to 61% less influence over ETF rebalancing demand after accounting for capital flows.
The effects of capital flows appear to be stronger for ETFs with higher leverage ratios. This is noteworthy because ETFs with higher leverage ratios are more prone to exacerbate volatility than those with lower leverage ratios. For ETFs with a leverage ratio of -1 , our evidence suggests that capital flows may aggravate rather than mitigate the potential to amplify volatility. However, these ETFs constitute the smallest segment of our sample, and capital flows seem to have only a
small effect on their rebalancing demand.
While our results indicate that capital flows tend to mitigate the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility, capital flows could be impeded by market frictions, e.g., transaction costs or creation unit constraints. To better understand how market frictions might affect the
impact of capital flows on ETF rebalancing, we conduct a numerical simulation that incorporates transaction costs for ETF investors. We find that frictions can considerably reduce the frequency of capital flows. Furthermore, we find that capital flows can aggravate the potential for ETFs to amplify
market movements when frictions are large, even though flows reduce rebalancing demand when frictions are small. This is due to the fact that large frictions can have a substantial effect on the size of an ETF because the size is partially determined by capital flows, and the potential to
exacerbate volatility is greater when frictions give rise to a larger ETF.
Finally, we show theoretically that, in the absence of frictions, leveraged and inverse ETFs never need to rebalance their portfolios if investors aim to track a multiple of the underlying return over a relatively long horizon by investing in an ETF. Such an objective could naturally arise from
investors such as market makers or other intermediaries using leveraged and inverse ETFs to hedge their exposures over a horizon longer than a day. Because rebalancing by an ETF alters investors' exposures to the underlying assets, investors must rebalance their own portfolios by trading shares of
the ETF to maintain their desired exposures to the underlying assets.5 Capital flows arising from such rebalancing by investors completely eliminate the
potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility in the limit because they drive the ETFs' leverage ratios back to target levels.
We are not the first to examine the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility, though, to our knowledge, we are the first to consider the effects of capital flows. A handful of researchers have attempted to assess whether leveraged and inverse ETFs amplify volatility in
practice by examining the relation between intra-day returns and end-of-day volatility (see, e.g., Bai et al. (2014), Trainor (2010), Tuzun (2014), and Shum et al. (2014)). None
of these analyses, however, use actual data on ETF holdings or rebalancing activity to estimate the impact of ETFs on volatility. Instead, many of these studies rely on an equation derived by Cheng & Madhavan (2009) to calculate "hypothetical" rebalancing by
ETFs, and they do not take into account the effect of capital flows. As our current work demonstrates, capital flows are an important factor to consider when assessing the impact of rebalancing by ETFs on volatility. In our opinion, therefore, the ultimate question of whether leveraged and inverse
ETFs exacerbate volatility in practice remains unresolved.
Our paper is also related to the literature that examines the performance of leveraged ETFs (see, e.g., Avellaneda & Zhang (2010), Charupat & Miu (2011), and Tang & Xu (2013)) and the impact
of the ETF arbitrage process on the volatility of underlying assets (Ben-David et al. (2014)) and the return co-movement of underlying assets (Da & Shive (2013)). More generally, our paper contributes to the literature that
analyzes capital flows in investment companies. In contrast to Coval & Stafford (2007), who find that capital flows increase institutional price pressure stemming from mutual funds during periods of financial distress, we find that capital flows tend to
decrease institutional price pressure originating from leveraged and inverse ETFs. This is due to the fact that mutual fund flows are related to performance (see, e.g., Sirri & Tufano (1998)), whereas capital flows for leveraged and inverse ETFs are related to
changes in leverage.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. We first demonstrate theoretically in Section 2 that capital flows can either mitigate or aggravate the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility. We then show empirically that capital flows tend to
mitigate the potential for these products to amplify volatility in practice in Section 3. Next, we discuss rationales for capital flows in Section 4 and show that rebalancing by investors can, in the limiting case, completely eliminate the
need for ETFs to rebalance. We then numerically evaluate the effects of market frictions in Section 5. Last, Section 6 concludes.
Assume there exists an index or other type of asset that realizes an exogenous return, , from time
to
. There also exists an ETF that seeks to replicate a multiple,
, of the one-period return on the index. This multiple may be either positive (for a leveraged ETF) or negative (for an inverse ETF). In reality,
typically takes a value
of
or
for a leveraged ETF and a value of -1 , -2 , or -3 for an inverse ETF. For our analysis, we only require that
.6
We denote the ETF's time- AUM by
. To replicate
-times the return on the underlying index, the ETF allocates a fraction,
, of its assets to the index and the
remaining fraction,
, to cash. This means that the ETF's time-
index exposure
is
Proposition 1. The ETF rebalances its portfolio according to
Proof: Substitute (1) and (4) into (5). According to Proposition 2, an ETF that tracks a multiple of an index and does not experience any capital flows
generally must rebalance its portfolio in the same direction as the index return. This rebalancing places additional upward pressure on prices when index returns are high and
additional downward pressure on prices when returns are low. Thus, leveraged and inverse ETFs have the potential to amplify volatility in the market. Because the relation characterized by (6) holds for both leveraged and inverse ETFs, rebalancing by leveraged ETFs does not
negate rebalancing by inverse ETFs, and vice versa. Leveraged ETFs rebalance in the same direction as the index return because these ETFs must increase (decrease) their exposure when the return is positive (negative), whereas inverse ETFs rebalance in the same direction as the index return because
these ETFs must decrease (increase) their negative exposure when the return is positive (negative). Rebalancing processes similar to (6) have been derived by Cheng & Madhavan (2009) and Jarrow (2010), though
these authors ignore the effects of capital flows.
As demonstrated by (6), capital flows may either increase or decrease the amount of rebalancing. Specifically, capital flows reduce the amount of rebalancing by a leveraged ETF when the flows occur in the opposite direction of the index return, but flows intensify
rebalancing when they occur in the same direction as the return. The opposite holds true for an inverse ETF, where capital flows mitigate rebalancing when they occur in the same direction as the index return but increase rebalancing when they occur in the opposite direction of the return. As a
consequence, capital flows may either diminish or enhance the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility. This is embodied in the following corollary.
Corollary 1. The extent of rebalancing by the ETF in the same direction as the index return, and therefore the potential for the ETF to exacerbate volatility, increases whenever
sgn sgn
but decreases whenever
sgn
sgn
. Capital flows impact the extent to which an ETF must rebalance because
flows alter the ETF's AUM, which in turn affects the amount of additional index exposure the ETF requires to maintain its target leverage ratio. For example, a positive index return would ordinarily lead a leveraged ETF to increase its index exposure if the ETF did not experience a capital flow, as
described above. A negative capital flow in this case, however, effectively decreases the amount of additional exposure that the ETF must obtain to achieve its target leverage ratio. Therefore, the ETF will not purchase as many additional shares of the underlying index following a positive return.
Similarly, a positive capital flow reduces the amount of exposure that a leveraged ETF must shed after a negative return because such a flow increases the ETF's AUM. Thus, the ETF will not sell as many shares of the underlying index following a negative return. Capital flows have the opposite
effect when they occur in the reverse direction, and analogous reasoning applies to inverse ETFs. Because capital flows may either reduce or augment the amount of rebalancing undertaken by leveraged and inverse ETFs, capital flows can mitigate or aggravate the potential for these types of financial
products to exacerbate volatility.
In this section, we empirically investigate the extent to which capital flows occur and how they affect the need for ETFs to rebalance their portfolios. We find that capital flows occur frequently and that they tend to reduce the amount by which ETFs must rebalance. Furthermore, this reduction in rebalancing demand appears to be economically significant. Overall, the evidence indicates that capital flows substantially mitigate the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to amplify volatility on a daily basis.
We use Morningstar to identify the universe of leveraged and inverse ETFs. There are a total of 188 such ETFs as of May 2014. We restrict our analysis to ETFs that track multiples of the daily performance of U.S. equity indices because we are interested in assessing whether leveraged or inverse
ETFs have the potential to exacerbate volatility in equity markets. We therefore exclude ETFs that are based on government bond, corporate bond, currency, commodity, and foreign equity indices. After these exclusions, there are 104 ETFs remaining in the sample. We further restrict the sample to
relatively large ETFs with a market capitalization of at least $500 million because rebalancing by smaller ETFs may have only a negligible, if any, impact on the volatility of underlying assets. The final sample consists of 31 large domestic equity ETFs and 17,288 ETF-day observations.
We obtain daily data on ETF prices and trading volume from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and shares outstanding and daily index price data from Bloomberg for the period starting in June 2006 and ending in May 2014. We adjust these variables to account for stock splits where
appropriate. We also hand-collect information about the indices tracked by the ETFs in our sample from public sources such as the websites of the ETF sponsors and index providers. Data regarding creation unit sizes and fees are obtained from Morningstar.
We first describe some characteristics of capital flows for all ETF-day observations in our sample. We measure capital flows as the percentage change in the number of ETF shares outstanding. A positive change indicates an inflow (or a net creation of ETF shares) whereas a negative change
indicates an outflow (or a net redemption). Capital flows occur on approximately 75% of ETF-days for leverage ratios of -3 and , on about 54% of ETF-days for leverage ratios of -2 , and on roughly and 40% of ETF-days for leverage ratios of -1 and
. The fact that capital flows occur more frequently for ETFs with higher leverage ratios is noteworthy
because, according to Proposition 2, the potential for rebalancing to exacerbate volatility is greater for ETFs with higher leverage ratios, and, as we demonstrate below, the greater frequency of flows helps to mitigate this potential.
Table 1 reports net capital flows--along with other summary statistics--broken down by the ETFs' leverage ratios. The evidence suggests that ETFs with higher leverage ratios experience larger capital flows, as the
and
percentiles of the flow distributions are larger in magnitude for these ETFs. This, too, is noteworthy because, as Proposition 2 shows, capital
flows must be larger if they are to have a meaningful impact on rebalancing by ETFs with higher leverage ratios. Additionally, the average daily trading volume of ETF shares tends to increase with the magnitude of the leverage ratio, and the average trading volume of ETFs with a leverage ratio of
-1 is substantially lower than the volume of ETFs with other leverage ratios.
Next, we examine the relations between capital flows and index returns. Index returns are reported at the end of the day, whereas the number of shares outstanding are reported at the beginning of the day before trading. We therefore measure the capital flow for ETF on date
as
, where
denotes the number of
shares of ETF
outstanding at
. Returns are measured in the usual way, e.g.,
, where
is the closing value of
the index tracked by ETF
on date
.
According to Corollary 2, capital flows mitigate the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to amplify volatility when the flows occur in the opposite direction of the return times the leverage ratio, but flows aggravate this potential when they occur in the
same direction as the return times the leverage ratio. Figure 1 displays the relations between returns and flows for various leverage ratios. As is evident from the scatter plots, there is a negative relation between returns and flows for leveraged ETFs but a
positive relation for inverse ETFs with leverage ratios of -2 and -3 . This suggests
that flows tend to reduce the extent to which these ETFs must rebalance. Conversely, the negative relation between returns and flows for ETFs with a leverage ratio of -1 suggests that flows
may induce these ETFs to undergo greater rebalancing.
Panel A in Table 2 reports Spearman rank correlation coefficients between capital flows and the magnitude of returns for the first and tenth deciles of returns. We focus our analysis on the tails of the index-return distributions because, in the absence of capital flows, the
potential for ETFs to amplify volatility by rebalancing their portfolios is strongest in these cases, as implied by Proposition 1. We calculate Spearman rank correlation coefficients because the prevalence of observations with zero capital flows (i.e., no net creation or redemption activity on a
given day) could lead to unreliable estimates of the Pearson product-moment correlation coefficient.
The correlation coefficients indicate that capital flows for leveraged ETFs are positively correlated with the magnitude of negative returns but are negatively correlated with the magnitude of positive returns. Conversely, capital flows for inverse ETFs with -2 and -3 leverage ratios, which constitute the vast majority of the inverse ETF observations in our sample, are
negatively correlated with the magnitude of negative returns but are positively correlated with the magnitude of positive returns. Overall, these results suggest that leveraged ETFs tend to experience capital flows in the opposite direction of the underlying index returns whereas inverse ETFs tend
to experience capital flows in the same direction as returns. Thus, capital flows appear to drive an ETF's leverage ratio closer to the target leverage ratio when underlying returns are large in magnitude, thereby mitigating the potential for these types of financial products to exacerbate
volatility.
We also examine the relations between returns and flows from another angle. Panel B in Table 2 reports Spearman rank correlation coefficients between capital flows and returns for days on which capital flows occur, i.e.,
. We calculate Spearman rank correlations because the data are not normally distributed. For leveraged ETFs, returns are positively correlated with the magnitude of outflows
but are negatively correlated with the magnitude of inflows. For inverse ETFs with leverage ratios of -2 and -3 , returns are negatively correlated with the magnitude of outflows but are positively correlated with the magnitude of inflows. Thus, when capital flows occur, they often tend to mitigate the potential for these ETFs to exacerbate volatility. For ETFs with a
leverage ratio of -1 , returns are positively correlated with the magnitude of outflows but are uncorrelated with inflows, which indicates that outflows tend to aggravate the effects of
rebalancing for these ETFs when returns are positive.
The correlations between capital flows and returns suggest that flows reduce the need for ETFs to rebalance their portfolios. In this subsection, we empirically demonstrate this effect more directly and attempt to quantify the economic impact of capital flows on the potential for ETFs to amplify
volatility.
Figure 2 depicts the relations between returns and ETF rebalancing demand, as determined by (6) with normalized to one. The
solid lines in these plots represent the amount of rebalancing that ETFs would need to undertake if they did not experience any capital flows. Each data point on the scatter plots represents the rebalancing demand given the observed capital flow. Clearly, capital flows have a substantial effect on
ETF rebalancing demand, and thus the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility.
In the context of Figure 2, capital flows mitigate (aggravate) rebalancing demand when the rebalancing amount is closer to (farther from)
than the solid line for a given return. The scatter plots indicate that flows often, though not always, reduce ETF rebalancing demand. In many cases, flows generate rebalancing
demand in the opposite direction of returns, which, in stark contrast to conventional thinking, could dampen the volatility of the underlying assets.
To more rigorously assess how capital flows affect the relation between returns and rebalancing demand, we perform a segmented regression analysis to analyze the relation between rebalancing demand and returns across the different quintiles of the return distribution. Segmenting the returns allows
us to evaluate how returns affect rebalancing demand in different parts of the return distribution, which is important because the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility is stronger when returns are larger in magnitude. For each leverage ratio, we estimate the following ordinary least squares
regression for the five quintiles of the return distribution:
As we demonstrate both theoretically and empirically, capital flows can affect the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to exacerbate volatility. So far, though, we have been agnostic about the source of capital flows, as our primary objective is to illustrate the effect of capital flows on
the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to amplify volatility. There are numerous reasons why investors trade, and identifying the underlying trading motive(s) behind capital flows is beyond the scope of this paper. Nonetheless, in this section we discuss a couple of possible motives for
trading that could lead to the empirically-observed relations between returns and capital flows.
One possible explanation could be mean-reversion and/or momentum trading. Under a mean-reversion trading strategy, investors would increase (decrease) their exposure to leveraged ETFs following negative (positive) index returns. Investors would also increase (decrease) their exposure to inverse
ETFs following positive (negative) returns. Under a momentum trading strategy, investors would behave in an opposite fashion. Such trading strategies could contribute to the empirical relations that we observe.
The observed relations between returns and capital flows could also originate from investors wishing to track--via an ETF--a multiple of the underlying index over a horizon longer than a day. Because daily rebalancing by an ETF alters investors' exposures to the underlying index, investors must
rebalance their own portfolios daily by trading shares of the ETF to maintain their desired exposure to the index over a horizon longer than a day. As we demonstrate below, such trading by investors could contribute to the empirical relations between capital flows and returns. Moreover, capital
flows can completely eliminate ETF rebalancing, and therefore eliminate the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility, if all investors aim to track a multiple of the underlying index over a long horizon. We describe this mechanism in detail in the remaining portion of this section.
To clearly illustrate the mechanism, we introduce a representative investor who wishes to track -times the return on the index over a horizon longer than one period and assume that trading
by the investor gives rise to capital flows. Although there are likely many investors who desire the exposure provided by a leveraged or inverse ETF over a single day or less, there are liable to be many others who use these types of products for longer-term hedging purposes (e.g., market makers or
financial intermediaries).
First consider the case in which the investor does not rebalance his own portfolio to account for changes in the ETF's exposure to the index. In this situation, his one-period return from holding the ETF is equal to
Corollary 2. The ETF does not rebalance its portfolio when the investor aims to track a multiple of the underlying return over multiple periods, i.e.,
Market frictions that impede capital flows are likely to have a considerable effect on the potential for leveraged and inverse ETFs to amplify market movements. One such friction is a requirement that permits the flow of capital only in large blocks (usually 50,000 shares) called creation units.
This requirement forces investors as a group to adjust their ETF holdings in discrete units and may therefore lead to less frequent capital flows. Another friction that could obstruct capital flows is transaction costs incurred by investors to adjust their ETF holdings in their own portfolios. To
the extent that these frictions impede capital flows, both could result in greater rebalancing by ETFs and ultimately increase their potential to exacerbate volatility.
In the remainder of this section, we conduct a numerical simulation to better understand the effects of market frictions. While both of the frictions identified above could impact capital flows, for the sake of brevity, we focus solely on transaction costs. In general, we find that frictions can
drastically reduce the frequency of capital flows, but flows still tend to mitigate the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility. When the frictions are relatively large, however, capital flows can aggravate the potential for ETFs to amplify market movements.
As a first benchmark against which to evaluate the impact of market frictions on ETF rebalancing demand, we select the limiting case where (17) characterizes the flow process and the ETF never rebalances its portfolio. Although this benchmark implicitly relies on the notion
that investors seek to track a multiple of the underlying index over a horizon longer than one period, the intuition developed through the simulation should not depend on the specific driver of capital flows. We also consider the rebalancing process defined by (6) with
as a second benchmark. The first benchmark enables us to gauge the extent to which frictions might reduce capital flows, and the second benchmark enables us to assess the degree to
which capital flows affect ETF rebalancing demand in the presence of frictions.
Because leveraged and inverse ETFs typically aim to track -times the daily return on an index, capital flows must occur daily to fully mitigate rebalancing by ETFs. As the ultimate source of
capital flows is trading by investors, however, this may be prohibitively expensive if the cost of trading is high relative to the amount of each individual investor's investment in the ETF. For example, if an investor allocated $10,000 to the ETF and paid a $10 brokerage fee every day to trade the
ETF's shares, after one year the total fees would constitute approximately 25% of the initial investment (assuming 250 trading days and ignoring bid-ask spreads). As a consequence, investors are unlikely to trade, and capital flows are therefore unlikely to occur, daily. Rather, capital flows
should occur only when the benefit to the investor of trading exceeds the cost.
To capture the effects of transaction costs, we assume that no capital flows occur unless the investor's effective index allocation (through holding the ETF) deviates from his desired allocation by a sufficiently large margin. The investor's index allocation in period is
, where
denotes the index value at time
. This corresponds to the ETF allocating a constant fraction
of its assets to the index each
period. However, (1), (6), and (17) indicate that the investor must maintain an allocation equal to
in all periods to achieve his objective of tracking
-times the index
performance over a long horizon. This implies that the investor prefers that the ETF allocate a fraction
of its assets to the index at time
.
The discrepancy between these two portfolios causes the return from holding the ETF to diverge from the investor's desired return, and the magnitude of this divergence depends on the degree to which these portfolios differ. When the investor incurs a transaction cost, capital flows occur only when
the benefit of trading outweighs the cost. Therefore, we assume that no capital flows occur unless the discrepancy between the two portfolios reaches a critical threshold, which we denote by
. Thus, a capital flow occurs at time
if and only if
When computing the capital flow and rebalancing processes, we assume that the index return follows the historical return on the S&P 500 from January 2007 to May 2014. Details regarding the source of the data are provided in Section 3.1. We compute results for
.
Algorithm 6 describes the procedure used to compute capital flows in the presence of transaction costs. Inputs for the algorithm include: the flow threshold, ;
the ETF multiple,
; the index return,
; the initial AUM,
; the initial index value,
; and the initial number of ETF shares outstanding,
. We calculate statistics for various combinations of
and
. We also normalize
,
, and
to one. The normalization does not affect the incidence of capital flows or ETF rebalancing, but it does affect the magnitude of
our results.
For each date , the algorithm first checks the extent of the deviation between the investor's actual and desired allocations. If this deviation is relatively small, i.e., if (19) is not satisfied, then there is no capital flow. On the other hand, if (19) is satisifed then there is a capital flow. The capital flow for the ETF in period
is given by
Table 5 reports results related to capital flows and the efficacy of rebalancing when the investor incurs a transaction cost. As predicted by (19), the frequency of capital flows is decreasing in but increasing in
. Hence, capital flows occur more frequently when transaction costs are
lower or the ETF has a higher leverage ratio. For
or -1 , capital flows occur
less than 15% of the time when
is a modest 5%. In many other scenarios, capital flows occur far less than 50% of the time. These results indicate that transaction costs can be a
serious impediment to flows.
The reduction in the frequency of capital flows impacts the potential for ETFs to exacerbate volatility, as evidenced by the reduction in the efficacy of rebalancing. We compute two measures of efficacy. The first measure, which we refer to as simple efficacy, normalizes the ratio of the ETF size
to the index value, , to 1 for all
and ignores the path of returns. The
second measure, which we refer to as gross efficacy, takes the return path into account and allows the aforementioned ratio to fluctuate over time. Over the entire sample period, the reduction in both efficacy scores is generally decreasing in
but increasing in
. Thus, capital flows reduce the efficacy of rebalancing to a greater extent when transaction
costs are lower or the ETF has a higher leverage ratio.
Comparing the two measures of efficacy reveals that the path of returns can have a tremendous effect on the potential for ETFs to amplify market movements when there are frictions that obstruct capital flows. Over the sample period, capital flows reduce simple efficacy more than gross efficacy for
leveraged ETFs, but flows decrease gross efficacy more than simple efficacy for inverse ETFs. These differing effects are driven by how the sharp decline in the value of the S&P 500 and subsequent gradual recovery affect the sizes of the ETFs. Because frictions are more of a hindrance to
capital flows when returns are smaller in magnitude, and the drop in value of the S&P 500 is steeper than the recovery, capital flows increase (decrease) the size of leveraged (inverse) ETFs during the fall more effectively than they decrease (increase) the size during the rise. Therefore, the
reduction in gross efficacy is less (greater) than the reduction in simple efficacy for leveraged (inverse) ETFs over the sample period.
Although capital flows (by construction) always reduce simple efficacy in the simulation, in some cases flows enhance gross efficacy when the frictions are relatively large. Figure 4, which plots the cumulative percentage reduction in the efficacy scores for an ETF
with a leverage ratio of , indicates that capital flows increase gross efficacy when
. The increase in gross efficacy is driven by the relatively infrequent flow of capital in combination with volatile returns. As illustrated by Figure 5, which plots the cumulative percentage changes in the number of shares outstanding for various levels of transaction costs, the large decline in the value of the S&P 500 during 2008-09 leads to a large capital inflow.8 This results in more assets under management for the ETF relative to the benchmark case with no capital flows. Then, as the index recovers, the ETF undergoes a greater amount of rebalancing on a day-to-day
basis because it has more assets under management and frictions prevent capital outflows from reducing AUM until the flow threshold characterized by (19) is reached. Under these circumstances--a long, gradual rise in the value of the index following a sharp
decline--capital flows in the presence of large frictions cause the gross efficacy of rebalancing to be higher relative to the case with no capital flows for leveraged ETFs.
Leveraged and inverse ETFs have received heavy criticism based on the belief that they exacerbate volatility in financial markets. We show that concerns about these types of products are likely exaggerated. Empirically, we find that capital flows considerably reduce ETF rebalancing demand and, therefore, mitigate the potential for ETFs to amplify volatility. Our analysis has relevant and timely policy implications, as regulators are reportedly considering changes to how ETFs are regulated.9
Mkt. Cap | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Volume | CU Size | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 1059.98 | 0.0001 | 0.0011 | 0.0032 | 23.371 | 50,000 |
St. Dev. | 466.51 | 0.0439 | 0.0173 | 0.0500 | 47.747 | |
![]() |
578.55 | -0.0443 | -0.0169 | -0.0499 | 2.927 | |
![]() |
1652.79 | 0.0438 | 0.0176 | 0.0518 | 43.916 |
Mkt. Cap | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Volume | CU Size | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 1138.59 | -0.0009 | 0.0008 | 0.0015 | 10.797 | 75,000 |
St. Dev. | 613.95 | 0.0368 | 0.0163 | 0.0315 | 17.063 | |
![]() |
583.53 | -0.0167 | -0.0162 | -0.0315 | 0.373 | |
![]() |
1755.27 | 0.0124 | 0.0163 | 0.0323 | 25.821 |
Mkt. Cap | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Volume | CU Size | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 1629.93 | 0.0019 | 0.0005 | -0.0006 | 3.293 | 75,000 |
St. Dev. | 554.70 | 0.0173 | 0.0134 | 0.0132 | 2.355 | |
![]() |
614.94 | -0.0107 | -0.0143 | -0.0142 | 1.359 | |
![]() |
2256.33 | 0.0189 | 0.0137 | 0.0140 | 5.901 |
Mkt. Cap | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Volume | CU Size | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 1407.43 | 0.0013 | 0.0003 | 0.0002 | 19.583 | 75,000 |
St. Dev. | 921.16 | 0.0353 | 0.0241 | 0.0460 | 16.063 | |
![]() |
554.36 | -0.0201 | -0.0238 | -0.0418 | 4.648 | |
![]() |
2859.84 | 0.0243 | 0.0213 | 0.0466 | 42.011 |
Mkt. Cap | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Volume | CU Size | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 776.10 | 0.0056 | 0.0004 | -0.0015 | 27.619 | 50,000 |
St. Dev. | 374.07 | 0.0974 | 0.0152 | 0.0440 | 42.659 | |
![]() |
539.22 | -0.0354 | -0.0161 | -0.0457 | 5.386 | |
![]() |
1082.38 | 0.0444 | 0.0155 | 0.0477 | 57.688 |
m+3 1st | m+3 10th | m+2 1st | m+2 10th | m-1 1st | m-1 10th | m-2 1st | m-2 10th | m-3 1st | m-3 10th | |
![]() |
0.334*** | -0.070 | 0.327*** | -0.103** | 0.188** | -0.035 | -0.267*** | 0.150*** | -0.189*** | 0.345*** |
p-value | (0.000) | (0.265) | (0.000) | (0.015) | (0.021) | (0.673) | (0.000) | (0.001) | (0.002) | (0.000) |
N | 255 | 255 | 553 | 554 | 151 | 150 | 503 | 504 | 265 | 264 |
---|
m+3 Out | m+3 In | m+2 Out | m+2 In | m-1 Out | m-1 In | m-2 Out | m-2 In | m-3 Out | m-3 In | |
![]() |
0.236*** | -0.168*** | 0.098*** | -0.126*** | 0.178*** | -0.015 | -0.203*** | 0.136*** | -0.342*** | 0.140*** |
p-value | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.003) | (0.780) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
N | 959 | 935 | 1283 | 897 | 280 | 334 | 1257 | 1486 | 845 | 1131 |
---|
m = +3 (1) | m = +2 (2) | m = -1 (3) | m = -2 (4) | m = 3 (5) | |
Quintile 1 | 1.533*** | 0.742*** | 2.248** | 3.719*** | 8.820*** |
Quintile 1, standard error | (0.569) | (0.191) | (0.107) | (0.261) | (0.628) |
Quintile 2 | 3.847 | 1.456 | 2.012 | 6.477 | 9.738 |
Quintile 2, standard error | (1.851) | (0.475) | (0.521)) | (0.476) | (2.289) |
Quintile 3 | 1.409* | 2.892 | 1.550 | 6.339 | 12.420 |
Quintile 3, standard error | (2.449) | (1.163) | (0.714) | (0.644) | (2.721) |
Quintile 4 | 4.590 | 1.838 | 0.993** | 5.711 | 5.964** |
Quintile 4, standard error | (2.393) | (0.539) | (0.506) | (0.500) | (2.553) |
Quintile 5 | 3.531*** | 1.512*** | 1.910 | 3.602*** | 7.315*** |
Quintile 5, standard error | (0.438) | (0.133) | (0.133) | (0.412) | (0.821) |
m = +3 | m = +2 | m = -1 | m =-2 | m = 3 | |
Efficacy without Flows | 0.158 | 0.050 | 0.040 | 0.234 | 0.261 |
Efficacy with Flows | 0.078 | 0.043 | 0.044 | 0.199 | 0.168 |
Efficacy Reduction (%) | 50.54 | 14.31 | -10.01 | 14.94 | 35.72 |
Rebalancing Threshold ![]() |
1% | 5% | 10% | 20% |
Flow Frequency | 82.3 | 41.6 | 22.8 | 8.6 |
Simple Efficacy Reduction | 99.9 | 95.2 | 84.0 | 62.8 |
Gross Efficacy Reduction | 99.8 | 85.9 | 55.3 | -2.3 |
Rebalancing Threshold ![]() |
1% | 5% | 10% | 20% |
Flow Frequency | 56.1 | 13.7 | 4.4 | 1.4 |
Simple Efficacy Reduction | 97.7 | 70.6 | 46.3 | 24.7 |
Gross Efficacy Reduction | 96.0 | 51.2 | 13.7 | -16.7 |
Rebalancing Threshold ![]() |
1% | 5% | 10% | 20% |
Flow Frequency | 56.1 | 13.3 | 5.1 | 1.4 |
Simple Efficacy Reduction | 97.8 | 71.1 | 48.5 | 20.7 |
Gross Efficacy Reduction | 98.2 | 77.5 | 61.5 | 42.5 |
Rebalancing Threshold ![]() |
1% | 5% | 10% | 20% |
Flow Frequency | 82.2 | 41.2 | 22.4 | 8.8 |
Simple Efficacy Reduction | 99.9 | 95.2 | 84.1 | 63.1 |
Gross Efficacy Reduction | 100.0 | 95.9 | 87.0 | 70.9 |
Rebalancing Threshold ![]() |
1% | 5% | 10% | 20% |
Flow Frequency | 90.7 | 61.5 | 41.1 | 22.3 |
Simple Efficacy Reduction | 100.0 | 98.6 | 95.2 | 83.9 |
Gross Efficacy Reduction | 100.0 | 98.7 | 95.5 | 85.5 |
Algorithm 1 compute capital flow process with transaction costs
input ,
,
,
,
,
for
to
if
then
else
end if
end for
return ,