Abstract:
Keywords: financial intermediaries, leverage, short-term risky debt, limited liability, risk-shifting moral hazard, cross-sectional volatility.
JEL codes: E20, E30, G10, G20
The 2007-9 financial crisis witnessed a severe disruption of financial intermediation in many industrialized economies. This has led to a surge in both empirical and theoretical research aimed at understanding the causes and consequences of the financial crisis, evaluating the policy measures put in place to tackle its effects, and proposing further policy actions and new regulatory frameworks.
A particularly influential strand of the literature has focused on the role played by the deleveraging of the financial intermediation sector in the propagation of the financial turmoil. Before the crisis, a significant share of financial intermediaries funded their asset purchases primarily by means of collateralized debt with very short maturity, such as sale and repurchase (repo) agreements or asset backed commercial paper (ABCP).1As argued by Brunnermeier (2009), Gorton and Metrick (2010, 2012), Krishnamurthy, Nagel and Orlov (2012) and others, the initial losses suffered by some of the assets that served as collateral in repo or ABCP transactions, together with the uncertainty surrounding individual exposures to such assets, led the holders of that short-term debt (mostly institutional investors, such as money market funds) to largely stop rolling over their lending. This funding freeze forced the financial intermediaries to deleverage, with the resulting contraction in their balance sheets and ultimately in the credit flow to the real economy.
In fact, the observed deleveraging of financial intermediaries during the 2007-9 financial crisis is not an isolated episode. As documented by Adrian and Shin (2010, 2011), since the 1960s the leverage ratio (i.e. the ratio of total assets to equity capital) of important segments of the financial intermediation sector has exhibited a markedly procyclical pattern, in the sense that expansions (contractions) in balance sheet size have gone hand in hand with increases (decreases) in leverage.2Overall, this evidence points to the importance of leverage fluctuations for the cyclical behavior of financial intermediation and real economic activity.
The aim of this paper is to propose a general equilibrium framework with leverage-constrained financial intermediaries that is able to explain the observed fluctuations in intermediary leverage and its comovement with real economic activity. Intermediary leverage is modeled along the lines of Adrian and Shin's (2013) static, partial equilibrium framework. Our main theoretical contribution is to incorporate their model of endogenous leverage into a fully dynamic, quantitative general equilibrium framework in which banks have an instrumental role in the channeling of funds from savers to borrowers.
In the model, banks borrow in the form of short-term risky debt. The source of risk in bank debt is the following. Firms are segmented across 'islands' and are hit by island-specific shocks. Some firms are more exposed to island-specific risk than others. Those more exposed also have lower island-specific returns on average, such that financing them is inefficient. Firms can only obtain funds from banks on the same island, as only the latter have the technology to assess their risk exposure. Banks are thus instrumental in channeling funds to firms, but they are also exposed to island-specific risk. A fraction of them declare bankruptcy and default on their debt in each period.
As in Adrian and Shin (2013), banks are affected by risk-shifting moral hazard.3 Due to limited liability, banks enjoy the upside risk in their assets over and above the face value of their debt, leaving their creditors to bear the downside risk. This provides banks with an incentive to finance firms that are more exposed to island-specific risk despite having lower expected returns, i.e. to engage in inefficient lending practices. Such an incentive increases with the bank's debt burden relative to the size of its balance sheet. In order to induce banks to invest efficiently, their creditors restrict bank indebtedness to a certain ratio of bank net worth, i.e. they impose a leverage constraint.
We then calibrate our model to the US economy and analyze its ability to replicate the fluctuations in leverage and its comovement with economic activity. In the data, intermediary leverage is characterized by relatively large fluctuations: it is several times more volatile than GDP, and has contributed more than equity to fluctuations in assets. Leverage is strongly procyclical with respect to assets (as originally documented by Adrian and Shin, 2010, 2011), and also mildly procyclical with respect to GDP. In the model, we consider two exogenous driving forces: total factor productivity (TFP), and time-varying volatility of island-specific shocks. While TFP shocks are fairly standard in business cycle modelling, a recent literature argues that exogenous changes in cross-sectional volatility are key in order to understand aggregate fluctuations.4 Moreover, such changes in volatility can be interpreted as changes in `uncertainty', which as argued before are considered to have played an important role in the recent financial crisis.
Our results show that TFP shocks by themselves are unable to replicate the volatility of leverage in the data, as well as its procyclicality with respect to GDP. Intuitively, TFP shocks barely affect banks' risk-taking incentives. On the contrary, shocks to cross-sectional volatility are able to produce fluctuations in leverage of a realistic size, as well as a positive comovement between leverage, assets and GDP. The mechanism, which we refer to as the 'volatility-leverage channel', is as follows. Consider e.g. an increase in island-specific volatility. Higher uncertainty regarding asset returns, coupled with limited liability, makes it more attractive for banks to engage in inefficiently risky lending practices. In order to prevent them from doing so, institutional investors impose a tighter constraint on banks' leverage. For given net worth, this deleveraging forces banks to contract their balance sheets, thus producing a fall in funding to firms. This leads to a fall in capital investment by firms, and in aggregate output. The consequence is a positive comovement between leverage, assets and GDP.
We also study the model's ability to shed light on the 2008-9 recession. Our results show that the fall in TFP observed during that period explains part of the fall in GDP, but it fails to replicate its severity and duration. Moreover, the TFP shock is completely unable to explain the observed deleveraging in the banking sector, as well as the reduction in its total assets. Adding an increase in volatility starting at the beginning of 2008 allows the model to match well the large and protracted fall not only of GDP, but also of bank leverage and assets during the Great Recession.
Finally, we use our model as a laboratory for studying how the steady-state level of cross-sectional volatility affects both the mean level and the volatility of economic activity. We find that lower cross-sectional volatility raises the mean level of banks' leverage, through a channel very similar to the one described above. This produces an increase in the mean levels of intermediary assets, capital investment and GDP. Perhaps more surprisingly, lower cross-sectional volatility raises the volatility of GDP. Intuitively, lower perceived risk allows banks to increase their leverage, which generates larger responses in bank funding and output in the face of aggregate shocks. This result, which may be thought of as a `risk diversification paradox', is reminiscent of Minsky's (1992) 'financial instability hypothesis,' according to which a lower perception of uncertainty leads to riskier investment practices, thus creating the conditions for the emergence of a financial crisis.
Literature review. Our paper contributes to the literature on the macroeconomic effects of financial frictions. A recent literature has provided theoretical explanations for the 'leverage cycles' discussed above, with contributions by Adrian and Shin (2013), Ashcraft, Garleanu and Pedersen (2011), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Dang, Gorton and Holmström (2011), Geanakoplos (2010), and Gorton and Ordoñez (2011), among others.5 Most of these models consider some type of link between changes in 'uncertainty', typically defined as changes in the volatility of shocks, and the emergence of these leverage cycles. While these models provide important insights on the equilibrium behavior of leverage, they are primarily aimed at illustrating theoretical mechanisms and are thus mainly qualitative. In particular, most of these papers consider two- or three-period economies, or two-period-lived agents in OLG setups; they also assume a partial equilibrium structure. We build on this literature by analyzing endogenous leverage cycles in a fully dynamic, general equilibrium model that can be compared to aggregate data, and that allows us to study the interaction between the real and financial sides of the economy.
Our paper is also related to a growing literature on the role of financial intermediaries in dynamic, stochastic, general equilibrium (DSGE) models. Early contributions to the macro-finance literature, such as Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), emphasized the importance of financial frictions for the macroeconomy, but largely obviated the role played by financial intermediaries. Since the recent financial crisis, a number of papers study how frictions arising in the financial intermediation sector affect credit flows to the real economy. Christiano, Motto and Rostagno (2010) model banks that face asymmetric information and agency problems in their lending activities and incur a cost when creating liquid liabilities such as deposits, but do not consider leverage constraints on financial intermediaries.
More closely related is the work of Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2010). These authors consider banks that borrow in the form of riskless debt, and that are leverage constrained due to a moral hazard problem stemming from bankers' ability to divert a fraction of deposits for personal use.6 They focus their discussion on how adverse shocks may disrupt credit supply through their effect on bank equity capital, and how unconventional monetary policy interventions can mitigate the effects of such shocks on economic activity. By contrast, we propose a model where intermediaries face leverage constraints that limit their incentives to fund inefficiently risky activities, as in Adrian and Shin (2013), and we then assess its ability to explain the observed fluctuations in intermediary leverage and economic activity. The central feature of our model is the presence of risky debt contracts and the associated risk-shifting incentives, which gives rise to the volatility-leverage channel discussed above.
Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2011), He and Krishnamurthy (2012) and Boissay, Collard and Smets (2013) propose models with financially constrained intermediaries and characterize their dynamics in a fully nonlinear manner. Such nonlinearities generate rich and interesting dynamics.7 Our framework is more standard in that it can be solved using standard perturbation methods, which facilitates simulation as well as likelihood-based estimation.
Our paper also contributes to the literature on the macroeconomic effects of second moment (volatility) shocks in quantitative general equilibrium models.8 In our model, first moment (TFP) and second moment shocks map differently on real and financial variables: while both shocks produce sizable fluctuations in GDP, investment, etc., only volatility shocks produce large and procyclical fluctuations in bank leverage. In this sense, our analysis points to the usefulness of financial data for disentangling the effects of first and second moment shocks.
Finally, we extend the empirical analysis of leverage fluctuations by Adrian and Shin (2010), who first documented the positive correlation between leverage and assets for security broker/dealers. Building on their work, our paper provides a systematic analysis of business cycle statistics (including measures of volatility, in addition to correlations) for the main components of intermediary balance sheets (assets, equity, and leverage) and for a wider range of financial subsectors. Moreover, we adopt a more macro perspective by including real GDP in the analysis, which allows us to gauge the comovements between balance sheet variables and aggregate economic activity. This gives rise to new empirical findings, such as the large volatility of intermediary leverage (relative both to equity -the other determinant of balance sheet size- and GDP), and its procyclicality with respect to GDP.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 1 presents empirical evidence on the cyclical behavior of financial intermediaries' balance-sheet aggregates and GDP in the US. Section 2 lays out a general equilibrium model with leverage constrained intermediaries and volatility shocks. Section 3 analyzes some of the theoretical properties of the model, including the volatility-leverage channel and a comparison with Gertler and Karadi (2011). Section 4 calibrates and simulates the model, assessing its ability to replicate the data. Section 5 concludes.
In this section, we perform a systematic analysis of the cyclical fluctuations in the main balance sheet components of US financial intermediaries, with a special attention to the leverage ratio, and their comovement with real economic activity. Our analysis comprises the main subsectors in what Greenlaw et al. (2008) have termed the 'leveraged sector', including depository intermediaries such as US-chartered commercial banks and savings institutions, as well as non-depository intermediaries such as security brokers and dealers and finance companies.
The balance sheet size of financial intermediaries is the product of two components: equity capital and leverage ratio. We may thus write
, where
denotes total assets,
represents the leverage ratio, and
is equity capital. In logs, we have
Standard deviation (%) | Commercial banks | Savings institutions | Security broker/dealers | Finance companies |
Assets | 1.88 | 4.00 | 8.93 | 3.85 |
Leverage | 2.84 | 8.16 | 10.21 | 4.71 |
Equity | 2.55 | 8.13 | 8.08 | 3.64 |
GDP: 1.48 |
Correlations
Correlation | Commercial banks | Savings institutions | Security broker/dealers | Finance companies |
Leverage - Assets | 0.48*** | 0.25*** | 0.65*** | 0.65*** |
Leverage - Assets (p-value) | (0.0000) | (0.0008) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) |
Leverage - Equity | -0.76*** | -0.88*** | -0.54*** | -0.60*** |
Leverage - Equity (p-value) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) |
Leverage - GDP | 0.18** | 0.12 | 0.26*** | 0.32*** |
Leverage - GDP (p-value) | (0.0188) | (0.1055) | (0.0006) | (0.0000) |
Assets - GDP | 0.63*** | 0.71*** | 0.42*** | 0.52*** |
Assets - GDP (p-value) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) |
The table reveals two main stylized facts regarding the cyclical fluctuations in the leverage ratio of financial intermediaries. First, leverage is volatile. Notice first that leverage fluctuates more than equity capital, which is the other determinant of balance sheet size. Moreover, leverage is several times more volatile than GDP. For broker/dealers and finance companies, the standard deviation of leverage is about 7 and 3 times larger than that of GDP, respectively. The leverage of savings institutions displays a high volatility too, due mainly to the savings and loans crisis episode in the 1980s. For commercial banks, the leverage ratio fluctuates comparatively less, although its standard deviation is still about twice that of GDP.
Second, leverage is strongly procyclical with respect to total assets, as originally documented by Adrian and Shin (2010, 2011).10 It is also mildly procyclical with respect to GDP. The comovement with assets is particularly strong for security broker/dealers and finance companies (with a correlation of 0.65), but is also significant for depository institutions. As explained by Adrian and Shin (2010), such a strong comovement reveals an active management of leverage as a means of expanding and contracting the size of balance sheets. The correlation of the different leverage ratios with GDP ranges from 0.12 to 0.36, and while they are comparatively small, they are all statistically significant (with the exception of savings institutions). We also note that leverage and equity comove negatively over the business cycle. This negative correlation is large for the four subsectors, ranging from -0.88 for savings institutions to -0.54 for security broker/dealers.
Source: US Flow of Funds. See Data Appendix for details. Leverage and Total assets have been logged and detrended with a bandpass filter that preserves cycles of 6 to 32 quarters (lag length of 12 quarters). Shaded areas represent NBER-dated recessions.As a graphical illustration, Figure 1 shows the cyclical components of total assets and leverage for the two largest leveraged financial subsectors in the United States: US-chartered commercial banks, and security brokers and dealers.11 The 2008-9 recession witnessed a sharp decline in the leverage ratio of security broker/dealers, and an incipient decline in that of commercial banks. A similar deleveraging process was observed during the mid-70s recession. However, other recessions such as the 1981-82 one did not have any noticeable effect on the leverage of these two subsectors. This explains their relatively low cyclicality with respect to GDP. Notice also that the strong correlation of commercial banks' assets and leverage at the beginning of the sample has weakened somewhat over time, while such comovement seems to have been more stable for security broker/dealers. Figure 1 displays the cyclical comovement between leverage and equity capital, again for commercial banks and security broker/dealers. The negative correlation between both variables is evident in the case of commercial banks, and less clear for broker/dealers. For instance, the recent recession featured an increase in equity of commercial banks, unlike that of broker/dealers. For the latter subsector, the negative correlation in Table 1 is the product of earlier historical episodes, such as the two recessions in the 1970s.
Source: US Flow of Funds. See Data Appendix for details. Leverage and Total assets have been logged and detrended with a bandpass filter that preserves cycles of 6 to 32 quarters (lag length of 12 quarters). Shaded areas represent NBER-dated recessions.Our analysis of financial intermediaries is performed on a sectoral level. It would be interesting to consolidate the balance sheets of the different financial subsectors so as to study the cyclical properties of the leveraged financial system as a whole. Unfortunately, the Flow of Funds data does not allow this possibility, because asset and liability positions between the different subsectors are not netted out. As a result, simply adding assets and equity would lead to a double-counting of such cross positions. Nevertheless, it is important to emphasize that the stylized facts discussed above are robust across financial subsectors.
The above empirical findings are also robust in other dimensions. First, we have repeated the analysis using a Hodrick-Prescott filter instead of a bandpass one. Second, we have replaced `total assets' by 'total financial assets', which are also available in the Flow of Funds. In both cases quantitative results change very little.12 Finally, we have restricted the sample period by starting it in 1984, instead of in 1963. Our motivation for doing so is the fact the US financial system has experienced substantial structural transformations during the postwar period, which raises the question as to how robust the business cycle statistics in Table 1 are to considering different subsamples. Results are shown in Table 2. Our stylized facts continue to hold. The only exception is that the correlation of commercial banks' leverage and GDP is no longer statistically significant.
Standard deviation (%) | Commercial banks | Savings institutions | Security broker/dealers | Finance companies |
Assets | 1.30 | 4.59 | 7.57 | 3.05 |
Leverage | 3.12 | 8.61 | 7.62 | 5.34 |
Equity | 3.12 | 8.35 | 5.27 | 4.58 |
GDP: 1.03 |
Correlations
Correlation | Commercial banks | Savings institutions | Security broker/dealers | Finance companies |
Leverage - Assets | 0.21* | 0.32*** | 0.76*** | 0.52*** |
Leverage - Assets (p-value) | (0.0518) | (0.0023) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) |
Leverage - Equity | -0.91*** | -0.85*** | -0.35*** | -0.82*** |
Leverage - Equity (p-value) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0008) | (0.0000) |
Leverage - GDP | -0.06 | 0.34*** | 0.22** | 0.24** |
Leverage - GDP (p-value) | (0.5942) | (0.0014) | (0.0444) | (0.0252) |
Assets - GDP | 0.46*** | 0.73*** | 0.47*** | 0.41*** |
Assets - GDP (p-value) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | (0.0001) |
Notice that the equity capital series from the Flow of Funds are of book equity, i.e. the difference between the value of intermediaries' portfolio of claims and their liabilities. An alternative measure of equity is the market capitalization, i.e. the market value of intermediaries' traded shares. As argued by Adrian, Colla and Shin (2012), book equity is the appropriate notion of equity if one is interested in the supply of bank credit, as we are here, whereas market capitalization would have been more appropriate if one were interested in new share issuance or mergers and acquisitions decisions.
A related issue is that, even if one focuses on the book value of equity, it matters how assets are valued. As argued e.g. by He, Khang and Krishnamurthy (2010), the fact that part of the assets on commercial banks' balance sheets are not subject to fair value accounting implies that official balance sheet data from the Flow of Funds or FDIC may overstate the true procyclicality of book leverage in that subsector. However, it is difficult to assess quantitatively how relevant this criticism is, given the lack of time series for the commercial banking sector that apply fair value accounting systematically. Also, this issue does not affect market-based intermediaries, such as security broker/dealers or finance companies, which constitute a significant share of the leveraged financial intermediary sector.13 Therefore, it is reasonable to argue that, for the leveraged intermediary sector as a whole, leverage follows a procyclical pattern. In any case, we stress that our measure of equity in the theoretical model will be consistent with the way equity is constructed in the data.
To summarize, our empirical analysis suggests the existence of a 'bank leverage cycle' in the postwar US economy, characterized by two main features. First, the leverage ratio of the different subsectors display large fluctuations, contributing more than equity capital to cyclical movements in total assets. Second, leverage is strongly procyclical with respect to total assets and mildly procyclical with respect to GDP; it is also negatively correlated with equity capital. In what follows, we present a general equilibrium model aimed at explaining these empirical patterns.
The model economy is composed of five types of agents: households, final good producers (`firms' for short), capital producers, institutional investors, and banks. On the financial side, the model structure is as follows. Households lend to institutional investors in the form of deposits and equity. Institutional investors use the latter funds to lend to banks in the form of short-term debt. Banks combine this external funding and their own accumulated net worth so as to provide funding for firms. We assume no frictions in the relationship between banks and firms, such that the Modigliani-Miller theorem applies to firm financing. For simplicity and without loss of generality, we follow Gertler and Karadi (2011) in assuming that firms issue perfectly state-contingent debt only, which can be interpreted as equity. Banks and firms are segmented across a continuum of islands. Firms are hit by island-specific shocks to effective capital.14 Banks are thus exposed to island-specific risk; each period, a fraction of them declare bankruptcy and default on their debt. Bank debt is not guaranteed and is therefore risky. As in Adrian and Shin (2013), moral hazard (of the risk-shifting type) creates a friction in the flow of funds from institutional investors to banks. Institutional investors operate economy-wide and diversify perfectly across islands; in fact, their only role in our model is to insulate households from island-specific risk, which allows us to make use of the representative household construct.
The real side of the model is fairly standard. At the end of each period, after production has taken place, firms use borrowed funds to purchase physical capital from capital producers. At the beginning of the following period, firms combine their stock of capital and households' supply of labor to produce a final good. The latter is purchased by households for consumption purposes, and by capital producers. After production, firms sell their depreciated capital stock to capital producers, who use the latter and final goods to produce new capital. The markets for labor, physical capital and the final good are all economy-wide.
We now analyze the behavior of each type of agent. All variables are expressed in real terms, with the final good acting as the numeraire.
The representative household's utility is
, where
is consumption and
is labor supply. The budget constraint is
![]() |
![]() ![]() ![]() |
The final good is produced by perfectly competitive firms. As in Kiyotaki and Moore (2008), we assume that firms are segmented across a continuum of 'islands', indexed by
.
In each island there are two types of firms, which we will refer to as 'standard' and 'substandard' firms. Each firm's type follows an iid process over time, with probability one half each; the type for time is drawn at the end of
, after production has taken place. Both types differ in the following dimension. At the start of each period, firms receive an island-specific
shock to effective capital. Let
and
denote the shock received by standard and substandard firms, respectively, in island
. Letting
denote the beginning-of-period capital stock of standard firms in island
, the shock
changes their amount of effective capital to
, and analogously for substandard firms. Both
and
are iid over time and across islands, and independent of each other. Let
and
denote the cumulative distribution functions of time-
island-specific shocks received by standard and substandard firms, respectively. The term
is an exogenous process that controls the time-
dispersion of both
distributions; notice that the dispersion indicator is known one period in advance. The mean of both distributions is assumed to be time-invariant, and that of the standard technology is normalized to one:
,
.
The role of the two-types assumption will be made explicit in section 2.4, when we discuss the banking sector. As of now, it suffices to note that firms which draw the substandard type in a given period do not operate in equilibrium. Therefore, in what follows our notation refers to standard-type firms only, unless otherwise indicated.
At the beginning of period , effective capital is combined with labor to produce units of final good,
, according to a Cobb-Douglas technology,
There is a representative, perfectly competitive capital producer. In each period , after production of final goods has taken place, the capital producer purchases the stock of
depreciated capital
from firms. Used capital can be transformed into new capital on a one-to-one basis. Capital producers also purchase final goods in the amount
, which are used to produce new capital goods also on a one-to-one basis. Therefore, the total supply of new capital goods is given by
. Capital goods are sold to firms at the end of the period for production in the following period. In equilibrium, the price of capital goods
equals one and capital producers make zero profits.
In each island there exists a representative bank. Only the bank on island has the technology to obtain perfect information about firms on that island (including their type: standard
or substandard), monitor them, and enforce their contractual obligations.16This effectively precludes firms from obtaining funding from other sources,
including households or institutional investors. As indicated before, banks finance firms in the form of perfectly state-contingent debt. After production in period
, island
's firm pays the bank the entire cash flow from the investment project,
. The gross return on the bank's assets is thus the product of an aggregate component,
, and an island-specific component,
.
Regarding the liabilities side of its balance sheet, the bank borrows from institutional investors by means of one-period risky debt contracts.17 Under
the latter contract, at the end of period the bank borrows funds from the institutional investor in the amount
, and agrees to pay back a non-state-contingent amount
at the beginning of time
. At that point, the proceeds from the
bank's assets,
, exceed the face value of its debt,
, if and only if the island-specific shock
exceeds a threshold level
given by
For non-defaulting banks, we assume that a random fraction of them close down for exogenous reasons each period, at which point the net worth accumulated in each bank is reverted
to the household.18 The remaining fraction
of banks continue operating. For the latter, the flow of dividends distributed to the household is given by
When borrowing from the institutional investor, the bank faces two constraints. First, a participation constraint requires that the expected payoff to the institutional investor from lending to the bank exceeds the expected payoff from lending at the riskless rate
. The latter is given by
, where we have used the household's Euler equation and the bank's balance sheet constraint. Therefore, the
participation constraint takes the form
Second, we introduce a risk-shifting moral hazard problem on the part of the bank, in the spirit of Adrian and Shin (2013). We assume that, once the bank has received the funding, it may choose to invest in either of the two firm types (standard and substandard) within its island. As explained
in section 2.2, both types differ in the distribution of island-specific shocks, and
. We make the following assumptions.
Assumption 1 states that the substandard technology has lower mean return and is thus inefficient. Assumption 2 states that the distribution function cuts
precisely once from below, at a point denoted by
.20 As we will see, these
assumptions imply that the bank may be tempted to invest in the substandard technology, despite its lower expected return. In order to induce the bank to invest in the standard firm type, the institutional investor imposes an incentive compatibility (IC) constraint. Let
denote the value function at time
of a non-defaulting, continuing bank, to be defined below. The IC constraint requires that the expected payoff of financing the standard firm exceeds that of financing the substandard one,
![]() |
Part (i) of Lemma 1 implies that, when choosing between investment strategies, the bank trades off the higher mean return of investing in standard firms against the lower put option value. Part (ii) implies that the incentive to invest in
substandard firms, as captured by the gain in put option value
, increases initially with the normalized debt burden
and eventually surpasses the loss in mean return
. This static reasoning contains the essence of the mechanism through which the bank may be tempted to finance substandard
technologies, even though the actual IC constraint (eq. 9) is intrinsically dynamic due to the presence of the continuation value
.
We are ready to spell out the bank's maximization problem. Let
denote the bank's value function after paying out dividends and at the time of borrowing from the institutional investor. We then have the following Bellman
equations:
![]() |
![]() |
According to (12), the (normalized) debt repayment
is set such that the gain in mean return from investing in the standard firm segment exactly compensates the bank for the loss in put option value. According to (13), the bank's demand for assets equals its net worth times a leverage ratio
which is equalized across islands. Notice that leverage
decreases with the left tail risk of the bank's portfolio, as captured by the put option value
. Intuitively, since all the downside risk in the bank's assets is born by the institutional investor, a higher perception of such risk
leads the latter to impose a tighter leverage constraint.
Once
and
have been determined, it is straightforward to obtain the
actual loan size,
, and its face value,
. Finally, the gross interest rate equals
.
A representative, perfectly competitive institutional investor collects funds from households in the form of deposits and equity, and lends these funds to banks through short-term risky debt. Its balance sheet is thus
, where
. There is no friction in the relationship between households and institutional investors. We assume that equity is sufficiently high to absorb aggregate risk
and thus make deposits effectively safe.24 The institutional investor operates economy-wide and hence perfectly diversifies its portfolio across
islands.
The institutional investor's return from financing the island- bank is
. Aggregating across islands and
subtracting gross interest payments on deposits, we obtain the return on the institutional investor's equity,
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() |
Aggregate net worth of banks at the end of period ,
, is the sum of the net worth of both continuing and new banks:
. From (11) and
, we have that
. Aggregating across islands, we obtain the total net worth of continuing banks,
where we have used the fact that
is distributed independently from
. Banks that default or exit the market exogenously are replaced by an equal number of new banks,
. We assume each new bank is endowed by households with a fraction
of total assets at the beginning of the period,
.25
Therefore,
. We thus have
Aggregate net dividends to households from banks are given by
. Market clearing for
capital requires that total demand by firms equals total supply by capital producers,
. Total issuance of state-contingent claims by firms must equal total demand by banks,
. Using (3) to solve for firm
's labor demand
, aggregating across islands and imposing labor market clearing, we have
Having laid out our model in the previous section, it is now worthwhile to explore some of its theoretical properties and transmission mechanisms.
Appendix D summarizes the equilibrium conditions in our model, and compares it with a standard RBC model. As we show there, the RBC model shares all its equilibrium conditions with our model, except for the investment Euler equation, given by
A recent financially oriented literature argues that the volatility of returns on the assets held by borrowers is a key determinant of their leverage. For example, Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009) analyze how an increase in the volatility of asset prices leads investors to demand higher margins, thus forcing borrowers to deleverage. Similarly, Fostel and Geanakoplos (2008) and Geanakoplos (2010) consider shocks that not only decrease the expected asset returns but also their volatility; these shocks, which the authors refer to as `scary bad news', lead to tighter margins as lenders protect themselves against increased uncertainty. From a more macro perspective, recent work following the lead of Bloom (2009) suggests that exogenous changes in volatility are an important driving force behind business cycle fluctuations (see e.g. Arellano et al., 2012; Bloom et al., 2012; Christiano et al., 2014; Gilchrist et al., 2010; Kiley and Sim, 2011). Much of this literature is inspired by the 2007-9 financial crisis, in which higher 'uncertainty' or 'risk' perception (concepts that are closely related to that of volatility) about the solvency of financial intermediaries is widely believed to have played an important role.
In the standard RBC model, the absence of the financial wedge
implies that shocks to cross-sectional volatility,
, have no effect whatsoever in the latter model. In our framework, on the contrary, the presence of financial frictions opens a link between cross-sectional volatility in asset
returns, bank leverage, and investment dynamics.
We now make two further assumptions on the distributions of island-specific shocks.
Both assumptions are relatively weak. They require that, following an increase in the dispersion of island-specific shocks, downside risk (as measured by the put option values and
) goes up for both firm types, and that it does so by more for the substandard firms.
Under our distributional assumptions, an increase in the standard deviation of island-specific shocks,
, induces a reduction in the leverage ratio of banks, via a mechanism sketched in Figure 3. The upper subplot represents the steady-state counterpart of
the IC constraint (eq. 12). The upward-sloping line is the gain in left tail risk from investing in the substandard firm segment,
, which is an increasing function of the default
threshold or (normalized) debt repayment,
.27 The horizontal
line is the loss in mean return,
. The IC constraint requires that the gain in left tail risk from investing
in the substandard technology does not exceed the loss in mean return; since the constraint is binding in equilibrium,
is determined by the intersection of both lines. Consider now an increase in cross-sectional volatility,
. Under Assumption 4, ceteris paribus the
schedule rotates upwards and
goes down. Intuitively, since higher volatility makes it more attractive for the bank to invest inefficiently, the institutional investor reduces the (normalized) face value of
debt so as to discourage the bank from doing so.
The lower subplot of Figure 3 represents the steady-state counterpart of the participation constraint,
, in
space. The latter is an upward-sloping relationship.28 Ceteris paribus, the increase in
has a double effect on leverage. First, the
participation constraint schedule rotates down as a result of Assumption 3, which reduces leverage for a given
. Intuitively, higher volatility of island-specific shocks increases the downside risk
of the bank's assets, which reduces the investor's expected payoff; in order to induce the investor to lend, the bank reduces its demand for funds as
a fraction of its net worth. Second, the reduction in
through the IC constraint produces a leftward movement along the leverage schedule, thus further reducing leverage. Both effects are mutually
reinforcing.
In an influential paper, Gertler and Karadi (2011; GK) introduce leverage-constrained financial intermediaries (banks) in a standard DSGE framework. In their model, banks are leverage-constrained due to a moral hazard problem different from our risk-shifting specification. In this section, we compare both frameworks, focusing on the differences in modelling choices and the resulting implications for the transmission mechanisms.
GK abstract from cross-sectional uncertainty in firms' project returns and hence in banks' asset returns. An immediate implication is that bank leverage is independent of volatility shocks in their framework. In our model, the presence of cross-sectional uncertainty, coupled with limited liability and risk-shifting moral hazard on the part of banks, gives rise to a volatility-leverage channel, by which volatility shocks affect real economic activity via the leverage ratio of financial intermediaries.
Even if one abstracts from cross-sectional uncertainty in the payoff of the investment projects that are financed in equilibrium (those of standard-type firms), our framework continues to feature a volatility-leverage channel. To see this, consider the special case in which the standard
technology has no island-specific uncertainty:
for all
and
, while the substandard technology retains its uncertainty.29 In this case, bank debt is
riskless and the participation constraint collapses to
. Under parametric conditions analogous to those of Proposition 1, the participation constraint continues to bind in
this simplified model version. Therefore, the interest rate on bank debt equals the risk-free rate,
, and the face value of debt equals
, as in GK. The default threshold if the bank chooses to fund substandard projects can be expressed as
.
To further facilitate the comparison between both models, we may assume that, conditional on funding the substandard firms, banks are forced to pay off the resulting earnings as dividends and close down, i.e. if the bank chooses the
lottery. Our IC constraint then becomes
![]() |
Therefore, the volatility-leverage channel per se does not depend on the presence of cross-sectional uncertainty in the projects that are financed in equilibrium. Allowing for the latter, however, introduces equilibrium default risk in bank debt, which in turn introduces a risk premium in the required return on bank debt.
We calibrate our model to the US economy for the period 1984:Q1-2011:Q3. The parameters are shown in Table 3. We may divide the parameters between those that are standard in the real business cycle literature, and those that are particular to this model. From now onwards, we let variables without time subscripts denote steady-state values.
Parameter | Value | Description | Source/Target |
![]() |
0.99 | discount factor |
![]() |
![]() |
0.36 | capital share | ![]() |
![]() |
0.025 | depreciation rate | ![]() |
![]() |
1 | inverse labor supply elasticity | macro literature |
![]() |
0.5080 | steady-state TFP | ![]() |
![]() |
0.9297 | autocorrelation TFP | FRBSF-CSIP TFP |
![]() |
0.0067 | standard deviation TFP | FRBSF-CSIP TFP |
Non-standard parameters
Parameter | Value | Description | Source/Target |
![]() |
0.0373 | steady-state island-spec. volatility | average leverage (![]() ![]() |
![]() |
1.2691 | variance substandard technology |
![]() |
![]() |
0.001 | mean substandard technology | average volatility of equity |
![]() |
0.0207 | equity injections new banks | ![]() |
![]() |
0.75 | continuation prob. banks | annual dividends
![]() |
![]() |
0.9457 | autocorr. island-specific volatility | NBER-CES manuf. TFP |
![]() |
0.0465 | std. dev. island-specific volatility | NBER-CES manuf. TFP |
We set the RBC parameters to standard values. In particular, we set
,
,
, which are broadly consistent with long-run averages for the real interest rate, the labor share, and the investment to capital ratio. We target a capital-output ratio of
, with is consistent with a ratio of investment over GDP of 20 percent,
roughly in line with the historical evidence. We then have
. Our functional forms for preferences are standard:
,
. We set
, in line with other macroeconomic studies (e.g. Comin and Gertler, 2006). We assume an AR(1) process for the natural log of TFP,
where
. Our empirical counterpart for
is the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco-CSIP quarterly log TFP series, after being linearly detrended. We then choose
and
so as to match their empirical counterparts.
is chosen such
that steady-state output is normalized to one.
Regarding the non-standard parameters in our model, our calibration strategy is as follows. Ideally, one would consolidate the balance sheets of the different financial subsectors so as to calibrate the model to the leveraged financial sector as a whole. As explained in section 1, this
consolidation is however not feasible, due to the existence of cross-positions among financial subsectors and the need to avoid double-counting. For this reason, we choose the average across subsectors of the mean leverage ratios in the sample period as target for the steady-state leverage ratio:
. If we were to interpret bank debt in the model as repo, then the haircut would be
; the latter is roughly in line with average haircuts for repos backed by corporate debt and private-label ABS, as documented by Krishnamurthy et al. (2012). The same
authors show that the spread between repo rates for the same collateral categories and the Fed funds rate was close to zero in the pre-crisis period. Based on this, we target a spread in bank debt of 25 annualized basis points. The gross interest rate then equals
. The face value of bank debt (normalized by assets) is then
. This implies a default threshold of
.
Island-specific shocks are assumed to be lognormally distributed, both for the standard and the substandard firm segment,
![]() ![]() |
Regarding the parameters of the substandard technology, and
, we
make use of the IC constraint in the steady state,
where
is given by expression (21) in the steady state. We thus have one equation for two unknowns,
and
. We set
to 0.001 so as to replicate the midpoint of the range of standard deviations of equity in Table 2, and then use the IC constraint to
solve for
. The standard deviation of (log)shocks to standard firms is thus
times that of their substandard counterparts.
Finally, the exogenous bank continuation rate and the bank equity injection parameter
are calibrated as follows. In the steady state, the law of motion of bank net worth (eq. 14) becomes
We follow the lead of the traditional RBC literature by exploring how well TFP shocks can explain the unconditional patterns found in the data. Table 4 displays the second-order moments of interests.35 For comparison, we also show the range of moments across subsectors for the 1984-2011 sample (see Table 2), as the model is calibrated with data from this period.
Standard deviation (%) | Data: 1984-2011 | Model: Both shocks | TFP | Volatility |
GDP | 1.03 | 1.08 | 1.00 | 0.38 |
Assets | ![]() |
0.58 | 0.36 | 0.45 |
Leverage | ![]() |
6.09 | 0.21 | 6.09 |
Equity | ![]() |
5.83 | 0.32 | 5.82 |
Correlations
Correlation | Data: 1984-2011 | Model: Both shocks | TFP | Volatility |
Leverage - Assets | ![]() |
0.49 | 0.49 | 0.63 |
Leverage - Equity |
![]() |
-0.996 | -0.12 | -0.998 |
Leverage - GDP |
![]() |
0.31 | -0.10 | 0.87 |
Assets - GDP | ![]() |
0.41 | 0.41 | 0.59 |
As shown by the third column of Table 4, conditional on TFP shocks the model replicates fairly well the standard deviation of GDP. However, the model fails dramatically at reproducing the volatility of intermediary leverage and equity. It also fails to produce any meaningful procyclicality in the leverage ratio, or to capture the high negative correlation between leverage and equity.36
To understand these results, Figure 4 displays the impulse responses to a one-standard-deviation fall in TFP (black dashed line).37 On impact, the fall in TFP produces a fall in the return on banks' assets, which in turn reduces their equity. However, the leverage ratio barely reacts. Intuitively, TFP shocks barely affect banks' incentives to invest in the substandard as opposed to the standard firm segment, and have thus little effect on the leverage constraint imposed by investors. Since bank leverage remains stable, bank assets basically reproduce the response of bank net worth; that is, the effects of TFP shocks on bank credit operate mainly through the bank equity channel.
In section 3, we analyzed the volatility-leverage channel from a theoretical, partial equilibrium perspective. Here we assess such a mechanism from a quantitative, general equilibrium point of view. With this purpose, we simulate the model conditional on shocks to cross-sectional volatility. The results are shown in the fourth column of Table 4. Volatility shocks generate large fluctuations in the leverage ratio and equity of banks, comparable to those in the data. The fluctuations in output are relatively modest. In terms of correlations, volatility shocks produce a strong positive comovement between leverage and assets. It also generates a strong procyclicality in leverage with respect to GDP, which actually exceeds the upper bound in the empirical range.38
To understand these results, the solid line in Figure 4 displays the responses to a one-standard-deviation increase in cross-sectional volatility. The shock produces a drastic reduction in the leverage ratio of banks, which is mirrored by a symmetric increase in the
haircuts imposed on bank debt. This results in a large fall in the amount of bank debt financed by investors, . The associated reduction in debt repayments (
) implies that bank net worth actually increases in subsequent periods. However, the drop in leverage dominates the increase in net worth, as evidenced by the fall in bank
assets. This produces a contraction in the capital stock, investment and aggregate output.39
Finally, the second column in Table 4 shows the combined effects of both TFP and volatility shocks in the model. The existence of two uncorrelated sources of fluctuations reduces the correlation of leverage and GDP to a level within the empirical range. Regarding the standard deviations, the model underpredicts the volatility of bank assets, while capturing fairly well the size of fluctuations in bank leverage and equity.
So far we have studied the model's ability to replicate business cycle statistics in the postwar period. In this section we change our focus and ask the following question: how well can the model explain the evolution of financial intermediaries' balance sheets and GDP during the Great Recession of 2008-09?
One implementation issue that arises in this exercise is the following. Our empirical proxy for the volatility process of island-specific shocks, the NBER-CES industry database, runs through 2005 only. We thus follow an alternative approach in order to infer the sequence of volatility shocks up
until 2011. In particular, we use our model in order to filter out the sequence of both TFP and volatility shocks. We use as observables (i) the same TFP series that we used to calibrate the TFP process ( ), and (ii) a series of bank equity capital (
), both in log-deviations from a linear trend.40 As regards the bank equity series, ideally one would like to have a consolidated equity capital series for the leveraged financial sector as a whole. However, as explained before, it is not possible to consolidate the balance
sheets of the different leveraged subsectors, because the latter include cross positions that cannot be netted out. Thus, for the purpose of this exercise we choose the US-chartered commercial banking sector (by far the largest in the US in terms of balance sheet size) as an empirical counterpart
for the bank balance sheet variables in the model (equity, leverage, and assets).41Since we are now using a different series to infer the volatility
shocks, we estimate the parameters of the volatility process (
,
) using Bayesian estimation; we also estimate the parameter
, which is an important determinant of bank equity dynamics. For all three parameters we adopt priors centered around their calibrated values in Table 3. The sample period is again 1984:Q1-2011:Q3.
Param. | Prior dist. | Prior mean | Prior s.e. | Post. mean | Post. conf. interval |
![]() |
Beta | 0.9457 | 0.025 | 0.9275 | 0.8952 - 0.9613 |
![]() |
Inv. gamma | 0.0465 | 0.10 | 0.0451 | 0.0110 - 0.0829 |
![]() |
Beta | 0.75 | 0.10 | 0.4024 | 0.3361 - 0.4703 |
Table 5 reports the estimation results. The posterior means of the volatility process parameters are very close to their prior means. The posterior estimate of is sensibly lower
than its prior mean. The reason is that in the model there is a positive relationship between
and the standard deviation of bank equity.42 Since the model is estimated with data on commercial banks' equity, and the latter has relatively low volatility (see Table 2), this leads to a relatively low posterior estimate for
. It would be natural to take this value as a lower bound.
Once the model has been estimated, we can use the Kalman smoothing algorithm to obtain the model-implied dynamics for real GDP ( ), bank leverage (
), and bank assets (
), and then compare the latter with the
actual historical series.43This provides an out-of-sample test for the model's ability to explain the observed dynamics in output and balance sheet
aggregates.
The left panel of Figure 5 shows the historical series for TFP for the period 2005-2011, i.e. the years around the Great Recession. The first column of Figure 6 compares for the same period the historical GDP and balance-sheet series with those generated by the model conditional on TFP shocks. All variables are expressed as log change relative to their 2005:Q1 value. The fall in TFP that started in 2008:Q1 explains part of the output fall during the recession, but it fails to replicate its depth and especially its duration. Moreover, the TFP shock is completely unable to explain the observed fall in leverage and total assets of the commercial banking sector during and after the recession.
The right panel of Figure 5 shows the smoothed series for the volatility process during 2005-2011. The increase in the latter during the 2008-9 recession is consistent with different measures of cross-sectional dispersion based on firm-level data (see e.g. Bloom et al. 2012, Christiano et al. 2014, and the references therein). The second column of Figure 6 performs the comparison between data and model-generated series conditional on volatility shocks. The sharp increase in volatility that starts at the beginning of 2008 explains part of the reduction in GDP during the Great Recession, as well as its prolonged duration. Furthermore, the rise in volatility explains well the contraction in bank leverage and assets that took place both during and after the recession. Once both shocks are combined (third column of Figure 6), we find that the model basically replicates the sharp and protracted fall in GDP, whereas it matches fairly well the actual dynamics in bank leverage and assets around the Great Recession period.
Summing up, the model is able to replicate the dynamics of both financial variables (banking assets and leverage) and real economic activity during the 2007-9 financial crisis through a combination of a fall in TFP and an increase in volatility. The latter is key to explain the sharp deleveraging and the contraction in banks' balance sheets, as well as the protracted duration of the recession.
The exercises presented above indicate that the model is able to roughly replicate the data in a number of dimensions. In particular, it can explain the observed intermediary leverage cycles as the result of exogenous changes in cross-sectional volatility. In this section, we use the model to
analyze how different levels of average cross-sectional volatility may affect the macroeconomy. We may indeed consider a scenario in which financial innovation allows banks to better diversify their risks. In terms of the model, this amounts to a reduction in the
steady-state volatility of island-specific shocks, The question then is: what is the effect of this financial innovation both on the mean level and the
volatility of output?
To answer this question, we study the behavior of the model as we lower from its baseline value in Table 3. For the purpose of this exercise, we simulate the model with both TFP
and volatility shocks. Figure 7 displays the results.44 The left panel displays the mean values of leverage (
) and output (
), whereas the right panel displays their standard deviations. In this
case the simulated series have not been filtered, as we need to preserve the means and we do not compare model results with filtered data.
As shown in the figure, a reduction in cross-sectional uncertainty allows banks to increase their leverage on average, through a mechanism very similar to the one explained before. For a given net worth, higher leverage allows banks to expand the size of their balance-sheets. This in turn leads to an increase in the stock of capital, and hence in the average level of output. Therefore, financial innovations that improve risk diversification induce an economic expansion on average via an increase in capital accumulation. This result is not controversial and has been confirmed by historical evidence, as discussed in Kindleberger (1986).
The effects on the volatilities are more striking. A reduction in cross-island volatility generates an increase in the volatility of output. For lack of a better name, we have named this effect `the risk diversification' paradox, even though such a paradox is only apparent. A reduction in cross-island volatility increases the mean leverage of the banking sector, which in turn increases the size of fluctuations in leverage. The consequence is that a reduction in cross-island volatility leads to larger fluctuations in total intermediated assets. This in turn results in larger fluctuations in the capital stock, and hence in aggregate output.45
The conclusion is that risk diversification has both a positive level effect on economic activity, and a negative effect through an increase in aggregate volatility, where the latter is due to higher mean leverage. The optimal size of risk diversification will depend on the degree risk aversion of the households, a point that we leave for further research.
We have presented a general equilibrium model with financial intermediation aimed at explaining the main features of the `bank leverage cycle' in the US economy, characterized by large fluctuations in the leverage ratio of financial intermediaries and by a positive comovement between leverage, assets and GDP. Our main theoretical contribution is to introduce Adrian and Shin's (2013) model of intermediary leverage determination, based on a risk-shifting moral hazard problem, into a dynamic general equilibrium setting. Our results indicate that, unlike standard TFP shocks, volatility shocks generate volatile and procyclical bank leverage, thanks to a volatility-leverage channel in which bank default, limited liability and moral hazard play an important role. The model also replicates well the observed contractions in leverage, assets and GDP during the 2008-9 recession.
Consistently with most of the macro-finance literature (Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist, 1999; Kiyotaki and Moore, 1997; Gertler and Kiyotaki, 2010; Christiano, Motto and Rostagno, 2014, etc.), our model only considers short-term debt on the liabilities side of banks' balance sheets. In reality, financial intermediaries are also funded by long-term debt and other more stable sources of funding such as deposits. These debt contracts will be in general more "sticky" across the business cycle, thus reducing the procyclicality of leverage. This may also explain why leverage is more procyclical for intermediaries that rely heavily on short-term funding, such as security broker/dealers. The inclusion of long-term bank debt is therefore a model extension that is worth undertaking in further work.
Our analysis attributes a causal role to variations in cross-sectional volatility as a source of fluctuations in intermediary leverage and aggregate economic activity. It is in principle possible that such changes in cross-sectional volatility represent an endogenous response to alternative shocks; see the discussion on this issue in Christiano, Motto and Rostagno (2014) and the references therein. In this regard, Baker and Bloom (2011) provide some support for causal nature of volatility shocks.
Finally, this study has adopted a positive focus. We believe that understanding the effects of unconventional monetary policy interventions in this kind of framework may constitute an important topic for future research.
Data on equity capital and total assets of the four leveraged financial subsectors we consider (US-chartered commercial banks, savings institutions, security brokers and dealers, and finance companies) are from the Z.1 files of the US Flow of Funds.46 The series corresponding to savings institutions are the sum of OTS and FDIC reporters. Data on levels in the Z.1 files (denoted by 'FL' in the series
identifier) suffer from discontinuities that are caused by changes in the definition of the series. The Flow of Funds accounts correct for such changes by constructing discontinuities series (denoted by 'FD').47 In particular, for each series the flow (denoted by 'FU') is equal to the change in level outstanding less any discontinuity. That is: FU = FL
- FL
- FD
. Therefore, the flow data are free from such discontinuities. In order to construct discontinuity-free level series, we take the value of the level in the
first period of the sample and then accumulate the flows onwards.
For each subsector, the leverage ratio is the ratio between total assets and equity capital, both in dollars. In the tables and figures, 'assets' refer to real total assets, which are total assets (in dollars) divided by the GDP Implicit Price Deflator. The latter and Real GDP are both from the Bureau of Economic Analysis. Both series are readily available at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database.48
In order to obtain an empirical proxy for aggregate log TFP, we use the quarterly change in the Business sector log TFP series (labelled 'dtfp') constructed by the Center for the Study of Income and Productivity (CSIP) at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.49 We then accumulate the log changes to obtain the log level series.
Finally, in order to construct a proxy for island-specific volatility, we use the annual TFP series for all 4-digit SIC manufacturing industries constructed by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and the US Census Bureau's Center for Economic Studies (CES).50 The data run through 2005, so our sample period in this case is 1984-2005. We discard those industries that exit the sample in the mid-nineties due to the
change in industry classification from SIC to NAICS. We then log and linearly detrend each industry TFP series. Our proxy for the time series of (annual) island-specific volatility is the cross-sectional standard deviation of all industry TFP series in each year. We may denote the latter by
, where
is the year subscript. Assuming that the
underlying quarterly process is
, with
, and that each annual observation corresponds to the last quarter in the year, then the annual process satisfies
, and
. The sample autocorrelation and
variance of
are 0.7997 and 0.0205, respectively, which imply
and
.
In the text, we have defined
. Using integration by parts, it is possible to show that
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() |
We start by defining the ratio
and using the latter to substitute for
. Given the choice of investment size
, the bank then chooses the ratio
. With this transformation, and abusing somewhat the notation
and
in the main text, the bank's maximization problem can be expressed as
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
|||
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() ![]() |
|
![]() |
|
![]() |
|
![]() |
0 | ![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
|||
![]() |
|||
![]() |
0 | ![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
|||
![]() |
|||
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
The participation constraint (holding with equality) is given by
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() |
Our model can be reduced to the following 11-equation system,
![]() |
(S2) |
![]() |
(S3) |
![]() |
(S4) |
![]() |
(S6) |
![]() |
(S7) |
![]() |
(S8) |
![]() |
(S9) |
![]() |
(S10) |
![]() |
(S11) |
The standard RBC model is given by equations (S1) to (S5), plus the following investment Euler equation,
![]() |
(S6') |