The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Are Recoveries from Banking and Financial Crises Really So Different?

Greg Howard, Robert Martin, and Beth Anne Wilson

NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.


Abstract:

This paper studies the behavior of recoveries from recessions across 59 advanced and emerging market economies over the past 40 years. Focusing specifically on the performance of output after the recession trough, we find little or no difference in the pace of output growth across types of recessions. In particular, banking and financial crisis do not affect the strength of the economic rebound, although these recessions are more severe, implying a sizable output loss. However, recovery does change with some characteristics of recession. Recoveries tend to be faster following deeper recessions, especially in emerging markets, and tend to be slower following long recessions. Most recessions are associated with a slowing, if not outright decline in house prices, but recessions with large declines in house prices also tend to have slower recoveries. Long recessions and those associated with poor housing-market outcomes can lead to sustained output losses relative to pre-crisis trends. Consistent with microeconomic studies showing permanent income loss to job-losing workers during recessions, we find that the sustained deviation in output from trend is associated with a reduction in labor input, especially linked to declines in employment and labor-force participation following recessions. On net, our results imply that the output/employment gap following a severe, long recessions is considerably smaller than is typically assumed by standard macro models, which in turn may have substantial implications for macroeconomic policy during recoveries.

Keywords: International, business cycles, recoveries, labor market, potential output, United States

JEL classification: E32 , E20, F44


More than two years after the date the NBER set for the end of the U.S. recession, U.S. employment growth remains sluggish, the housing market is moribund, and GDP has barely exceeded its pre-recession peak. Thus, attention is increasingly focusing on the determinants and characteristics of recoveries. Although research on the causes and types of recessions is legion, there has been surprisingly little academic work that concentrates on recoveries.1 That said, two stylized facts have been frequently cited in the current policy discussion. The first is that recoveries from banking and financial crises are typically slow, reflecting impaired financial intermediation and the need for structural adjustment (see Cerra and Saxena (2008) and Reinhart and Reinhart (2010)). The second is that the rate of growth following deep recessions is typically faster than average, given pent-up demand and large stocks of underutilized labor and capital. As the Great Recession was both a banking and financial crisis and associated with a deep decline in output, these stylized facts imply different trajectories for output growth in this recovery.

To address this uncertainty and to gain greater insight into the nature of recoveries, defined as output growth following recession troughs, we examine quarterly data on GDP over the past 40 years for almost 60 countries, split roughly evenly between the advanced and the emerging market economies, resulting in observations on 271 recessions. Classifying recessions according to whether or not they included a banking or financial (B&F) crisis we find, in contrast to earlier work, that there is little distinction in the pace of recovery across recession types. Although recessions associated with B&F crises are typically more severe, the subsequent recoveries are not particularly unusual. Earlier work, finding the opposite, does so because it characterizes the pace of recoveries by averaging growth starting from the pre-recession cyclical peak rather than the recession trough, thus confounding the strength of the recession with the behavior of the recovery.

We do, however, find that, independent of whether a recession is associated with a banking or financial crisis, the depth and duration of the recession do have some predictive power for the pace of recoveries. Deeper recessions are associated with slightly stronger growth during the first three years of recovery. Recessions of greater duration are linked to slower post-trough performance. Also, recessions with large house price declines--a common but not omnipresent feature of long recessions--tend to recover slower than other recessions.

Because banking and financial crises are often both deep and long, these effects on the pace of recovery balance out, leading post-trough growth to be about average and implying that output declines during such severe recessions are not made up quickly. We confirm and extend earlier work showing that severe recessions are associated with sustained negative gaps in the level of output from pre-crisis trend and show that these gaps are attributable to reductions in the utilization of labor - particularly through employment and labor force participation rates.

Until recently in the United States, GDP growth was about on pace with the average recovery in the advanced economies. However, recently the path of output has veered below the average recovery and is well below what would be predicted given the depth and duration of the Great Recession. However, once the impact of the severe decline in housing prices is accounted for, the recovery becomes less surprising. In addition, the composition of the recovery has been unusual.2 Exports and non-residential investment have outperformed the median recovery so far, but consumption, housing, and employment have languished. Looking more closely at these components, we find surprising strength in consumption of goods, in particular large durable goods such as cars and household furniture which one might think would be particularly restrained in this recovery. On the other hand, services consumption in almost every category is weaker than ever before in a post-war U.S. recovery. Likewise, even compared with other "jobless" recoveries, the weakness in employment is omnipresent and extreme.

Following this introduction, section II of the paper describes the dataset and recession classification system used. Section III presents our results, provides robustness checks, and contrasts our work with previous findings. Section IV focuses on characterizing and comparing the current U.S. recovery with past U.S. experience. Section V concludes.


II.  Data and Methodology

For our cross-country comparisons, our database contains an unbalanced panel of quarterly GDP data for 59 countries - 26 advanced economies (AEs) and 33 emerging market economies (EMEs) - from 1970 (or whenever we begin to have quarterly GDP data) to present. Most data are from national sources, and a full list of countries can be found in appendix A. For comparability across countries, recessions are classified as two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth. If a single quarter of positive growth occurs surrounded by a recession on either side, it is included in the recession. The pre-recession peak is defined as the last quarter before the beginning of a recession while the recession trough is the last quarter of the recession. As will be discussed further, we check the robustness of our results using a variety of other recession-dating methodologies found in the literature including the Bry-Boschen procedure for quarterly data (henceforth called the BBQ method) as described by Harding and Pagan (2002).3

Using our definition of recession, our sample contains 271 recessions; 137 occurring in the advanced economies and 134 in the emerging market economies (table 1). If the Great Recession is excluded, the sample of recessions is reduced to 224 episodes (116 AE and 108 EME). The greater number of AE recessions reflects the fact that quarterly GDP data are available for those countries earlier than for most of the EMEs. (See appendix B for data range for each country in our sample.)

In our analysis, we divide our sample by the type of economy - emerging market or advanced - and by type of recession. For comparability with earlier work, we match up the list of banking and financial crises found in IMF work by Laeven and Valencia (2008) with the list of recessions from the above procedure to identify if the downturn coincides with a currency, banking, or debt crisis.4 Laeven and Valencia identify crises in the year of occurrence. For each recession, if a crisis occurred in a year during which the recession began or was ongoing, or if the recession began in the first or second quarter of a year immediately following a crisis, it was classified as being related to that crisis. Using this method, we identify 8 recessions in the advanced economies and 39 recessions in the emerging economies as being related to a crisis.

We also classify housing price slumps for a smaller sample of OECD countries for which we have a long time series of quarterly data on house prices. For these countries, we identify cycles in real house prices. Because the housing market is highly cyclical, most recessions are associated with periods of real house price decline. We identify periods of severe housing market stress as those associated with declines in real house prices above the median. We identify 35 recessions associated with severe housing slumps in the advanced economies. A list of countries, recession dates, and recession types is found in appendix A.

As with other work in this area, much of our analysis will be in the form of butterfly charts, allowing us to compare the behavior of output around cyclical downturns across numerous recessions and countries. In our case, however, instead of indexing the output series for each recession to be 100 at the pre-recession peak, we index the level of GDP to 100 at the date of the recession trough. This allows us to isolate the trajectory of the recovery, which is the key focus of our paper. We typically look at the 12 quarters before and after the trough. Because we have observations on so many recessions, it is not informative to chart individual recessions for most of our analysis. To summarize the cross-country experience, we calculate the mean value of output at each quarter across recession observations to construct the average path of GDP before and after the trough. Our results are not qualitatively different if medians are constructed. Using means allows us to create standard error bands around our average output paths.


III.  Results

A.  Banking and Financial Crises

As a first look, we construct the average path of GDP around recession troughs for our entire sample, excluding the Great Recession (figure 1). On average in a recession in our sample, output falls 4½ percent from the pre-recession peak to the trough.5 GDP then rises at an average annual pace of 3¾ percent for the next three years, putting the level of output roughly 12 percent higher than at the trough. Splitting the sample between advanced economies and emerging market economies (figure 2), shows, not surprisingly, that the EMEs have more extreme cycles, both in terms of the severity of recessions and the rapidity of recoveries. For the average EME recession, output falls 6½ percent from peak to trough, compared to 2½ percent for the AEs. And the average annual pace of EME recovery is 5 percent over the three years following the trough, almost 2 percentage points faster than that in the AEs, leaving the level of output in the EMEs about 6 percentage points higher than that in the advanced economies.

As mentioned earlier, we have classified recessions by type, depending on whether they were associated with banking and financial crises. Over our sample, excluding the current recession, 8 advanced economies have experienced B&F crises out of a sample of 116 - or roughly 6½ percent of all AE recessions.6 The frequency of banking and financial crises is a much higher 36 percent (or 39 out of 108) for the emerging market economies. Because of this, and the more pronounced behavior of output around EME recessions, we separate our sample into advanced and emerging market economies throughout the paper so country composition does not distort our conclusions.

As seen in figures 3 and 4, the pace of output growth upon exiting a recession, shown in the region to the right of the recession trough, is remarkably similar for both the advanced and emerging economies. Recoveries from banking and financial crises appear identical in pace to recoveries from other types of recessions. Table 2 presents the results of regressions of the level of GDP one, two, and three years after the trough on a constant and a dummy for whether the crisis was associated with a banking and financial crisis. For both the advanced economies and the emerging markets, the coefficient on banking and financial crises comes in highly insignificant. There appears to be little evidence that the pace of output differs in recovery depending on whether the recession is related to a banking and financial crisis.

This result is surprising given the stylized fact and the standard interpretation of the previous empirical work (Reinhart and Reinhart, 2010; Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009; Claessens et al., 2008 and Terrones et al, IMF WEO, 2009) that finds that recoveries from banking crises are slow.7 A key reason for the divergence in results is that earlier analysis has indexed the level of GDP to the pre-recession peak, rather than the trough. As can be seen in figures 3 and 4, there are significant differences in the severity of recessions associated with B&F crises. The red lines in the region to the left of the trough are all higher and fall more sharply. Indeed, running similar regressions on the level of GDP one, two, and three years prior to the trough show that the coefficient on banking and financial crises is large and significantly positive in most cases - indicating a sharper decline during the recession for B&F crises (table 3). Indexing to the peak confounds the strength of the recession and the behavior of the recovery, as can be seen when we re-index our data to the pre-recession peak (figures 5 and 6). Our results are consistent with findings that banking and financial crises are associated with greater declines in output and slower returns to pre-crises levels or trends, but this is because the recessions were deeper rather than because of disparities in the pace of recovery.

To confirm that indexing is central to our differences with the previous literature, we also ran robustness tests using the alternative methods of dating recessions and country samples for the AEs used in earlier work. Figures 7 and 8, display the output paths around the trough for the various samples of AE countries experiencing B&F crises found in Reinhart and Rogoff or Terrones et al. for both the two-quarter and the BBQ method of dating recessions. For the Reinhart and Rogoff recessions (excluding the Great Depression), the average path of GDP after a recession for B&F crises follows closely or is even stronger than our own, while the Terrones sample is just a touch weaker. To a first order, differences in recession classification and country sampling do not appear to alter our results. Figures 9 and 10 present similar results for the emerging economies, though only for Reinhart and Rogoff, as Terrones et al. does not cover emerging economies.8

B.  Housing Slowdowns

Given the collapse in housing markets in a number of countries during the recent recession, we also looked at historical experiences with recoveries associated with severe slumps in housing markets. Our analysis is limited to the 18 advanced economies for which we could obtain reasonable historical data on housing markets and we define housing slumps simply in terms of changes in real house prices using quarterly OECD data starting in 1970.

The quarterly house price data are volatile, so to define a housing price slump we smooth each country's data using an HP filter with the low parameter of 100 and then look for local maxima and minima in the smoothed series. Returning to the unsmoothed data with the dates of the local peaks and troughs, we calculate the duration and depth of house price declines across the sample. Our methodology identifies 57 periods of house price declines, covering a significant portion of countries and time periods (occasionally across multiple recessions). For the United States (figure 11), this process identified four periods of real house price decline: the mid-1970s, the early 1980s, a brief period around 1990, and the most recent downturn. To classify a severe housing slump, we pick only the more sizable declines, those above the median. (For the United States, only the current housing slump would be classified as severe.) In these cases, the decline in real house prices is greater than 19 percent. They last for an average of 6½ years and fall an average of 33 percent.

Our paper focuses on the cyclicality of GDP, not real house prices, so our final step is matching housing slumps to recessions. We do this simply: if any quarter of the recession overlaps with any quarter of the housing slump, we classify the recession as associated with a severe housing slump. There are 35 such recessions.

Dividing the OECD sample into recessions associated with severe housing slumps and those without reveals some interesting patterns. In particular, as shown in figure 12, housing-slump recessions tend to be longer and deeper and recoveries from these recessions are significantly slower. Table 4 runs a simple regression showing similar results.

C.  Depth and Duration

Our result that the pace of growth after the trough of recessions associated with financial crises are similar to other recessions is somewhat surprising and leads to questions about what we know about recoveries following severe recessions more generally. In particular, how accurate is the second stylized fact that deep recessions are associated with faster bouncebacks? To address the questions, we characterize all recessions in terms of their depth - the decline in the level of GDP from peak to trough - and duration - the number of quarters from peak to trough. Figures 13 and 14 present histograms of the depth of the recessions in our sample for the advanced and emerging market economies, along with selected summary statistics, excluding the Great Recession. As mentioned above, the average decline in output for the AEs is 2.6 percent, with 12 percent of recessions associated with declines of more than 5 percent. The right tail is even more elongated for the EMEs, with the average decline being 6.4 percent, but 17 percent of the sample seeing output loss of 10 percent or greater. Figures 15 and 16 present the same analysis for recession duration. Not surprisingly, for both sets of countries, there is a mass of recessions lasting 2 quarters (the duration of output decline that defines a recession in our work). For the advanced economies, the average recession length is about 3 quarters with almost 30 percent of the sample experiencing output declines for a year or more. For the EMEs, the duration is more extreme. The average EME recession lasts a year, and 45 percent of recessions last more than a year with one, that for post-Soviet Russia, of almost 6 years.

In Figures 17 through 20, we construct butterfly charts around the trough for recessions that are above the top 25th percentile in depth and duration and below the bottom 25th percentile for the AFEs and EMEs. In terms of recession depth, the charts certainly suggest that deeper recessions are associated with sharper bouncebacks than shallower recessions for both types of countries. The average level of output is 5 percent higher three years after a deep recession in the AEs and the EMEs. The results are different for long recessions. Here the average recovery appears slightly weaker following long recessions in the advanced economies, especially in the first few years. For the EMEs, there appears little difference between recoveries following long recessions than those following short recessions.

To provide a bit more rigorous look at this, table 5 presents the results of regressions of the level of GDP in the advanced economies one, two, and three years following a recession trough on the depth and duration of the recession, a dummy for whether the recession is associated with a banking or financial crisis, and a constant. Unlike with banking and financial crises, both depth and duration significantly affect the path of recovery, particularly in the first year. For example, for every 1 percentage point increase in recession depth, the level of output one year after the trough is a little over ½ percentage point greater. In contrast, a recession that is 1 quarter longer is associated with a similar-sized reduction in the pace of recovery. Over time, the drag from a longer recession appears to dissipate while the level of output is still roughly ½ percentage point higher following deep recessions. The results are even stronger for regressions on EME recessions (table 6). For these economies, a quarter longer recession is associated with a 1 percentage point lower level in output a year after the trough and 1½ percentage point lower level in output three years later. In contrast, a 1 percentage point greater decline in the level of output during the recession is associated with a ½ percentage point higher level of output rising to ¾ percentage point greater level by year three of the recovery. In all three versions, the coefficients on length and depth come in statistically significantly and with opposite signs.

In the previous literature, financial and banking crises have been linked to severe recessions - implying both deeper and longer downturns - which may explain why we are failing to get statistically significant effects of banking and financial crises - these impacts may be cancelling each other out. To check this, we take a closer look at the relationship between banking and financial crises and severity of recessions. Figures 21 and 22 present scatterplots of the depth and duration of recessions, again dividing countries by whether they are considered advanced or emerging market economies. Individual banking and financial crises are represented by the yellow dots and all other recessions are captured by the black dots. The vertical and horizontal lines represent the average duration and depth of recessions, respectively--yellow lines capturing the averages for banking and financial crises and black lines the average duration and depth for all other recessions. What was somewhat surprising to us is that banking and financial crises are not universally longer and deeper. Judging by the distance between the yellow and black lines, for the AEs, B&F crises tend to be longer but not much deeper than all other types of recessions. The reverse is true for the EMEs. For these economies, B&F recessions are associated with deeper but not much longer recessions. Table 7 details the summary statistics behind these charts. Prior to the Great Recession, the correlation between length and depth was .36 for the AEs and a much stronger .67 for EMEs.

D.  Implications

What do our results imply should be the pace of the current recovery? To show this, we use the coefficients from our three regressions above to predict the pace of recovery at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough based on observed depth and duration in the current recession9. Figures 23 through 24 illustrate the results of this exercise. The solid black line represents the pace of recovery predicted for all AEs and EMEs, respectively, given the average depth and duration of the Great Recession and the red line represents the path of actual average AE or EME GDP in the current recovery. The pace of recovery in the AEs appears to be underperforming while that in the EMEs seems right on track.

Turning to the United States, figure 25 compares the current U.S. recovery to past recoveries in the advanced economies. Although the U.S. Great Recession was longer and deeper than almost all previous U.S. and advanced economy recessions and was accompanied by extreme financial disruptions, the U.S. recovery aligned well with average AE recoveries until the first half of 2011 when the pace of recovery slowed sharply. However, figure 26 shows that the actual path of recovery is well below what would be predicted by our simple model of depth and duration, suggesting other factors, possibly related to the financial crisis, may be at play this time around.10 One could ask if generalization from overall AE experience to the U.S. economy is appropriate given its relatively high average growth rate and greater flexibility. In simple tests, however, we were unable to find compelling evidence that U.S. recoveries are typically faster than AE recoveries in general (tables 8 and 9).

E.  Permanent Versus Transitory, or Does the Economy Ever Actually "Recover"

Despite the differences in recovery rates we have highlighted above for recessions that are long or deep, recovery rates across recessions are still quite similar. This implies that long and deep recessions are associated with large and sustained losses to output. In particular, the economy will not return to its long-term trend, implying a persistent gap between the pre-crisis trend and the post-crisis level of output. This result is consistent with Cerra and Saxena (2008) which finds that large output losses associated with financial crises are highly persistent.

Our work also suggests that large declines in output over long periods of time can have more permanent effects on the level of output. For example, using the regression results for the advanced economies, the pace of recovery is the same after a recession of 2 quarters duration that results in a 2 percent decline in output and one of twice that length and duration - suggesting a greater potential permanent loss in output from the more severe recession.

To press this result further, we conduct a series of exercises to test whether output returns to pre-recession trend levels. To do this, we face both a conceptual and a practical challenge. Often, macroeconomic data are detrended using HP or Kalman filters. Both of these techniques are two-sided moving average filters. This implies that the view of the past changes as the data evolves. In particular, and of great importance here, these detrending tools cannot accommodate a permanent deviation from trend. For this reason, we choose to use a simple exponential trend which can accommodate such long-lasting deviations. Even with this methodology, determining the appropriate pre-recession trend is somewhat tricky, to the extent that banking and financial crises are associated with bubbles or positive deviations from trend prior to the crisis. To avoid including the bubble in our trend, we calculate the four-year average growth rate for each country, two years prior to the peak, thus excluding the often rapid period of growth before the crisis. (The results are similar using average growth calculated over different pre-peak intervals.)

Having calculated a pre-recession trend, we then examine GDP as a percentage of this trend (figures 27 and 28) for the average recession and from particularly mild and severe recessions. Average GDP in the advanced economies never recovers to trend, even for short and shallow recessions. However, the average recession in the emerging economies does return to trend, and exceeds trend for short and shallow recessions. But, as for the AE recessions, for deep and long EME receesions, GDP does not drift back toward 100 percent of the pre-crisis trend, even after 10 years. For both AEs and EMEs, deep and long recessions lead to a sustained loss from pre-recession trend of about 8 to 10 percent after 10 years. While varying the specification of our regressions or the definition of pre-crisis trend can modify these loss estimates, these exercises all suggest a more sustained hit to output from severe recessions.

Another way of testing if GDP returns to its pre-crisis trend is to evaluate whether growth rates immediately after recessions differ from long-run average growth. We have examined this, first, by constructing scatterplots for the AE and EME countries of average growth over the sample for each country and average pace of growth three years after a recession trough (figures 29 and 30). If growth in recoveries proceeds at about average pace, then the points should line up close to the 45 degree line, indicating no quick return to pre-recession trend levels. In these charts, average growth seems very close to the pace of growth during recoveries. We also include a variable in our depth and duration regression to capture average pre-recession growth. It is possible that countries with faster trend growth experience faster growth coming out of recoveries. If these countries are also associated with greater propensity (or less) to experience banking and financial crises, then our estimates of post-trough growth may be biased. As seen in in table 10, pre-crises growth rates come in statistically insignificant - suggesting the average pace of growth prior to the recession does not affect the post-recession recovery rate.

Shifting back to our comparison with Cerra and Saxena, they find that B&F crises lead to permanent losses in output. Given our results on depth and duration, one might ask whether their result is purely a reflection of the depth and duration of the downturns associated with financial crises or is there something special about financial crises above and beyond the contour of the downturn which leads to permanently lower output? There are differences in methodology and data between the two studies - Cerra and Saxena restrict their analysis to the initial shock stemming from the first year of a banking crisis, focus solely on banking crises (treating currency and debt crises as separate), use simulations from VAR analysis to estimate the impact of banking crises, and compare banking crises to non-crisis growth performance whereas we draw comparisons to other recessions. Despite these differences, we can shed some light on this question.

Using the sample of non-crisis recessions, we regress the level of post-trough GDP on the depth and duration of the crisis, similar to table 5, but with a sample restricted to non-crisis recessions and of course without the B&F crisis explanatory variable. This gives us a prediction for the recovery given a recession of a certain depth and duration. We use the model to create a prediction for a recovery after a non-B&F related recession that has the same depth and duration of an average B&F crisis. Finally, we compare the prediction to the average of actual outcomes of B&F crises. Figures 31 and 32 show that the average recovery and the prediction are almost identical. There appears to be nothing inherently special about banking and financial crises that creates more of an output loss than similarly sized recessions unassociated with crises. Combining this simple experiment with our earlier results, we conclude that any recession of similar magnitude to a B&F crisis may lead to sustained losses in the level of output.

F.  A Simple Look at What Doesn't Recover

Our work above suggests that the level of GDP, particularly after long and deep recessions, does not recover to its pre-crisis trend even five years after the start of a recession, thus it is important to understand what is driving this sustained output loss. In general, even for the advanced economies, it is a challenge to get comparable quarterly time series data across countries to allow a more granular look at post-recession behavior. One exception is a dataset developed by and detailed in Ohanian and Raffo (2011) which contains quarterly information on total hours, labor-force participation, employment, and average weekly hours for 15 OECD countries from 1960 to the 2010.11 With these data we can examine the broad supply-side components of output - total hours and output per hour - to see where the weakness in overall GDP lies following a recession. Figure 33 shows, for the smaller sample used here, the average behavior of the level of GDP as a percentage of pre-recession trend - divided into those that were particularly severe (in the top 25th percentile of depth and duration) and all others. In both cases, the level of output fails to return to the pre-recession trend, with the gap being particularly sizable (about 7½ percent) for severe recessions. Figures 34 and 35 break output down into total hours and output per hour for both sets of recessions. Interestingly, for typical recessions, the loss in output is a reflection of declines in both productivity and labor input. In contrast, for severe recessions, the sustained deviation in the level of output from trend is more than entirely accounted for by a loss in total hours - productivity actually increases relative to trend.

We next decompose total hours into labor-force participation, the employment rate, and average weekly hours (figure 36 through 38). Interestingly, whereas the workweek returns and even exceeds its pre-recession trend relatively quickly, employment and labor-force participation rates remain depressed - particularly after long and deep recessions. These results suggest the decline in output relative to pre-crisis trend, especially after severe recessions, is importantly concentrated in a reduction in the utilization of labor. For particularly bad recessions, the reduction in the employment and labor force participation rates is sustained even five years after the pre-recession peak.


IV.  The Current U.S. Recovery in More Detail

With the general knowledge of the features of recoveries in hand, we can now turn to characterizing the current U.S. recovery in more detail. The butterfly chart in figure 39 shows the evolution of U.S. GDP around the trough of every recession since 1947, separating the 1980s downturn into two recession periods.12 The thick black line denotes the current recession. Only the downturn in 1980 had a more sluggish pace of recovery two years after the trough.

This anemic post-recession performance is not a reflection of weak outcomes in the manufacturing sector. After falling dramatically in the recent recession industrial production (figure 40) has since climbed at an about-average pace and real exports (figure 41) have surged nearly 25 percent. Non-residential investment (shown in figure 42) tells a similar story. The fall in investment was larger than in any previous recession, leaving a tremendous gap between the current level and the peak, but the pace of investment growth during the recovery has been on the high end of the more recent historical experiences.

On the other hand, unusually poor recovery is evident in consumption and housing. The level of real private consumption (figure 43) has fallen behind every recession except the 1980 double dip. Residential investment remains below its level at the trough of the recession (figure 44) and house prices have underperformed all previous recoveries (figure 45).

A number of factors appear to be contributing to these areas. Credit growth, even outside of mortgage lending, has fallen further since the recession trough (figure 46) - undoubtedly reflecting tighter lending conditions but also weak demand. Consumer sentiment has also improved little over the past two years (figure 47) as income growth has been particularly slow (figure 48) and employment has languished (figure 49). Consumption performance has shown some variation - with goods consumption, especially for durables and motor vehicles, picking up at about on average pace (figures 50 to 52) but services consumption is markedly weaker than in previous recoveries (figure 53). Employment growth has been weak across the board but like consumption, relatively worse in in the services industries than the goods industries (figure 54 and 55). Also of note is the unusual behavior of state and local employment which was rising at a relatively slow pace prior to the recession and has shown declines matched only by the recession in 1980, with little hope of improvement going forward (figure 56).

The policy response in this recovery has been mixed. Monetary policy, even excluding long-term asset purchases and other non-traditional programs, has been larger than in most previous recoveries with the real federal funds rate (figure 57) remaining in negative territory two years after the recession trough. In contrast, government expenditures (figure 58), which had risen sharply during the recession, has leveled off noticeably since then especially compared with earlier recoveries. Further, although revenue fell more than in other recessions, the revenue growth following the recession is on the high end of previous recoveries (figure 59).

Finally, we apply similar supply-side analysis to the United States as above to the OECD countries.13 Re-indexing to the peak and taking deviations from a simple exponential pre-recession trend, shows that 2½ years after the recession trough the level of output in the United States is strikingly below trend (figure 60). This gap is driven entirely by a lack of hours (figure 61), as labor productivity has returned to trend (figure 62). As with the OECD results more generally, this hours gap reflects a downshift in labor force participation and employment rather than the workweek (figure 63 to 65).


V.  Conclusion

We take away several key points from our work on recoveries. First, whether a recession is associated with a banking or financial crisis does not have a statistically significant effect on the pace of growth following recession troughs. This result surprised us and raises questions for future research about the exact channels through which banking and financial crises affect growth. In comparison, as might be expected, recoveries from recessions associated with severe housing downturns are found to be slower.

Second, the depth and duration of a recession does matter for recovery speed. Deeper recessions are associated with faster post-trough recoveries, in line with the view that pent-up demand and underutilized resources can contribute to a sharp snapback. In contrast, longer recessions are associated with slower post-trough growth, possibly reflecting skill and capital deterioration as recessions drag on. Banking and financial crises are associated with more severe recessions - deeper in the case of emerging market economies and longer in the case of the advanced economies - but do not appear to impose additional restraint to recoveries beyond the depth and duration. Currently, the emerging market economies are recovering as would be predicted given the depth and duration of their Great Recession experiences, but the advanced economies, including the United States, are lagging.

Third, we expand on earlier work in the literature that finds evidence that recessions, especially severe recessions, are associated with persistent negative deviations in the level of GDP from pre-crisis trend. This deviation appears to importantly reflect the lower utilization of labor, particularly a decline in employment and labor force participation rates from earlier trend levels. Going forward, it will be important to examine these results in line with what we know from the micro labor literature about skill deterioration, hysteresis, and long-term unemployment. Finally, we may need to reexamine the assumptions in many of our macro models that output levels eventually return to trend or reevaluate the concept of trend.

For the United States, the current recovery has been weaker than would have predicted based on the depth and duration of the recession alone. Without question, the labor market has performed particularly weakly - with especially tepid employment growth and a sharp decline in labor force participation. These developments raise questions about the financial and fiscal channels that affect labor demand and about the role of policy in the face of long and deep recessions.


References

Cerra, Valerie and Sweta Chaman Saxena, "Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery," American Economic Review, 2008, 98:1, p. 439-457.

Claessens, Stijn, M. Ayhan Kose, and Marco E. Terrones, "What Happens During Recessions, Crunches, and Busts?" IMF Working Paper, WP/08/274, December 2008.

Harding, Don and Adrian Pagan, "Dissecting the Cycle: a methodological investigation," Journal of Monetary Economics, 2002, vol 49, p 365-381.

Laeven, Luc and Fabian Valencia "Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database," IMF Working Paper, 08/224, November 2008.

Lopez-Salido, David and Edward Nelson, "Postwar Financial Crises and Economic Recoveries in the United States," mimeo, 2010.

Ohanian, Lee E and Andrea Raffo, "Hours Worked over the Business Cycles: Evidence from OECD Countries, 1960-2010," mimeo, 2011.

Romer, Christina and David Romer, "What Ends Recessions?" NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1994, vol. 9, p13-80.

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Vincent R. Reinhart, "After the Fall" NBER Working Paper Series, Nuxmber 16334, September 2010.

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kennth S. Rogoff, "The Aftermath of Financial Crises," NBER Working Paper Series, Number 14656, January 2009.

Terrones, Marco E., Alasdair Scott, Prakash Kannan, "From Recession to Recovery: How soon and how strong?" International Monetary Fund World Economic Outlook, April 2009, Chapter 3.

Table 1

 TotalAdvanced
Economies
Emerging Market
Economies
All Recessions271137134
Excluding Great Recession of which...224118104
Banking or Financial Crisis47839
Housing Related--35--

Table 2

 

One year after: CoefficientOne year after: Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after: Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Advanced Economies: B&F-1.051.23-0.281.571.301.78
Advanced Economies: Constant103.99 106.48 108.75 
Advanced Economies: R-squared0.00 -0.01 0.00 
Emerging Economies: B&F0.171.090.201.851.252.58
Emerging Economies: Constant106.78 110.90 114.51 
Emerging Economies: R-squared-0.01 -0.01 -0.01 

Table 2 is based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle \frac{GDP_{trough+x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{B\&F}+?$

where x is one, two, or three years, and $ D_{B\&F}$ is a dummy variable for whether the recession was associated with a banking or financial crisis.

A * indicates confidence at the 95 percent level, and a ** indicates confidence at a 99 percent level.

Table 3

 One year prior: CoefficientOne year prior: Std ErrorTwo years prior: CoefficientTwo years prior: Std ErrorThree years prior: CoefficientThree years prior: Std Error
Advanced Economies: B&F0.841.113.20 *1.303.98 *1.67
Advanced Economies: Constant101.28 98.76 95.67 
Advanced Economies: R-squared0.00 0.04 0.04 
Emerging Economies: B&F4.96 **1.258.30 **1.947.84 **2/72
Emerging Economies: Constant102.96 98.67 96.05 
Emerging Economies: R-squared0.08 0.11 0.05 

Table 3 is based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough-x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{B\&F}+?$


Table 4

 One year after: CoefficientOne year after: Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after: Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Advanced Economies: Housing-1.57 *0.71-1.98 *0.83-1.320.95
Advanced Economies: Constant104.52 107.15 109.20 
Advanced Economies: R-squared0.04 0.05 0.01 

Table 4 is based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough-x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_H+?$

where $ D_H$ is a dummy variable for whether the recession was associated with a housing slump.

Table 5

 One year after: CoefficientOne year after: Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after: Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Advanced Economies: Depth0.64 **0.110.61 **0.150.42 **0.18
Advanced Economies: Duration-0.62 **0.20-0.520.27-0.190.32
Advanced Economies: B&F-0.401.170.181.581.271.87
Advanced Economies: Constant104.20 106.45 108.23 
Advanced Economies: R-squared0.20 0.10 0.02 

Tables 5 and 6 are based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough+x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{B\&F}+{\beta }_2Depth+{\beta }_3Duration+?$

where Depth is a positive number measuring the fall in GDP during the recession as a percentage of peak GDP and Duration is the number of quarter from peak to trough.

Table 6

 One year after: CoefficientOne year after: Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after: Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Emerging Economies: Depth0.57 **0.090.62 ** 0.170.85 **0.24
Emerging Economies: Duration-1.07 **0.21-1.30 **0.39-1.61 **0.55
Emerging Economies: B&F-1.590.98-1.601.85-1.342.61
Emerging Economies: Constant107.95 112.68 116.31 
Emerging Economies: R-squared0.19 0.11 0.07 

Table 7a

 Depth: Mean (p=.26)Depth: Std Dev (p=.26)Duration: Mean (p=.00)Duration: Std Dev (p=.00)
Advanced Economies: B&F3.664.075.132.75
Advanced Economies: Others2.582.492.971.36

Table 7b

 Depth: Mean (p=.00)Depth: Std Dev (p=.00)Duration: Mean (p=.20)Duration: Std Dev (p=.20)
Emerging Economies: B&F9.417.314.472.71
Emerging Economies: Others4.925.943.712.80

Table 8

 One year after: CoefficientOne year after:Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after:Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Advanced Economies: U.S. Dummy-0.241.720.372.182.802.46
Advanced Economies: Constant103.93 106.45 108.74 
Advanced Economies: R-squared-0.01 -0.01 0.00 

Table 8 is based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough-x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{US}+?$

where is a dummy variable for whether the recession occurred in the United States.

Table 9

 One year after: CoefficientOne year after: Std ErrorTwo years after: CoefficientTwo years after: Std ErrorThree years after: CoefficientThree years after: Std Error
Advanced Economies: Depth0.64 **0.110.61 **0.150.42 **0.18
Advanced Economies: Duration-0.65 **0.19-0.51 *0.26-0.110.30
Advanced Economies: U.S. Dummy-0.321.520.342.062.872.42
Advanced Economies: Constant104.25 106.41 107.95 
Advanced Economies: R-squared0.20 0.10 0.03 

Table 9 is based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough+x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{US}+{\beta }_2Depth+{\beta }_3Duration+?$

Table 10a

 One year later: CoefficientOne year later: Std ErrorTwo years later: CoefficientTwo years later: Std ErrorThree years later: CoefficientThree years later: Std Error
Advanced Economies:Depth0.50 **0.130.45 *0.200.270.24
Advanced Economies:Duration-0.49 **0.19-0.410.28-0.110.34
Advanced Economies:Pre-crisis Growth-0.050.130.180.190.270.24
Advanced Economies:B&F0.041.020.551.511.701.85
Advanced Economies:Constant103.77 105.46 106.95 

Table 10b

 One year later: CoefficientOne year later: Std ErrorTwo years later:CoefficientTwo years later:Std ErrorThree years later: CoefficientThree years later: Std Error
Emerging Economies: Emerging Economies: Depth0.56 **0.090.64 **0.170.83 **0.26
Emerging Economies: Duration-1.11 **0.21-1.36 **0.39-1.71 **0.58
Emerging Economies: Pre-crisis Growth0.060.120.360.230.520.34
Emerging Economies: B&F-0.151.011.781.912.56 
Emerging Economies: Constant106.96 110.00 112.77 

Tables 5 and 6 are based on a simple linear regression of the form

$\displaystyle 100\frac{GDP_{trough+x}}{GDP_{trough}}={\beta }_0+{\beta }_1D_{B\&F}+{\beta }_2Depth+{\beta }_3Duration+{\beta }_4Trend+?$

where Trend is the 4 year average annual growth in the two years prior to the peak.

Figure 1. Recoveries in the entire sample

Figure 1: Constructs the average path of GDP around recession troughs for our entire sample, excluding the Great Recession. On average in a recession in our sample, output falls 4½ percent from the pre-recession peak to the trough.5 GDP then rises at an average annual pace of 3¾ percent for the next three years, putting the level of output roughly 12 percent higher than at the trough

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 2. Recoveries

Figure 2: Splitting the sample between advanced economies and emerging market economies, shows, not surprisingly, that the EMEs have more extreme cycles, both in terms of the severity of recessions and the rapidity of recoveries. For the average EME recession, output falls 6½ percent from peak to trough, compared to 2½ percent for the AEs. And the average annual pace of EME recovery is 5 percent over the three years following the trough, almost 2 percentage points faster than that in the AEs, leaving the level of output in the EMEs about 6 percentage points higher than that in the advanced economies.

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 3. Recoveries in the Advanced Economies

Figure 3: This figure shows the pace of output growth upon exiting a recession, shown in the region to the right of the recession trough, is remarkably similar for both the advanced and emerging economies. Recoveries from banking and financial crises appear identical in pace to recoveries from other types of recessions.

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 4. Recoveries in the Emerging Economies

Figure 4: This figure shows the pace of output growth upon exiting a recession, shown in the region to the right of the recession trough, is remarkably similar for both the advanced and emerging economies. Recoveries from banking and financial crises appear identical in pace to recoveries from other types of recessions.

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 5. Recessions in the AEs, indexed to peak

Figure 5: Indexing to the peak confounds the strength of the recession and the behavior of the recovery, as can be seen when we re-index our data to the pre-recession peak. Our results are consistent with findings that banking and financial crises are associated with greater declines in output and slower returns to pre-crises levels or trends, but this is because the recessions were deeper rather than because of disparities in the pace of recovery.

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 6. Recessions in the EMEs, indexed to peak

Figure 6: Indexing to the peak confounds the strength of the recession and the behavior of the recovery, as can be seen when we re-index our data to the pre-recession peak. Our results are consistent with findings that banking and financial crises are associated with greater declines in output and slower returns to pre-crises levels or trends, but this is because the recessions were deeper rather than because of disparities in the pace of recovery.

*Solid lines is the mean, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error.

Figure 7. Two-quarter method of dating AE recessions

Figure 7: To confirm that indexing is central to our differences with the previous literature, we also ran robustness tests using the alternative methods of dating recessions and country samples for the AEs used in earlier work. This figure displays the output paths around the trough for the various samples of AE countries experiencing B&F crises found in Reinhart and Rogoff or Terrones et al. for both the two-quarter and the BBQ method of dating recessions. For the Reinhart and Rogoff recessions (excluding the Great Depression), the average path of GDP after a recession for B&F crises follows closely or is even stronger than our own, while the Terrones sample is just a touch weaker.

A country is in a recession during two consecutive quarters of decline or one period of growth surrounded by periods of recession.

Figure 8. BBQ Method of dating AE recessions

Figure 8: To confirm that indexing is central to our differences with the previous literature, we also ran robustness tests using the alternative methods of dating recessions and country samples for the AEs used in earlier work. This figure displays the output paths around the trough for the various samples of AE countries experiencing B&F crises found in Reinhart and Rogoff or Terrones et al. for both the two-quarter and the BBQ method of dating recessions. For the Reinhart and Rogoff recessions (excluding the Great Depression), the average path of GDP after a recession for B&F crises follows closely or is even stronger than our own, while the Terrones sample is just a touch weaker.

A country is in a recession as identified by the procedure outlined in Harding and Pagan (2001)

Figure 9. Two-quarter method of dating EME recessions

Figure 9: To a first order, differences in recession classification and country sampling do not appear to alter our results. This figure presents similar results for the emerging economies, though only for Reinhart and Rogoff, as Terrones et al. does not cover emerging economies.

A country is in a recession during two consecutive quarters of decline or one period of growth surrounded by periods of recession.

Figure 10. BBQ Method of dating, EME recessions

Figure 10: To a first order, differences in recession classification and country sampling do not appear to alter our results. This figure presents similar results for the emerging economies, though only for Reinhart and Rogoff, as Terrones et al. does not cover emerging economies.

A country is in a recession as identified by the procedure outlined in Harding and Pagan (2001)

Figure 11. U.S. House Prices

Figure 11: The quarterly house price data are volatile, so to define a housing price slump we smooth each country's data using an HP filter with the low parameter of 100 and then look for local maxima and minima in the smoothed series. Returning to the unsmoothed data with the dates of the local peaks and troughs, we calculate the duration and depth of house price declines across the sample. Our methodology identifies 57 periods of house price declines, covering a significant portion of countries and time periods (occasionally across multiple recessions). For the United States, this process identified four periods of real house price decline: the mid-1970s, the early 1980s, a brief period around 1990, and the most recent downturn. To classify a severe housing slump, we pick only the more sizable declines, those above the median. (For the United States, only the current housing slump would be classified as severe.) In these cases, the decline in real house prices is greater than 19 percent. They last for an average of 6½ years and fall an average of 33 percent.

Note: Dots indicate turning points

Figure 12. GDP in Select Advance Economies

Figure 12: Dividing the OECD sample into recessions associated with severe housing slumps and those without reveals some interesting patterns. In particular, as shown in this figure, housing-slump recessions tend to be longer and deeper and recoveries from these recessions are significantly slower. Table 4 runs a simple regression showing similar results.

Recessions in severe housing slumps overlap with a period of house price declines over 19 percent.

Figure 13. Recessions in the Advanced Economies

Figure 13: This figure presents histograms of the depth of the recessions in our sample for the advanced and emerging market economies, along with selected summary statistics, excluding the Great Recession. As mentioned above, the average decline in output for the AEs is 2.6 percent, with 12 percent of recessions associated with declines of more than 5 percent. The right tail is even more elongated for the EMEs, with the average decline being 6.4 percent, but 17 percent of the sample seeing output loss of 10 percent or greater.

Figure 14. Recessions in the Emerging Economies

Figure 14: This figure presents histograms of the depth of the recessions in our sample for the advanced and emerging market economies, along with selected summary statistics, excluding the Great Recession. As mentioned above, the average decline in output for the AEs is 2.6 percent, with 12 percent of recessions associated with declines of more than 5 percent. The right tail is even more elongated for the EMEs, with the average decline being 6.4 percent, but 17 percent of the sample seeing output loss of 10 percent or greater.

Figure 15. Recessions in the Advanced Economies

Figure 15: This figure presents the same analysis for recession duration. Not surprisingly, for both sets of countries, there is a mass of recessions lasting 2 quarters (the duration of output decline that defines a recession in our work). For the advanced economies, the average recession length is about 3 quarters with almost 30 percent of the sample experiencing output declines for a year or more. For the EMEs, the duration is more extreme. The average EME recession lasts a year, and 45 percent of recessions last more than a year with one, that for post-Soviet Russia, of almost 6 years.

Figure 16. Recessions in the Emerging Economies

Figure 16: This figure presents the same analysis for recession duration. Not surprisingly, for both sets of countries, there is a mass of recessions lasting 2 quarters (the duration of output decline that defines a recession in our work). For the advanced economies, the average recession length is about 3 quarters with almost 30 percent of the sample experiencing output declines for a year or more. For the EMEs, the duration is more extreme. The average EME recession lasts a year, and 45 percent of recessions last more than a year with one, that for post-Soviet Russia, of almost 6 years.

Figure 17. Recoveries in the Advanced Economies

Figure 17: In this figure, we construct butterfly charts around the trough for recessions that are above the top 25th percentile in depth and duration and below the bottom 25th percentile for the AFEs and EMEs. In terms of recession depth, the charts certainly suggest that deeper recessions are associated with sharper bouncebacks than shallower recessions for both types of countries. The average level of output is 5 percent higher three years after a deep recession in the AEs and the EMEs. The results are different for long recessions. Here the average recovery appears slightly weaker following long recessions in the advanced economies, especially in the first few years. For the EMEs, there appears little difference between recoveries following long recessions than those following short recessions.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error

Extreme recessions are in the top 25% or bottom 25% of observed recessions.

Figure 18. Recoveries in the Emerging Economies

Figure 18: In this figure, we construct butterfly charts around the trough for recessions that are above the top 25th percentile in depth and duration and below the bottom 25th percentile for the AFEs and EMEs. In terms of recession depth, the charts certainly suggest that deeper recessions are associated with sharper bouncebacks than shallower recessions for both types of countries. The average level of output is 5 percent higher three years after a deep recession in the AEs and the EMEs. The results are different for long recessions. Here the average recovery appears slightly weaker following long recessions in the advanced economies, especially in the first few years. For the EMEs, there appears little difference between recoveries following long recessions than those following short recessions.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error

Extreme recessions are in the top 25% or bottom 25% of observed recessions.

Figure 19. Recoveries in the Advanced Economies

Figure 19: In this figure, we construct butterfly charts around the trough for recessions that are above the top 25th percentile in depth and duration and below the bottom 25th percentile for the AFEs and EMEs. In terms of recession depth, the charts certainly suggest that deeper recessions are associated with sharper bouncebacks than shallower recessions for both types of countries. The average level of output is 5 percent higher three years after a deep recession in the AEs and the EMEs. The results are different for long recessions. Here the average recovery appears slightly weaker following long recessions in the advanced economies, especially in the first few years. For the EMEs, there appears little difference between recoveries following long recessions than those following short recessions.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error

Very long recessions last as long or longer than those in the 75th percentiles.

Short recessions lasted two quarters.

Figure 20. Recoveries in the Emerging Economies

Figure 20: In this figure, we construct butterfly charts around the trough for recessions that are above the top 25th percentile in depth and duration and below the bottom 25th percentile for the AFEs and EMEs. In terms of recession depth, the charts certainly suggest that deeper recessions are associated with sharper bouncebacks than shallower recessions for both types of countries. The average level of output is 5 percent higher three years after a deep recession in the AEs and the EMEs. The results are different for long recessions. Here the average recovery appears slightly weaker following long recessions in the advanced economies, especially in the first few years. For the EMEs, there appears little difference between recoveries following long recessions than those following short recessions.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error

Very long recessions last as long or longer than those in the 75th percentiles.

Short recessions lasted two quarters.

Figure 21. Recessions in the Advanced Economies

Figure 21: This figure presents scatterplots of the depth and duration of recessions, again dividing countries by whether they are considered advanced or emerging market economies. Individual banking and financial crises are represented by the yellow dots and all other recessions are captured by the black dots. The vertical and horizontal lines represent the average duration and depth of recessions, respectively--yellow lines capturing the averages for banking and financial crises and black lines the average duration and depth for all other recessions. What was somewhat surprising to us is that banking and financial crises are not universally longer and deeper. Judging by the distance between the yellow and black lines, for the AEs, B&F crises tend to be longer but not much deeper than all other types of recessions. The reverse is true for the EMEs. For these economies, B&F recessions are associated with deeper but not much longer recessions. Table 7 details the summary statistics behind these charts. Prior to the Great Recession, the correlation between length and depth was .36 for the AEs and a much stronger .67 for EMEs.

Figure 22. Recessions in the Emerging Economies

Figure 22: This figure presents scatterplots of the depth and duration of recessions, again dividing countries by whether they are considered advanced or emerging market economies. Individual banking and financial crises are represented by the yellow dots and all other recessions are captured by the black dots. The vertical and horizontal lines represent the average duration and depth of recessions, respectively--yellow lines capturing the averages for banking and financial crises and black lines the average duration and depth for all other recessions. What was somewhat surprising to us is that banking and financial crises are not universally longer and deeper. Judging by the distance between the yellow and black lines, for the AEs, B&F crises tend to be longer but not much deeper than all other types of recessions. The reverse is true for the EMEs. For these economies, B&F recessions are associated with deeper but not much longer recessions. Table 7 details the summary statistics behind these charts. Prior to the Great Recession, the correlation between length and depth was .36 for the AEs and a much stronger .67 for EMEs.

There is one additional black point at (39,23)

Figure 23. The Current AE recovery

Figure 23: The coefficients from our three regressions are used to predict the pace of recovery at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough based on observed depth and duration in the current recession. This figure illustrates the results of this exercise. The solid black line represents the pace of recovery predicted for all AEs and EMEs, respectively, given the average depth and duration of the Great Recession and the red line represents the path of actual average AE or EME GDP in the current recovery. The pace of recovery in the AEs appears to be underperforming while that in the EMEs seems right on track.

*Regression predicts indexed GDP levels at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough, based on the observed depth and duration of the recession.

Figure 24. The Current EME Recovery

Figure 24: The coefficients from our three regressions are used to predict the pace of recovery at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough based on observed depth and duration in the current recession. This figure illustrates the results of this exercise. The solid black line represents the pace of recovery predicted for all AEs and EMEs, respectively, given the average depth and duration of the Great Recession and the red line represents the path of actual average AE or EME GDP in the current recovery. The pace of recovery in the AEs appears to be underperforming while that in the EMEs seems right on track.

*Regression predicts indexed GDP levels at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough, based on the observed depth and duration of the recession.

Figure 25. Recoveries in the Advanced Economies

Figure 25: This figure compares the current U.S. recovery to past recoveries in the advanced economies. Although the U.S. Great Recession was longer and deeper than almost all previous U.S. and advanced economy recessions and was accompanied by extreme financial disruptions, the U.S. recovery aligned well with average AE recoveries until the first half of 2011 when the pace of recovery slowed sharply.

Figure 26. The Current U.S. recovery

Figure 26: This figure shows that the actual path of recovery is well below what would be predicted by our simple model of depth and duration, suggesting other factors, possibly related to the financial crisis, may be at play this time around.

*Regression predicts indexed GDP levels at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough, based on the observed depth and duration of the recession.

Figure 27. Recoveries in the Advanced Economies

Figure 27: Having calculated a pre-recession trend, GDP as a percentage of this trend is examined for the average recession and from particularly mild and severe recessions. Average GDP in the advanced economies never recovers to trend, even for short and shallow recessions. However, the average recession in the emerging economies does return to trend, and exceeds trend for short and shallow recessions. But, as for the AE recessions, for deep and long EME receesions, GDP does not drift back toward 100 percent of the pre-crisis trend, even after 10 years. For both AEs and EMEs, deep and long recessions lead to a sustained loss from pre-recession trend of about 8 to 10 percent after 10 years. While varying the specification of our regressions or the definition of pre-crisis trend can modify these loss estimates, these exercises all suggest a more sustained hit to output from severe recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the four-year average two years prior to the peak

* Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions as measured by both depth and duration. Similarly, shallow and short recessions are in the bottom 25th percentile of each category.

Figure 28. Recoveries in the Emerging Economies

Figure 28: Having calculated a pre-recession trend, GDP as a percentage of this trend is examined for the average recession and from particularly mild and severe recessions. Average GDP in the advanced economies never recovers to trend, even for short and shallow recessions. However, the average recession in the emerging economies does return to trend, and exceeds trend for short and shallow recessions. But, as for the AE recessions, for deep and long EME receesions, GDP does not drift back toward 100 percent of the pre-crisis trend, even after 10 years. For both AEs and EMEs, deep and long recessions lead to a sustained loss from pre-recession trend of about 8 to 10 percent after 10 years. While varying the specification of our regressions or the definition of pre-crisis trend can modify these loss estimates, these exercises all suggest a more sustained hit to output from severe recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the four-year average two years prior to the peak

* Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions as measured by both depth and duration. Similarly, shallow and short recessions are in the bottom 25th percentile of each category.

Figure 29. Growth Rates in the Advanced Economies

Figure 29: Another way of testing if GDP returns to its pre-crisis trend is to evaluate whether growth rates immediately after recessions differ from long-run average growth. We have examined this, first, by constructing scatterplots for the AE and EME countries of average growth over the sample for each country and average pace of growth three years after a recession trough. If growth in recoveries proceeds at about average pace, then the points should line up close to the 45 degree line, indicating no quick return to pre-recession trend levels. In these charts, average growth seems very close to the pace of growth during recoveries. We also include a variable in our depth and duration regression to capture average pre-recession growth. It is possible that countries with faster trend growth experience faster growth coming out of recoveries. If these countries are also associated with greater propensity (or less) to experience banking and financial crises, then our estimates of post-trough growth may be biased. As seen in in table 10, pre-crises growth rates come in statistically insignificant - suggesting the average pace of growth prior to the recession does not affect the post-recession recovery rate.

Average speed during a recovery is measured as GDP growth in the three years after a trough.

Each data point represents one country.

Figure 30. Growth Rates in the Emerging Economies

Figure 30: Another way of testing if GDP returns to its pre-crisis trend is to evaluate whether growth rates immediately after recessions differ from long-run average growth. We have examined this, first, by constructing scatterplots for the AE and EME countries of average growth over the sample for each country and average pace of growth three years after a recession trough. If growth in recoveries proceeds at about average pace, then the points should line up close to the 45 degree line, indicating no quick return to pre-recession trend levels. In these charts, average growth seems very close to the pace of growth during recoveries. We also include a variable in our depth and duration regression to capture average pre-recession growth. It is possible that countries with faster trend growth experience faster growth coming out of recoveries. If these countries are also associated with greater propensity (or less) to experience banking and financial crises, then our estimates of post-trough growth may be biased. As seen in in table 10, pre-crises growth rates come in statistically insignificant - suggesting the average pace of growth prior to the recession does not affect the post-recession recovery rate.

Average speed during a recovery is measured as GDP growth in the three years after a trough.

Each data point represents one country.

Figure 31. B&F crises in the Advanced Economies

Figure 31: This figure shows that the average recovery and the prediction are almost identical. There appears to be nothing inherently special about banking and financial crises that creates more of an output loss than similarly sized recessions unassociated with crises. Combining this simple experiment with our earlier results, we conclude that any recession of similar magnitude to a B&F crisis may lead to sustained losses in the level of output.

*Values from regressions estimating GDP at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough. Regressions are depth and length of recession.

The sample covers recession in advanced economies since 1970.

Figure 32. B&F crises in the Emerging Economies

Figure 32: This figure shows that the average recovery and the prediction are almost identical. There appears to be nothing inherently special about banking and financial crises that creates more of an output loss than similarly sized recessions unassociated with crises. Combining this simple experiment with our earlier results, we conclude that any recession of similar magnitude to a B&F crisis may lead to sustained losses in the level of output.

*Values from regressions estimating GDP at 4, 8, and 12 quarters past the trough. Regressions are depth and length of recession.

The sample covers recession in advanced economies since 1970.

Figure 33. GDP in Select Advanced Economies

Figure 33: This figure shows, for the smaller sample used here, the average behavior of the level of GDP as a percentage of pre-recession trend - divided into those that were particularly severe (in the top 25th percentile of depth and duration) and all others. In both cases, the level of output fails to return to the pre-recession trend, with the gap being particularly sizable (about 7½ percent) for severe recessions.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Figure 34. Total Hours in Select Advanced Economies

Figure 34: This figure breaks output down into total hours and output per hour for both sets of recessions. Interestingly, for typical recessions, the loss in output is a reflection of declines in both productivity and labor input. In contrast, for severe recessions, the sustained deviation in the level of output from trend is more than entirely accounted for by a loss in total hours - productivity actually increases relative to trend.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Data are from Raffo and Ohanian (2010)

Figure 35. Output per Hour in Select AEs

Figure 35: This figure breaks output down into total hours and output per hour for both sets of recessions. Interestingly, for typical recessions, the loss in output is a reflection of declines in both productivity and labor input. In contrast, for severe recessions, the sustained deviation in the level of output from trend is more than entirely accounted for by a loss in total hours - productivity actually increases relative to trend.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Data are from Raffo and Ohanian (2010)

Figure 36. Labor Force Participation in Select AEs

Figure 36: In this figure, we decompose total hours into labor-force participation, the employment rate, and average weekly hours. Interestingly, whereas the workweek returns and even exceeds its pre-recession trend relatively quickly, employment and labor-force participation rates remain depressed - particularly after long and deep recessions. These results suggest the decline in output relative to pre-crisis trend, especially after severe recessions, is importantly concentrated in a reduction in the utilization of labor. For particularly bad recessions, the reduction in the employment and labor force participation rates is sustained even five years after the pre-recession peak.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Data are from Raffo and Ohanian (2010)

Figure 37. Employment Rate in Select AEs

Figure 37: In this figure, we decompose total hours into labor-force participation, the employment rate, and average weekly hours. Interestingly, whereas the workweek returns and even exceeds its pre-recession trend relatively quickly, employment and labor-force participation rates remain depressed - particularly after long and deep recessions. These results suggest the decline in output relative to pre-crisis trend, especially after severe recessions, is importantly concentrated in a reduction in the utilization of labor. For particularly bad recessions, the reduction in the employment and labor force participation rates is sustained even five years after the pre-recession peak.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Data are from Raffo and Ohanian (2010)

Figure 38. Average Weekly Hours in Select AEs

Figure 38: In this figure, we decompose total hours into labor-force participation, the employment rate, and average weekly hours. Interestingly, whereas the workweek returns and even exceeds its pre-recession trend relatively quickly, employment and labor-force participation rates remain depressed - particularly after long and deep recessions. These results suggest the decline in output relative to pre-crisis trend, especially after severe recessions, is importantly concentrated in a reduction in the utilization of labor. For particularly bad recessions, the reduction in the employment and labor force participation rates is sustained even five years after the pre-recession peak.

*Solid lines are means, with dashed lines plus or minus one standard error. Trend is exponential function growing at the 4-year average 2 years prior to the peak. Deep and long recessions are in the top 25th percent of recessions measured by depth and duration.

Data are from Raffo and Ohanian (2010)

Figure 39. GDP During U.S. Recessions

Figure 39: The butterfly chart in this figure shows the evolution of U.S. GDP around the trough of every recession since 1947, separating the 1980s downturn into two recession periods. The thick black line denotes the current recession. Only the downturn in 1980 had a more sluggish pace of recovery two years after the trough.

Note: since 1947.

Figure 40. Industrial Production

Figure 40: Anemic post-recession performance is not a reflection of weak outcomes in the manufacturing sector. This figure shows it falling dramatically in the recent recession industrial production has since climbed at an about-average pace.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 41. Real Exports

Figure 41: This figure shows that real exports have surged nearly 25 percent.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 42. Non-residential Investment

Figure 42: In this figure, the fall in investment was larger than in any previous recession, leaving a tremendous gap between the current level and the peak, but the pace of investment growth during the recovery has been on the high end of the more recent historical experiences.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 43. Private Consumption

Figure 43: In this figure, poor recovery is evident in consumption and housing. The level of real private consumption (figure 43) has fallen behind every recession except the 1980 double dip.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 44. Residential Investment

Figure 44: This figure shows that residential investment remains below its level at the trough of the recession.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 45. Housing Prices

Figure 45: This figure shows that house prices have underperformed all previous recoveries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 46. Consumer Credit

Figure 46: In this figure, credit growth, even outside of mortgage lending, has fallen further since the recession trough - undoubtedly reflecting tighter lending conditions but also weak demand.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 47. Consumer Sentiment (Michigan Index)

Figure 47: This figure shows that consumer sentiment has also improved little over the past two years.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 48. Personal Income

Figure 48: This figure shows that income growth has been particularly slow.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 49. Employment

Figure 49: This figure shows that employment has languished.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 50. Goods Consumption

Figure 50: Consumption performance has shown some variation - with goods consumption, especially for durables and motor vehicles, picking up at about on average pace.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 51. Household Durable Consumption

Figure 51: Consumption performance has shown some variation - with goods consumption, especially for durables and motor vehicles, picking up at about on average pace.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 52. Motor Vehicle Consumption

Figure 52: Consumption performance has shown some variation - with goods consumption, especially for durables and motor vehicles, picking up at about on average pace.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 53. Service Consumption

Figure 53: This figure shows that services consumption is markedly weaker than in previous recoveries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 54. Goods-Producing Employment

Figure 54: In this figure, employment growth has been weak across the board but like consumption, relatively worse in in the services industries than the goods industries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 55. Private Service Providing Employment

Figure 55: In this figure, employment growth has been weak across the board but like consumption, relatively worse in in the services industries than the goods industries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 56. State and Local Government Employment

Figure 56: This figure shows the unusual behavior of state and local employment which was rising at a relatively slow pace prior to the recession and has shown declines matched only by the recession in 1980, with little hope of improvement going forward.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Figure 57. Real Federal Funds Rate

Figure 57: This figure shows that the policy response in this recovery has been mixed. Monetary policy, even excluding long-term asset purchases and other non-traditional programs, has been larger than in most previous recoveries with the real federal funds rate remaining in negative territory two years after the recession trough.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Federal Funds rate minus 4-quarter core inflaction.

Figure 58. Government Expenditures

Figure 58: In contrast to figure 57, this figure shows that government expenditures, which had risen sharply during the recession, has leveled off noticeably since then especially compared with earlier recoveries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Calculated as percent of GDP, then indexed to 100 at the trough of the recession.

Figure 59. Government Revenue

Figure 59: Further, in this figure, although revenue fell more than in other recessions, the revenue growth following the recession is on the high end of previous recoveries.

*See Figure 39 for colors of other recessions.

Calculated as percent of GDP, then indexed to 100 at the trough of the recession.

Figure 60. Gross Domestic Product

Figure 60: Supply-side analysis is applied to the United States as above to the OECD countries. Re-indexing to the peak and taking deviations from a simple exponential pre-recession trend, shows that 2½ years after the recession trough the level of output in the United States is strikingly below trend.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Figure 61. Total Hours

Figure 61: Supply-side analysis is applied to the United States as above to the OECD countries. Re-indexing to the peak and taking deviations from a simple exponential pre-recession trend, shows that 2½ years after the recession trough the level of output in the United States is strikingly below trend. This figure shows that this gap is driven entirely by a lack of hours.

*See Figure 60 for colors of other recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Figure 62. Output per Hour

Figure 62: Supply-side analysis is applied to the United States as above to the OECD countries. Re-indexing to the peak and taking deviations from a simple exponential pre-recession trend, shows that 2½ years after the recession trough the level of output in the United States is strikingly below trend. This figure shows that labor productivity has returned to trend.

*See Figure 60 for colors of other recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Figure 63. Labor Force Participation

Figure 63: As with the OECD results more generally, the hours gap reflects a downshift in labor force participation and employment rather than the work week.

*See Figure 60 for colors of other recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Figure 64. Employment Rate

Figure 64: As with the OECD results more generally, the hours gap reflects a downshift in labor force participation and employment rather than the work week.

*See Figure 60 for colors of other recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Figure 65. Average Work Week

Figure 65: As with the OECD results more generally, the hours gap reflects a downshift in labor force participation and employment rather than the work week.

*See Figure 60 for colors of other recessions.

Trend calculated as exponential function growing at the five-year average prior to the peak

Appendix A. Data by Episode

Duration measured in quarters, Depth as percentage of GDP. Recessions after 2007 are not categorized.
CountryPeakTroughIMFHousingAE/EMEDuration Depth
Argentina1974 Q41976 Q1Currency EME53.6
Argentina1977 Q21978 Q3  EME54.9
Argentina1980 Q31981 Q4Banking, Currency  EME59.8
Argentina1984 Q41985 Q3  EME310.7
Argentina1986 Q31987 Q1Currency EME22.7
Argentina1988 Q11989 Q3Banking EME615.6
Argentina1992 Q31993 Q1  EME23.9
Argentina1994 Q41995 Q3Banking, Currency, Debt  EME35.7
Argentina1998 Q22002 Q1Banking EME1520
Argentina2008 Q32009 Q1  EME21.5
Australia1971 Q31972 Q1  AE21.3
Australia1975 Q21975 Q4  AE22.4
Australia1977 Q21977 Q4  AE20.7
Australia1981 Q31983 Q2  AE73.7
Australia1990 Q41991 Q2  AE21.4
Australia2000 Q22000 Q4  AE20.6
Austria1974 Q31975 Q2  AE32
Austria1981 Q21981 Q4  AE20.8
Austria1982 Q21982 Q4  AE20.4
Austria1983 Q41984 Q2  AE22
Austria1992 Q31993 Q1  AE20.8
Austria2000 Q42001 Q3  AE30.8
Austria2008 Q22009 Q2  AE44.8
Belgium1974 Q21975 Q2  AE42.8
Belgium1976 Q31977 Q2  AE30.8
Belgium1979 Q41980 Q4 HousingAE42
Belgium1982 Q31983 Q1 HousingAE20.7
Belgium1992 Q31993 Q1  AE21.9
Belgium2001 Q22001 Q4  AE20.5
Belgium2008 Q22009 Q2  AE44.1
Brazil1980 Q41981 Q4  EME47.8
Brazil1982 Q31983 Q1Currency, Debt  EME25.5
Brazil1987 Q11987 Q3Currency EME23.1
Brazil1988 Q11988 Q4  EME33.5
Brazil1989 Q41991 Q1Banking EME58.9
Brazil1991 Q31992 Q3Currency EME44.7
Brazil1995 Q11995 Q3Banking EME22.9
Brazil1998 Q21999 Q1Currency EME31.6
Brazil2001 Q12001 Q4  EME31.2
Brazil2008 Q32009 Q1  EME25.6
Canada1981 Q21982 Q4 HousingAE64.4
Canada1990 Q11991 Q1 HousingAE43.3
Canada2008 Q32009 Q2  AE33.6
Chile1971 Q41973 Q2Currency EME68.6
Chile1974 Q21975 Q4  EME616.8
Chile1981 Q21982 Q4Banking, Currency EME619.2
Chile1990 Q11990 Q3  EME21.2
Chile1998 Q21999 Q1  EME34.1
Chile2008 Q22009 Q2  EME44.3
China1971 Q21971 Q4  EME20.2
China1973 Q31974 Q2  EME31.4
China1975 Q31976 Q3  EME44.7
Colombia1982 Q21982 Q4Banking EME21.2
Colombia1998 Q11999 Q2Banking EME56.7
Costa Rica1995 Q31996 Q1  EME22.7
Costa Rica2008 Q12009 Q1  EME43.6
Czech Republic1996 Q41997 Q3Banking EME32.4
Czech Republic2008 Q22009 Q2  EME44.8
Denmark1973 Q31975 Q2  AE74.2
Denmark1976 Q41977 Q2  AE20.3
Denmark1979 Q41981 Q2 HousingAE63.3
Denmark1986 Q31987 Q2 HousingAE30.6
Denmark1992 Q31993 Q2 HousingAE31.9
Denmark1997 Q21997 Q4  AE21
Denmark2000 Q42002 Q4  AE8-0.1
Denmark2008 Q22009 Q3  AE57.3
Estonia1998 Q31999 Q2  EME32.4
Estonia2007 Q42009 Q3  EME720.2
Finland1971 Q21971 Q4  AE20.3
Finland1975 Q11975 Q4 HousingAE32.2
Finland1980 Q31981 Q1  AE22.7
Finland1990 Q11992 Q3BankingHousingAE1012.8
Finland2008 Q12009 Q2  AE510.3
France1974 Q31975 Q2  AE32.8
France1980 Q11980 Q3  AE20.3
France1992 Q11993 Q1  AE41.1
France2008 Q12009 Q2  AE53.9
Germany1974 Q31975 Q1  AE23.4
Germany1981 Q31982 Q4  AE52.2
Germany1985 Q31986 Q1  AE21.2
Germany1992 Q31993 Q1  AE22
Germany1995 Q31996 Q1 BankingAE20.7
Germany2002 Q32003 Q2 BankingAE30.9
Germany2004 Q12004 Q3 BankingAE20.2
Germany2008 Q12009 Q1  AE46.6
Greece1973 Q31974 Q3  AE412.4
Greece1976 Q41977 Q2  AE23
Greece1979 Q21979 Q4  AE23.1
Greece1980 Q21981 Q1  AE35.6
Greece1981 Q31982 Q4  AE54.6
Greece1984 Q31985 Q1  AE22.3
Greece1990 Q11990 Q3  AE27.1
Greece1992 Q31993 Q1  AE23.6
Greece2000 Q12000 Q3  AE21.1
Hong Kong1973 Q41975 Q1  EME54.9
Hong Kong1981 Q41982 Q2  EME22.9
Hong Kong1984 Q21985 Q3  EME54.1
Hong Kong1988 Q41989 Q2  EME21.3
Hong Kong1995 Q11995 Q3  EME20.4
Hong Kong1997 Q31998 Q4  EME58.8
Hong Kong2000 Q42001 Q4  EME42
Hong Kong2002 Q42003 Q2  EME22.5
Hong Kong2008 Q12009 Q1  EME47.6
Hungary1995 Q11995 Q4  EME31.2
Hungary2008 Q12009 Q3  EME68.3
Iceland1982 Q21983 Q2Currency AE43
Iceland1987 Q41988 Q3  AE31.3
Iceland1991 Q11992 Q3  AE64.4
Iceland1997 Q31998 Q1  AE21.4
Iceland2003 Q12003 Q3  AE24.3
Iceland2008 Q12010 Q2  AE912
India1975 Q21976 Q1  EME31.6
India1978 Q11979 Q2  EME58.6
India1981 Q21981 Q4  EME20.2
India1983 Q41984 Q2  EME21.3
Indonesia1997 Q31998 Q4  EME518.2
Ireland1982 Q31983 Q2 HousingAE31
Ireland1985 Q31986 Q2 HousingAE31.3
Ireland2007 Q12009 Q4  AE1111.4
Israel2000 Q42001 Q4  EME43.9
Israel2008 Q32009 Q1  EME21.3
Italy1974 Q21975 Q2  AE43.7
Italy1977 Q11977 Q3  AE21.4
Italy1982 Q11982 Q4CurrencyHousingAE30.9
Italy1992 Q11993 Q1 HousingAE41.5
Italy2001 Q12001 Q4  AE30.6
Italy2002 Q42003 Q2  AE20.5
Italy2004 Q32005 Q1  AE20.1
Italy2008 Q12009 Q2  AE57
Japan1974 Q31975 Q1 HousingAE20.3
Japan1997 Q11998 Q2BankingHousingAE53.2
Japan2001 Q12001 Q4 HousingAE32.1
Japan2008 Q12009 Q1  AE49.9
Jordan1998 Q11998 Q3  EME21.2
Latvia1992 Q11993 Q4Currency EME729.9
Latvia1994 Q31995 Q1  EME23.1
Latvia2007 Q42009 Q4  EME825.4
Lithuania2008 Q22009 Q4  EME617.3
Luxembourg1974 Q21975 Q3  AE58.3
Luxembourg1980 Q21981 Q2  AE40.7
Luxembourg2008 Q12008 Q4  AE35.7
Malaysia1974 Q31975 Q2  EME31.3
Malaysia1984 Q31985 Q3  EME42
Malaysia1997 Q41998 Q4Banking, Currency  EME411.1
Malaysia2000 Q42001 Q2  EME21.1
Malaysia2008 Q22009 Q1  EME36.5
Mexico1982 Q21983 Q2banking, Currency, Debt  EME45.5
Mexico1985 Q31986 Q4  EME54.6
Mexico1987 Q41988 Q2  EME21.3
Mexico1994 Q41995 Q2Banking, Currency  EME29.4
Mexico2000 Q32002 Q1  EME62.6
Mexico2008 Q12009 Q2  EME58.5
Netherlands1974 Q31975 Q2  AE30.8
Netherlands1980 Q11980 Q3 HousingAE22.5
Netherlands2008 Q12009 Q2  AE54.6
New Zealand1970 Q11970 Q3  AE24
New Zealand1971 Q31972 Q1  AE26.5
New Zealand1973 Q11973 Q3  AE27.8
New Zealand1974 Q31975 Q2 HousingAE39.9
New Zealand1977 Q21978 Q1 HousingAE313.1
New Zealand1982 Q31983 Q1  AE24.6
New Zealand1984 Q11984 Q3  AE23.2
New Zealand1985 Q11985 Q3  AE23.1
New Zealand1986 Q31987 Q1  AE27
New Zealand1990 Q41991 Q2  AE23.8
New Zealand1997 Q31998 Q1  AE21.4
New Zealand2007 Q42009 Q1  AE52.4
Norway1977 Q31978 Q1  AE25.9
Norway1978 Q31979 Q2  AE31.2
Norway1980 Q11980 Q3  AE22.5
Norway1991 Q21991 Q4BankingHousingAE20.6
Norway1992 Q31993 Q1 HousingAE21.4
Norway2005 Q32006 Q1  AE20.9
Norway2008 Q22009 Q2  AE42.5
Peru1982 Q11983 Q4Banking, Currency  EME718.3
Peru1985 Q11985 Q3  EME27
Peru1987 Q31989 Q2  EME726.2
Peru1990 Q11990 Q3  EME221.5
Peru1992 Q11992 Q3  EME25.2
Peru1997 Q41999 Q1  EME53.1
Peru2000 Q12000 Q4  EME35
Peru2003 Q22003 Q4  EME20.2
Peru2008 Q32009 Q1  EME22.6
Philippines1983 Q21985 Q3Banking, Currency, Debt  EME916.9
Philippines1990 Q31991 Q1  EME21.4
Philippines1997 Q41998 Q2Banking, Currency  EME22.8
Poland2000 Q42001 Q2  EME20.6
Portugal1974 Q11975 Q2  AE56
Portugal1982 Q41984 Q2Banking, Currency  AE62.7
Portugal1992 Q21993 Q3  AE52.6
Portugal2001 Q42003 Q2  AE62.1
Portugal2004 Q22004 Q4  AE20.2
Portugal2007 Q42009 Q1  AE54
Russia1989 Q21995 Q1  EME2339.1
Russia1995 Q31996 Q3  EME45.4
Russia2008 Q22009 Q2  EME410.9
Singapore1984 Q41985 Q4  EME42
Singapore1997 Q41998 Q3  EME31.3
Singapore2000 Q42001 Q3  EME31.7
Singapore2008 Q12008 Q4  EME32.6
Slovakia1998 Q41999 Q4Banking EME46.7
Slovakia2008 Q32009 Q1  EME26.4
Slovenia2008 Q22009 Q3  EME59.8
South Africa1974 Q31975 Q1  EME21.3
South Africa1976 Q31977 Q2  EME31.3
South Africa1981 Q41983 Q1  EME55.1
South Africa1984 Q21985 Q3Currency, Debt  EME52.8
South Africa1990 Q11992 Q4  EME114.6
South Africa1998 Q11998 Q3  EME20.1
South Africa2008 Q32009 Q2  EME32.6
South Korea1979 Q21980 Q2  EME43.9
South Korea1997 Q31998 Q2Banking, Currency  EME38.1
South Korea2008 Q22008 Q4  EME24.1
Spain1974 Q41975 Q2  AE20.6
Spain1978 Q21979 Q1BankingHousingAE30.4
Spain1980 Q31981 Q2 HousingAE30.3
Spain1992 Q21993 Q2  AE41.8
Spain2008 Q12009 Q4  AE74.9
Sweden1973 Q11973 Q3  AE22.1
Sweden1976 Q41977 Q2  AE23
Sweden1982 Q21983 Q1 HousingAE30.9
Sweden1990 Q41992 Q4BankingHousingAE85.6
Sweden2007 Q42009 Q3  AE77.8
Switzerland1974 Q21975 Q3 HousingAE510.3
Switzerland1977 Q31978 Q1  AE20.6
Switzerland1981 Q21982 Q2  AE41.7
Switzerland1986 Q21986 Q4  AE20.2
Switzerland1990 Q31991 Q2  AE31.4
Switzerland1992 Q11993 Q1  AE41.5
Switzerland2002 Q22003 Q1  AE30.9
Switzerland2008 Q22009 Q2  AE43.2
Taiwan1974 Q11974 Q3  EME22.3
Taiwan2000 Q32001 Q3  EME44.4
Taiwan2008 Q12009 Q1  EME49.5
Thailand1996 Q31998 Q3Banking, Currency  EME814.9
Thailand2008 Q22009 Q1  EME37.6
Turkey1987 Q41989 Q2  EME64.3
Turkey1993 Q41994 Q2  EME211.6
Turkey2000 Q42001 Q2  EME27.5
Turkey2008 Q12009 Q1  EME413.3
United Kingdom1973 Q11974 Q1 HousingAE43.3
United Kingdom1975 Q11975 Q3 HousingAE21.5
United Kingdom1979 Q41981 Q1  AE54.4
United Kingdom1990 Q21991 Q3 HousingAE52.5
United Kingdom2008 Q12009 Q3  AE66.6
United States1973 Q41975 Q1  AE53.3
United States1980 Q11980 Q3  AE22.2
United States1981 Q31982 Q1  AE22.8
United States1990 Q31991 Q1  AE21.2
United States2008 Q22009 Q2  AE45.3
Uruguay1988 Q11988 Q4  EME30.1
Uruguay1994 Q31995 Q1  EME22.2
Uruguay1998 Q31999 Q4  EME55.7
Uruguay2001 Q12002 Q4Banking, Currency, Debt  EME719.6
Venezuela1979 Q21981 Q1  EME73.1
Venezuela1982 Q21983 Q4Debt EME67.6
Venezuela1984 Q21985 Q1Currency EME31.2
Venezuela1988 Q21989 Q3Currency EME511.7
Venezuela1992 Q41994 Q1Banking, Currency  EME52.8
Venezuela1995 Q41996 Q2  EME22.6
Venezuela2000 Q1 2000 Q3   EME21.6
Venezuela2001 Q4 2003 Q1 Currency EME528.6
Venezuela2008 Q4 2010 Q1   EME56.4

Appendix B. Sample Countries

CountryFirst Value
Argentina1970 Q1
Australia1970 Q1
Austria1970 Q1
Belgium1970 Q1
Brazil1970 Q1
Canada1970 Q1
Chile1970 Q1
China1970 Q1
Colombia1970 Q1
Costa Rica1991 Q1
Czech1996 Q1
Denmark1970 Q1
Estonia1995 Q1
Finland1970 Q1
France1970 Q1
Germany1970 Q1
Greece1970 Q1
Hong Kong1970 Q1
Hungary1995 Q1
Iceland1970 Q1
India1970 Q1
Indonesia1970 Q1
Ireland1970 Q1
Israel1970 Q1
Italy1970 Q1
Japan1970 Q1
Jordan1992 Q1
Latvia1992 Q1
Lithuania1995 Q1
Luxembourg1970 Q1
Malaysia1970 Q1
Mexico1970 Q1
Netherland1970 Q1
New1970 Q1
Norway1970 Q1
Peru1980 Q1
Philippine1970 Q1
Poland1995 Q1
Portugal1970 Q1
Russia1970 Q1
Singapore1970 Q1
Slovakia1993 Q1
Slovenia1995 Q1
South Africa1970 Q1
South Korea1970 Q1
Spain1970 Q1
Sweden1970 Q1
Switzerland1970 Q1
Taiwan1970 Q1
Thailand1970 Q1
Turkey1987 Q1
United Kingdom1970 Q1
United States1970 Q1
Uruguay1988 Q1
Venezuela1970 Q1

Footnotes

1.   Notable exceptions being Romer and Romer (1994) and Cerra and Saxena (2008). Return to text

2.   The analysis of the U.S. data goes through the third quarter of 2011. Return to text

3.   The BBQ method identifies cyclical peaks and troughs as local maxima in the two quarters preceding and the two quarters following. It then eliminates maxima that do not alternate between peaks and troughs or do not have a long enough time span, in this case 2 quarters from a peak to trough and five quarters from a trough to peak. Once these criteria are met, recessions are defined as the time between a peak and a trough. We did not use this method because it requires at least 5 quarters of recovery, which would restrict and potentially bias our sample. Return to text

4.   This is similar to the methodology used in the IMF WEO analysis on recessions and recoveries (Terrones et al. 2009). Return to text

5.   This decline is measured as the decline in the average GDP path in our sample. Because recessions are of different duration, the average decline from peak to trough across recessions is a different and slightly higher figure.  Return to text

6.   B&F recessions include Finland (1990), Iceland (1982), Italy (1982), Japan (1997), Norway (1991), Portugal (1982), Spain (1978), and Sweden (1990). Return to text

7.   Complementary to our results, Lopez-Salido and Nelson (2010) find that recoveries are not systemically slower in the aftermath of financial crises in post-war United States. Return to text

8.   Reinhart and Rogoff identify five AE recessions as banking crises. By our dating, the troughs of these recessions occur in: Finland (1992), Japan (1993), Norway (1991), Sweden (1992), and Spain (1979). Terrones et al. add Australia (1991), Denmark (1987), France (1993), Greece (1993), Italy (1993), Japan (1993), New Zealand (1987), the United Kingdom (1974), and the United Kingdom (1991), as well as a crisis in Germany around 1980 which does not correspond to a recession in our sample. In addition to the AEs, Reinhart and Rogoff also identify eight crises in the EMEs, fewer than in our sample: Argentina (2002), Colombia (1999), Hong Kong (1998), Indonesia (1998), Korea (1998), Malaysia (1998), the Philippines (1998), and Thailand (1998). Return to text

9.   Housing declines were common but not universal in the most recent recession, so are not included in this part of the analysis. Including the severe housing downturn as an explanatory variable for the pace of the U.S. recovery, the current recovery is still underperforming the model's expectation but by only one percent. Return to text

10.   Prior to the annual revision in July, the actual path of the U.S. recovery was very close to what would be predicted by the depth and duration regressions. Return to text

11.   The countries included are Australia, Austria, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Norway, Spain, Sweden, the UK, and the US. Return to text

12.   This section of the paper uses recession dating by the NBER in order to include the 2001 recession. The only other notable change is that NBER classifies the pre-recession peak of the Great Recession as 2007 Q3 instead of 2008 Q1. Return to text

13.   For individual recessions, we use the trend based on the average growth in the five years prior to the pre-recession peak because the four-year average two years prior to the peak introduces too much noise. Without the benefit of an average over a large sample, the results are much more difficult to interpret. Return to text


This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text

Home | Economic research and data | Publications and education resources
Accessibility | Contact us
Last update: May 9, 2013