The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2007-53 Screen Reader version

Documentation of the Research and Statistics Division's Estimated DSGE Model of the U.S. Economy: 2006 Version

Rochelle M. Edge, Michael T. Kiley, and Jean-Philippe Laforte*

Keywords: Two-sector growth model, sticky-prices, sticky-wages, habit-persistence, investment adjustment costs, variable utilization, Bayesian estimation

Abstract:

This paper provides documentation for the large-scale estimated DSGE model of the U.S. economy used in Edge, Kiley, and Laforte (2007). The model represents part of an ongoing research project (the Federal Reserve Board's Estimated, Dynamic, Optimization-based--FRB/EDO--model project) in the Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies section of the Federal Reserve Board aimed at developing a DSGE model that can be used to address practical policy questions and the model documented here is the version that was current at the end of 2006. The paper discusses the model's specification, estimated parameters, and key properties.


This paper contains documentation for the large-scale estimated DSGE model of the U.S. economy that was employed in Edge, Kiley, and Laforte (2007) to discuss the use of DSGE models in a policy oriented environment. The model represents part of an ongoing research project in the Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies section of the Federal Reserve Board aimed at developing a DSGE model that can be used to address practical policy questions. The outline of the paper is as follows. Section 1 provides a brief qualitative description of the model. Section 2 outlines the model's production, capital evolution, and preference technologies. Section 3 describes the economy's decentralization, and section 3 defines equilibrium in the model. Section 4 lists the data that is used in estimating the model. Section 5 reports the model's key estimation results, which include the estimated parameter values, variance decompositions, impulse response functions, and implied paths of model variables. The precise equations that characterize equilibrium in this model are contained in the appendix. Appendix A presents the equations of the symmetric model, appendix B reports the equations of the symmetric and stationary model, and appendix C gives the solution to the model's steady-state. Finally, since the model contains a large number of parameter and variable names a key is given in appendices D, E, and F.

Before moving to our presentation of the model, we note that we anticipate that the DSGE model developed in this paper (and subsequent versions of it) will serve as a complement to the analyses that are currently performed using existing large-scale econometric models, such as FRB/US model, as well as smaller, ad hoc models that we have found useful for more specific questions. Our model, while quite a bit more detailed and disaggregated than most existing DSGE models, is nonetheless incapable of addressing many of the questions addressed in a very large model like FRB/US and cannot therefore serve as the sole model for policy purposes. We suspect that model-based analyses are enhanced by consideration of multiple models (and, indeed, our experience suggests that often we learn as much when models disagree than when they agree). The use of multiple models will allow us to examine the robustness of policy strategies across models with quite different foundations, which we view as important given the significant divergences of opinion regarding the plausibility of various types of models.


1 Model Overview and Motivation

Figure 1 provides a graphical overview of the economy described by our model. The model possesses two final goods: slow-growing "CBI" goods--so called because most of these goods are used for consumption (C) and because they are produced by the business and institutions (BI) sector--and fast-growing "KB" goods--so called because these goods are used for capital (K) accumulation and are produced by the business (B) sector. The goods are produced in two stages by intermediate- and then final-goods producing firms (shown in the center of the figure). On the model's demand-side, there are four components of spending (each shown in a box surrounding the producers in the figure): consumer nondurable goods and services (sold to households), consumer durable goods, residential capital goods, and non-residential capital goods. Consumer nondurable goods and services and residential capital goods are purchased (by households and residential capital goods owners, respectively) from the first of economy's two final goods producing sectors (good CBI producers), while consumer durable goods and non-residential capital goods are purchased (by consumer durable and residential capital goods owners, respectively) from the second sector (good KB producers). We "decentralize" the economy by assuming that residential capital and consumer durables capital are rented to households while non-residential capital is rented to firms. In addition to consuming the nondurable goods and services that they purchase, households also supply labor to the intermediate goods-producing firms in both sectors of the economy.

Our assumption of a two-sector production structure is motivated by the trends in certain relative prices and categories of real expenditure apparent in the data. As reported in Table 1, expenditures on consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services and residential investment have grown at roughly similar real rates of around 3-1/2 percent per year over the last 20 years, while real spending on consumer durable goods and on nonresidential investment have grown at around 6-1/2 percent per year. The relative price of residential investment to consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services has been fairly stable over the last twenty years (increasing only 1/2 percent per year on average, with about half of this average increase accounted for by a large swing in relative prices over 2003 and 2004). In contrast, the prices of both consumer durable goods and non-residential investment relative to those of consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services have decreased, on average, about 3 percent per year. A one-sector model is unable to deliver long-term growth and relative price movements that are consistent with these stylized facts. As a result, we adopt a two-sector structure, with differential rates of technical progress across sectors. These different rates of technological progress induce secular relative price differentials, which in turn lead to different trend rates of growth across the economy's expenditure and production aggregates. We assume that the output of the slower growing sector (denoted  X^{cbi}_{t}) is used for consumer nondurable goods and services and residential capital goods and the output of a faster growing sector (denoted  X^{kb}_{t}) is used for consumer durable goods and non-residential capital goods, roughly capturing the long-run properties of the data summarized in Table 1.

The DSGE models of Christiano et al. [2005] and Smets and Wouters [2004] did not address differences in trend growth rates in spending aggregates and trending relative price measures, although an earlier literature--less closely tied to business cycle fluctuations in the data--did explore the multi-sector structure underlying U.S. growth and fluctuations.1 Subsequent models have adopted a multi-sector growth structure, including Altig et al.  [2004], Edge, Laubach, and Williams [2003], and DiCecio [2005]; our model shares features with the latter two of these models.

The disaggregation of production (aggregate supply) leads naturally to some disaggregation of expenditures (aggregate demand). We move beyond a model with just two categories of (private domestic) final spending and disaggregate along the four categories of private expenditure mentioned earlier: consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services (denoted  E^{cnn}_{t}), consumer durable goods (denoted  E^{cd}_{t}), residential investment (denoted  E^{r}_{t}), and non-residential investment (denoted  E^{nr}_{t}).

While differential trend growth rates are the primary motivation for our disaggregation of production, our specification of expenditure decisions is related to the well-known fact that the expenditure categories that we consider have different cyclical properties. As shown in Table 2, consumer durables and residential investment tend to lead GDP, while non-residential investment (and especially non-residential fixed investment, not shown) lags. These patterns suggest some differences in the short-run response of each series to structural shocks. One area where this is apparent is the response of each series to monetary-policy innovations. As documented by Bernanke and Gertler  [1995], residential investment is the most responsive component of spending to monetary policy innovations, while outlays on consumer durable goods are also very responsive. According to Bernanke and Gertler  [1995], non-residential investment is less sensitive to monetary policy shocks than other categories of capital goods spending, although it is more responsive than consumer nondurable goods and services spending.

Beyond the statistical motivation, our disaggregation of aggregate demand is motivated by the concerns of policymakers. A recent example relates to the divergent movements in household and business investment in the early stages of the U.S. expansion following the 2001 recession, a topic discussed in Kohn [2003]. We believe that providing a model that may explain the shifting pattern of spending through differential effects of monetary policy, technology, and preference shocks is a potentially important operational role for our disaggregated framework.


2 Production, Capital Evolution, and Preferences

In this section we present the production, capital evolution, and preference technologies for our model. The long-run evolution of the economy is determined by differential rates of stochastic growth in the production sectors of the economy; its short-run dynamics are influenced by various forms of adjustment costs. Adjustment costs to real aggregate variables are captured in the economy's preference, production, and capital evolution technologies presented in this section. Adjustment costs to real sectoral variables and nominal variables are captured in the decentralization of the model presented in the following section.

2.1 The Production Technology

As noted in the previous section our model economy produces two final goods and services: slow-growing "consumption" goods and services  X^{cbi}_{t} and fast-growing "capital" goods  X^{kb}_{t}. "Capital" goods are produced by businesses; "consumption" goods and services are produced by businesses and institutions. These final goods are produced by aggregating (according to a Dixit-Stiglitz technology) an infinite number of differentiated inputs,  X_{t}^{s}(j) for  s=cbi,kb, distributed over the unit interval. Specifically, final goods production is governed by the function

\displaystyle X^{s}_{t} =\left(\int_{0}^{1} X_{t}^{s}(j)^{\frac{\Theta^{x,s}_{t}-1} {\Theta^{x,s}_{t}}}dj\right)^{\frac{\Theta^{x,s}_{t}} {\Theta^{x,s}_{t}-1}}, s=cbi,kb. (1)

The term  \Theta^{x,s}_{t} is the stochastic elasticity of substitution between the differentiated intermediate goods inputs used in the production of the consumption or capital goods sectors. Letting  \theta^{x,s}_{t} \equiv \ln \Theta^{x,s}_{t}-\ln \Theta^{x,s}_{\ast} denote the log-deviation of  \Theta^{x,s}_{t} from its steady-state value of  \Theta^{x,s}_{\ast}, we assume that
\displaystyle \theta_{t}^{x,s}=\epsilon_{t}^{\theta,x,s} (2)

where  \epsilon_{t}^{\theta,x,s} is an i.i.d. shock process.

The  jth differentiated intermediate good in sector  s (which is used as an input in equation 1) is produced by combining each variety of the economy's differentiated labor inputs  \{L^{s}_{t}(i,j)\}_{i=0}^{1} with the sector's specific utilized non-residential capital stock  K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j). (Utilized non-residential capital,  K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j), is equal to the product of physical non-residential capital,  K^{nr,s}_{t}(j), and the utilization rate,  U^{nr,s}_{t}(j)). A Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator characterizes the way in which differentiated labor inputs are combined to yield a composite bundle of labor, denoted  L^{s}_{t}(j). A Cobb-Douglas production function then characterizes how this composite bundle of labor is used with capital to produce--given the current level of multifactor productivity  MFP^{s}_{t} in the sector  s--the intermediate good  X^{s}_{t}(j). The production of intermediate good  j is governed by the function:

\displaystyle X_{t}^{m,s}(j)\!=\! \left(K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j)\right)^{\alpha} \!\left( Z^{m}_{t}Z^{s}_{t} L_{t}^{x,s}(j)\right)^{1-\alpha} \!\!{\textrm{where }}L_{t}^{x,s}(j)=\!\left(\int_{0}^{1} \!\! L_{t}^{x,s}(i,j)^{\frac{\Theta^{l}_{t}\!-\!1}{\Theta^{l}_{t}}} di \! \right) ^{\frac{\Theta^{l}_{t}}{\Theta^{l}_{t}\!-\!1}} \!\!\!\!\!\!\!\! s=cbi,kb (3)

and where we assume  Z^{cbi}_{t}\equiv 1. The parameter  \alpha in equation (3) is the elasticity of output with respect to capital while  \Theta^{l}_{t} denotes the stochastic elasticity of substitution between the differentiated labor inputs. Letting  \theta^{l}_{t} \equiv \ln \Theta^{l}_{t}-\ln \Theta^{l}_{\ast} denote the log-deviation of  \Theta^{l}_{t} from its steady-state value of  \Theta^{l}_{\ast}, we assume that
\displaystyle \theta_{t}^{l}=\epsilon_{t}^{\theta,l} (4)

where  \epsilon_{t}^{\theta,l} is an i.i.d. shock process.

The level of productivity in the capital goods producing sector has two components. The  Z^{m}_{t} component represents an economy-wide productivity shock, while the  Z^{kb}_{t} term represents a productivity shock that is specific to the capital goods sector. The level of productivity in the consumption goods producing sector has only the one economy-wide component,  Z^{m}_{t}, since we assume  Z^{cbi}_{t}=1. The exogenous productivity terms contain a unit root, that is, they exhibit permanent movements in their levels. We assume that the stochastic process  Z^{s}_{t} evolves according to

\displaystyle \ln Z^{s}_{t} - \ln Z^{s}_{t-1} =\ln \Gamma^{z,s}_{t} =\ln \left(\Gamma^{z,s}_{\ast} \cdot \exp[\gamma^{z,s}_{t}] \right) =\ln \Gamma^{z,s}_{\ast} + \gamma^{z,s}_{t}, s = kb,m, (5)

where  \Gamma^{z,s}_{\ast} and  \gamma^{z,s}_{t} are the steady-state and stochastic components of  \Gamma^{z,s}_{t}. The stochastic component  \gamma^{z,s}_{t} is assumed to evolve according to
\displaystyle \gamma^{z,s}_{t}=\rho^{z,s}\gamma_{t-1}^{z,s}+\epsilon_{t}^{z,s}. (6)

where  \epsilon_{t}^{z,s} is an i.i.d shock process, and  \rho^{z,s} represents the persistence of  \gamma^{z,s}_{t} to a shock. In line with historical experience, we assume a more rapid rate of technological progress in capital goods production by calibrating   \Gamma^{z,k}_{\ast} \geq 1.

2.2 Capital Stock Evolution

As already noted, there are three types of physical capital stocks in our model economy: non-residential capital,  K^{nr}_{t}, residential capital,  K^{r}_{t}, and consumer durables capital,  K^{cd}_{t}.

Purchases of the economy's fast-growing "capital" good can be transformed into either non-residential capital,  K^{nr}_{t+1}, which can be used to produce output in either sector of the economy, or into the economy's consumer-durable capital stock,  K^{cd}_{t+1}, from which households derive utility. Purchases of the economy's slow-growing "consumption" good can be transformed into residential capital.

The evolution of the economy's three capital stocks are given below in equations (8), (9), and (10). We assume that there is some stochastic element affecting the efficiency of investment--reflected in the term  A^{s}_{t}, for  s=nr,  cd, and  r--in the capital accumulation process. These shocks are uncorrelated with each other and exhibit only transitory movements from their steady-state unit mean.2 Letting  a_{t}^{s}\equiv\ln A_{t}^{s} denote the log-deviation of  A^{s}_{t} from its steady-state value of unity, we assume that:

\displaystyle a_{t}^{s}=\rho^{a,s}a_{t-1}^{s}+\epsilon_{t}^{a,s}, s = nr,cd,r. (7)

We also asssume that there are adjustment costs (captured by the final term in equations 8, 9, and 10) that are implied by capital installation. The evolution of capital is given by:
\displaystyle K^{nr}_{t+1}(k) \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{nr})K^{nr}_{t}(k)\!+\!A^{nr}_{t}E^{nr}_{t}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{nr}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{nr}_{t}(k)\!-\! E^{nr}_{t-1}(k)\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} {K^{nr}_{t}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{nr}_{t}, (8)
\displaystyle K^{cd}_{t+1}(k) \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{cd})K^{cd}_{t}(k)\!+\!A^{cd}_{t}E^{cd}_{t}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{cd}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{cd}_{t}(k)\!-\! E^{cd}_{t-1}(k)\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} {K^{cd}_{t}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{cd}_{t}, \mathrm{and} (9)
\displaystyle K^{r}_{t+1}(k) \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{r})K^{r}_{t}(k)\!+\!A^{r}_{t}E^{r}_{t}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{r}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{r}_{t}(k)\!-\! E^{r}_{t-1}(k)\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}} {K^{r}_{t}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{r}_{t}. (10)

The parameter  \delta^{s} denotes the depreciation rate for either the non-residential ( s=nr), consumer durables ( s=cd), or residential ( s=r) capital stocks. Investment adjustment costs are zero for non-residential capital when  E^{nr}_{t}=E^{nr}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}but rise to above zero (at an increasing rate that depends on  \chi^{nr}) as these values diverge. The relative values of  E^{cd}_{t} and  E^{nr}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t} have similar implications for the adjustment costs entailed in the accumulation of consumer durables capital, as do the relative values of  E^{r}_{t} and  E^{r}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t} for the accumulation of residential capital. The parameters  \chi^{cd} and  \chi^{r} have the same interpretation as  \chi^{nr}. Adjustment costs are quite important in models such as ours in ensuring gradual responses of investment to shocks.

2.3 Preferences

The  ith household derives utility from four sources: consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services,  E^{cnn}_{t}(i), the flow of services from consumer-durable capital,  K^{cd}_{t}(i), the flow of services from residential capital  K^{r}_{t}(i), and its leisure time, which is equal to what remains of its time endowment after  L^{cbi}_{t}(i)+L^{kb}_{t}(i) hours are spent working. The preferences of household  i are separable over all of the arguments of its utility function. The utility that the household derives from the three components of its goods and services consumption is influenced by its habit stock for each of these consumption components, a feature that has been shown to be important for consumption dynamics in similar models. Household  i's habit stock for its consumption of non-durable goods and non-housing services, is equal to a factor  h^{cnn} multiplied by its consumption last period  E^{cnn}_{t-1}(i). The household's habit stock for its other components of consumption is defined similarly. In summary, the preferences of household  i are represented by the utility function:

    \displaystyle \mathcal{E}_{0}\!\sum_{t=0}^{\infty}\!\beta^{t}\!\! \left\{\varsigma^{cnn}\Xi_{t}^{cnn}\ln(E^{cnn}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{cnn} E^{cnn}_{t-1}(i)) +\!\varsigma^{cd}\Xi_{t}^{cd}\ln(K^{cd}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{cd} K^{cd}_{t-1}(i)) \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. +\varsigma^{r}\Xi_{t}^{r}\ln(K^{r}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{r} K^{r}_{t-1}(i)) -\!\varsigma^{l}\Xi_{t}^{l} \frac{(L^{cbi}_{t}(i)\!+\!L^{kb}_{t}(i))^{1+\nu}}{1+\nu} \right\}\!\!. (11)

The parameter  \beta is the household's discount factor,  \nu denotes its inverse labor supply elasticity, while  \varsigma^{cnn},  \varsigma^{cd},  \varsigma^{r}, and  \varsigma^{l} are scale parameter that tie down the ratios between the household's consumption components. The stationary, unit-mean, stochastic variables  \Xi^{cnn}_{t},  \Xi^{cd}_{t},  \Xi^{r}_{t}, and  \Xi^{l}_{t} represent aggregate shocks to the household's utility of its consumption components and its disutility of labor.3 Letting  \xi^{x}_{t} \equiv \ln \Xi^{x}_{t}-\ln \Xi^{x}_{\ast} denote the log-deviation of  \Xi^{x}_{t} from its steady-state value of  \Xi^{x}_{\ast}, we assume that
\displaystyle \xi_{t}^{x}=\rho^{\xi,x} \xi_{t-1}^{x}+\epsilon_{t}^{\xi,x}, x=cnn,cd,r,l. (12)

The variable  \epsilon_{t}^{\xi,x} is an i.i.d. shock process, and  \rho^{\xi,x} represents the persistence of  \Xi^{x}_{t} away from steady-state following a shock to equation (12).


3 The Decentralized Economy

The economy's decentralization, which is also depicted in Figure 1, is as follows:

A representative firm in each of the economy's two final-goods producing sectors purchases intermediate inputs from the continuum of intermediate goods producers and produces the sector's final goods output.

Each firm in the economy's two intermediate-goods producing sectors rents non-residential capital from the capital owners and hires each type of differentiated labor from households so as to to produce its differentiated output. Because each firm is a monopolistically-competitive supplier of its own output, it is able to set the price at which it sells this output.

Each household purchases output from final-goods producers in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector, which it then uses as non-durable goods and non-housing services, and rents consumer durables capital and residential capital from the capital owners. Because each household is a monopolistically-competitive supplier of its own labor, it is able to set the wage at which it supplies its labor services.

Each non-residential and consumer durables capital owner purchases output from the fast-growing "capital" final-goods sector and transforms it into either non-residential or consumer durables capital. Each residential capital owner purchases output from the slow-growing "consumption" final-goods and transforms it into residential capital.

The monetary authority sets the nominal interest rate given an interest rate feedback rule with smoothing of the policy response to endogenous variables.

The government and foreign economic agents demand a share of the economy's output.

We describe in this section the behaviour of agents listed above.

3.1 Consumption and Capital Final Goods Producers

The representative, perfectly competitive firm in the final consumption good sector owns the production technology described in equation (1) for  s=cbi, while the representative, perfectly competitive firm in the final capital goods sector owns the same technology for  s=kb. The final-good producer in sector  s solves the cost-minimization problem of:

\displaystyle \min_{\left\{ X_{t}^{s}(j)\right\} _{j=0}^{1}} \int_{0}^{1}P_{t}^{s}(j)X_{t}^{s}(j)dj\mathrm{ subject to } \left( \int_{0}^{1}\left(X_{t}^{s}(j)\right)^{\frac{\Theta^{x,s}_{t}-1} {\Theta^{x,s}_{t}}}dj\right)^{\frac{\Theta^{x,s}_{t} } {\Theta^{x,s}_{t}-1}} \!\!\geq X^{s}_{t}, \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb. (13)

3.2 Consumption and Capital Intermediate Goods Producers

Each intermediate-good producing firm  j \in [0,1] and  s=c,k owns the production technology described in equation (3). It is convenient to think of the intermediate good producing firm as solving three problems: two factor-input cost-minimization problems and one price-setting profit-maximization problem. The two cost-minimization problems faced by the representative firm in sector s are:

\displaystyle \min_{\left\{ L^{s}_{t}(i,j)\right\} _{i=0}^{1}}\!\! \int_{0}^{1}\!\!W_{t}^{s}(i)L^{s}_{t}(i,j)di\mathrm{ subject to }\! \left(\int_{0}^{1}\left(L^{s}_{t}(i,j)\right)^{\frac{\Theta^{l}_{t}-1} {\Theta^{l}_{t}}}\!\!di\right)^{\frac{\Theta^{l}_{t}} {\Theta^{l}_{t}-1}} \!\!\!\!\!\!\!\!\geq L^{s}_{t}(j), \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb, (14)

and
    \displaystyle \min _{\left\{ L^{s}_{t}(j),K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j)\right\} } W^{s}_{t}L^{s}_{t}(j)+R^{nr,s}_{t}K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j)  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{ subject to } \left(Z^{m}_{t}Z^{s}_{t}L^{s}_{t}(j)\right)^{1-\alpha} \left(K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j)\right)^{\alpha}\geq X^{s}_{t}(j), \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb, \mathrm{where} Z^{cbi}_{t}\equiv 1. (15)

The profit-maximization problem faces by the firm is given by:
    \displaystyle \max_{\{P^{s}_{t}(j),X^{s}_{t}(j)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}} \mathcal{E}_{0}\sum_{t=0}^{\infty}\beta^{t} \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left\{ P^{s}_{t}(j)X^{s}_{t}(j) -\!MC^{s}_{t}(j) X^{s}_{t}(j) \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. -\frac{100\cdot\chi^{p}}{2} \left(\frac{P^{s}_{t}(j)}{P^{s}_{t-1}(j)}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,s}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,s}_{\ast}\right)^{2}\!\!P^{s}_{t}X^{s}_{t} \right\}  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{subject to} X^{s}_{\tau}(j) =\!\left(\!\frac{P^{s}_{\tau}(j)}{P^{s}_{\tau}}\!\right)^{-\Theta^{x,s}_{\tau}}\!X^{s}_{\tau}, \mathrm{for} \tau=0,1,...,\infty, \mathrm{and} s = cbi,kb. (16)

The variable  MC^{s}_{t}(j) represents the marginal cost of producing a unit of  X^{s}_{t}(j). The profits function incorporates price setting adjustment costs (the size which depend on the parameter  \chi^{p} and the lagged and steady-state inflation rate). The constraint against which the firm maximizes its profits is the demand curve it faces for its differentiated good; this is derived from the final goods producing firm's cost-minimization problem.

3.3 Capital Owners

Capital owners possess the technologies described in equations (8) and (9) for transforming the economy's fast-growing "capital" good into either non-residential capital,  K^{nr}_{t+1}, or the consumer-durable capital stock,  K^{nr}_{t+1}, and in equation (10) for transforming the economy's slow-growing "consumption" good into the economy's residential capital stock  K^{nr}_{t+1}.

The non-residential capital owner solves:

    \displaystyle \max_{\{E^{nr}_{t}(k),K^{nr}_{t+1}(k),K^{nr,cbi}_{t}(k),K^{nr,kb}_{t}(k), U^{cbi}_{t}(k),U^{kb}_{t}(k)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}}  
    \displaystyle \mathcal{E}_{0}\sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^{t} \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left\{R_{t}^{nr,cbi}U^{cbi}_{t}(k)K^{nr,cbi}_{t}(k) +\!R_{t}^{nr,kb}U^{kb}_{t}(k)K^{nr,kb}_{t}(k)\!-\!P^{kb}_{t}E^{nr}_{t}(k) \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. -\kappa \left(\frac{(U^{cbi}_{t}(k))^{1+\psi}-1}{1+\psi} \right)P^{kb}_{t}K^{nr,cbi}_{t} -\kappa \left(\frac{(U^{kb}_{t}(k))^{1+\psi}-1}{1+\psi} \right)P^{kb}_{t}K^{nr,kb}_{t} \right\}  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{subject to}  
    \displaystyle K^{nr}_{\tau+1}(k) =\! (1-\delta^{nr})K^{nr}_{\tau}(k)\!+\!A^{nr}_{\tau}E^{nr}_{\tau}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{nr}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{nr}_{\tau}(k)\!-\! E^{nr}_{\tau-1}(k)\Gamma^{y,kb}_{t} }{K^{nr}_{\tau}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{nr}_{\tau}  
    \displaystyle K^{nr,cbi}_{\tau}(k)\!+\!K^{nr,kb}_{\tau}(k) =\! K^{nr}_{\tau}(k), \mathrm{for} \tau=0,1,...,\infty. (17)

We assume that the capital owner decides on both the amount of capital that it will rent to firms and the rate of utilization at which this capital is used by firms. (Recall that the firm's choice variable in 15 is utilized capital  K^{u,nr,s}_{t}=U^{s}_{t}K^{nr,s}_{t}.) Raising the rate of utilization will boost the capital owners rental income but will incur a cost reflected in the last two terms in the capital owners profit function. We assume that  \kappa=R^{nr}_{\ast}/P^{kb}_{\ast}, which implies that in the steady-state equilibrium utilization is unity. The consumer durables capital owner solves:
    \displaystyle \max_{\{E^{cd}_{t}(k),K^{cd}_{t+1}(k)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}\}} \mathcal{E}_{0}\sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^{t} \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left\{R^{cd}_{t}K^{cd}_{t}(k)-P^{kb}_{t}E^{cd}_{t}(k) \right\} \mathrm{subject to}  
    \displaystyle K^{cd}_{\tau+1}(k) =(1-\delta^{cd})K^{cd}_{\tau}(k)\!+\!A^{cd}_{\tau}E^{cd}_{\tau}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{cd}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{cd}_{\tau}(k)\!-\! E^{cd}_{\tau-1}(k)\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\tau} } {K^{cd}_{\tau}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{cd}_{\tau}  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{for} \tau=0,...,\infty, (18)

while the residential capital owner solves:
    \displaystyle \max_{\{E^{r}_{t}(k),K^{r}_{t+1}(k)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}\}} \mathcal{E}_{0}\sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^{t} \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left\{R^{r}_{t}K^{r}_{t}(k)-P^{cbi}_{t}E^{r}_{t}(k) \right\} \mathrm{subject to}  
    \displaystyle K^{r}_{\tau+1}(k) =(1-\delta^{r})K^{r}_{\tau}(k)\!+\!A^{r}_{\tau}E^{r}_{\tau}(k) -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{r}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{r}_{\tau}(k)\!-\! E^{r}_{\tau-1}(k)\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\tau} } {K^{cd}_{\tau}}\right)^{\!2}\!\!K^{cd}_{\tau}  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{for} \tau=0,1,...,\infty. (19)

3.4 Households

The household possesses the utility function--defined over three components of goods and services consumption and leisure--described by equation (11).The representative household solves the problem:

    \displaystyle \max_{\left\{E^{cnn}_{t}(i),K^{cd}_{t}(i),K^{r}_{t}(i),\{W^{s}_{t}(i),L^{s}_{t}(i)\}_{s=cbi,kb}, B_{t+1}(i)\right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}}\!\!  
    \displaystyle \mathcal{E}_{0}\!\sum_{t=0}^{\infty}\!\beta^{t}\!\! \left\{\varsigma^{cnn}\Xi_{t}^{cnn}\ln(E^{cnn}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{cnn} E^{cnn}_{t-1}(i)) +\!\varsigma^{cd}\Xi_{t}^{cd}\ln(K^{cd}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{cd} K^{cd}_{t-1}(i)) \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. +\varsigma^{r}\Xi_{t}^{r}\ln(K^{r}_{t}(i)\!-\!h^{r} K^{r}_{t-1}(i)) -\!\varsigma^{l}\Xi_{t}^{l} \frac{(L^{cbi}_{t}(i)\!+\!L^{kb}_{t}(i))^{1+\nu}}{1+\nu} \right\} \mathrm{subject to}  
    \displaystyle R^{-1}_{\tau}B_{\tau+1}(i) =\! B_{\tau}(i)+\!\!\!\!\sum_{s=cbi,kb}\!\!\!\! W^{s}_{\tau}(i)L^{s}_{\tau}(i) +{\textit{Capital and Profits Income}}_{\tau}(i) -P^{cbi}_{\tau}E^{cnn}_{\tau}(i)  
    \displaystyle -\!R^{cd}_{\tau}K^{cd}_{\tau}\!-\!R^{r}_{\tau}K^{r}_{\tau} -\!\sum_{s=cbi,kb}\frac{100\cdot\chi^{w}}{2} \left(\frac{W^{s}_{\tau}(j)}{W^{s}_{\tau-1}(j)}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,s}_{\tau-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w}_{\ast}\right)^{2} W^{s}_{\tau}L^{s}_{\tau}  
    \displaystyle -\frac{100\!\cdot\!\chi^{l}}{2} \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}\!+\!L^{kb}_{\ast}}\!\cdot\! W^{cbi}_{\tau} +\frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}\!+\!L^{kb}_{\ast}}\!\cdot\! W^{kb}_{\tau} \right)\! \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\tau}(i)}{L^{kb}_{\tau}(i)}\!-\!\eta^{l}\frac{L^{cbi}_{\tau-1}}{L^{kb}_{\tau-1}} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{l}) \frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)^{2} \frac{L^{kb}_{\tau}}{L^{cbi}_{\tau}},  
    \displaystyle L^{cbi}_{\tau}(i) =\!\left(\!\frac{W^{cbi}_{\tau}(i)}{W^{cbi}_{\tau}}\!\right)^{\!-\Theta^{l}_{\tau}}\!\! L^{cbi}_{\tau}, {\textrm{and }} L^{kb}_{\tau}(i) =\!\left(\!\frac{W^{kb}_{\tau}(i)}{W^{kb}_{\tau}}\!\right)^{\!-\Theta^{l}_{\tau}}\!\! L^{kb}_{\tau}, \mathrm{for} \tau=0,1,...,\infty. (20)

The household's budget constraint incorporates wage setting adjustment costs (the size of which depend on the parameter  \chi^{w} and the lagged and steady-state wage inflation rate) and costs in altering the composition of labor supply. The constraint against which the household maximizes its utility is the demand curve it faces for its differentiated labor. This demand curve derives from the first of the intermediate goods producing firm's cost-minimization problems.

3.5 Market Clearing

There are a number of market clearing conditions that must be satisfied in our model. Market clearing in the slow-growing "consumption" goods and fast-growing "capital" goods sectors, given price- and wage-adjustment costs and variable utilization costs implies that

\displaystyle X^{cbi}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!E^{cnn}_{t}(i)di +\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!E^{r}_{t}(k)dk +\frac{100\cdot\chi^{p}}{2} \left(\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}\right)^{2}\!\!P^{cbi}_{t}X^{cbi}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \frac{100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w}}{2} \left(\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}\!\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,cbi}_{\ast}\right)^{2}\!\!W^{cbi}_{t}L^{cbi}_{t} -\!\kappa\left(\frac{U^{cbi}_{t}(k)^{1+\psi}\!-\!1}{1+\psi} \right)\!P^{cbi}_{t}K^{nr,cbi}_{t} (21)

and
\displaystyle X^{kb}_{t}\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!E^{cd}_{t}(k)dk +\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!E^{nr}_{t}(k)dk. +\frac{100\cdot\chi^{p}}{2} \left(\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,kb}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}\right)^{2}\!\!P^{kb}_{t}X^{kb}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \frac{100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w}}{2} \left(\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}\!\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,kb}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,kb}_{\ast}\right)^{2}\!\!W^{kb}_{t}L^{kb}_{t} -\!\kappa\left(\frac{U^{kb}_{t}(k)^{1+\psi}\!-\!1}{1+\psi} \right)\!P^{kb}_{t}K^{nr,kb}_{t}\!\!\!\!\!\!\!\!. (22)

The market clearing conditions for the labor and non-residential capital supplied and demanded in sector  s are given by
\displaystyle L^{s}_{t}(i)=\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!L^{s}_{t}(i,j)dj {\mathrm{and}} \!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!U(k)^{s}_{t}K^{nr,s}_{t}(k)dk=\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!K^{u,nr,s}_{t}(j)dj \forall i \in [0,1] {\mathrm{and for}} s=cbi,kb. (23)

The market clearing conditions for consumer durables and residential capital are
\displaystyle \int_{0}^{1}\!\!K^{cd}_{t}(k)dk=\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!K^{cd}_{t}(i)di {\mathrm{and}} \!\! \int_{0}^{1}\!\!K^{r}_{t}(k)dk=\!\!\int_{0}^{1}\!\!\!K^{r}_{t}(i)di . (24)

3.6 Identities

The model also consists of the following identities:

\displaystyle W^{s}_{t}(i)= \Pi^{w,s}_{t}(i)W^{s}_{t-1}(i) \displaystyle {\mathrm{and}}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle W^{s}_{t}= \Pi^{w,s}_{t}W^{s}_{t-1} \forall i \in [0,1] {\mathrm{and for}} s=cbi,kb, {\mathrm{and}} (25)
\displaystyle P^{s}_{t}(j)= \Pi^{p,s}_{t}(j)P^{s}_{t-1}(j) \displaystyle {\mathrm{and}}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle P^{s}_{t}= \Pi^{p,s}_{t}P^{s}_{t-1} \forall j \in [0,1] {\mathrm{and for}} s=cbi,kb. (26)

3.7 Real GDP Growth and GDP Price Inflation

Real GDP growth and the inflation rate of the GDP deflator are two variables of interest to policy-makers that do not automatically appear in our model. Real GDP growth is constructed as the divisia (share-weighted) aggregate of output in the economy, that is:

\displaystyle H^{gdp}_{t}\!= \!\left(\left(\frac{X^{cbi}_{t}} {X^{cbi}_{t-1}}\right)^{P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \!\!\!\!\left(\frac{X^{kb}_{t}} {X^{kb}_{t-1}}\right)^{P^{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} \!\!\!\!\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}\!\!\cdot\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t}} {\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t-1}}\right)^{P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1} {P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} +P^{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} +P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}}} \!\!\!\! \!\!\!\!. (27)

To a first-order approximation, this definition of GDP growth is equivalent to how it is defined in the U.S. NIPA. The variable  \widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t} in equation (28) represents stationary un-modelled output (that is, GDP other that  E^{cnn}_{t},  E^{cd}_{t},  E^{r}_{t}, and  E^{nr}_{t}). Stationary un-modeled output is exogenous and is assumed to follow the process:
\displaystyle \ln \widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t}-\ln \widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast} =\rho^{x,gf}\left(\ln \widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t}-\ln \widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast} \right) +\epsilon^{x,gf}.
The inflation rate of the GDP deflator, represented by  \Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}, is defined implicitly by:
\displaystyle \Pi^{p,gdp}_{t} H^{gdp}_{t} =\frac{P^{gdp}_{t}X^{gdp}_{t}}{P^{gdp}_{t-1}X^{gdp}_{t-1}} =\frac{P^{cbi}_{t}X^{cbi}_{t}+P^{kb}_{t}X^{kb}_{t}+P^{cbi}_{t}X^{gf}_{t}} {P^{cbi}_{t-1}X^{cbi}_{t-1}+P^{kb}_{t-1}X^{kb}_{t-1}+P^{cbi}_{t-1}X^{gf}_{t-1}}. (28)

3.8 Monetary Authority

The central bank sets monetary policy in accordance with a Taylor-type interest-rate feedback rule. Policymakers smoothly adjust the actual interest rate  R_{t} to its target level   \bar{R}_{t}

\displaystyle R_{t} = \left( R_{t-1}\right)^{\phi^{r}} \left( \bar{R}_{t} \right)^{1-\phi^{r}} \exp \left[ \epsilon^{r}_{t} \right], (29)

where the parameter  \phi^{r} reflects the degree of interest rate smoothing, while  \epsilon_{t}^{r} represents a monetary policy shock. The central bank's target nominal interest rate  \bar{R}_{t} is given by:
\displaystyle \bar{R}_{t} = \left( \Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}/\Pi^{p,gdp}_{\ast} \right)^{\phi^{\pi,gdp}} \left( \Delta\Pi^{p,gdp}_{t} \right)^{\phi^{\Delta\pi,gdp}} \left( H^{gdp}_{t}/H^{gdp}_{\ast} \right)^{\phi^{h,gdp}} \left( \Delta H^{gdp}_{t}\right)^{\phi^{\Delta h,gdp}} R_{\ast}. (30)

where  R_{\ast} denotes the economy's steady-state nominal interest rate (which is equal to  (1/\beta)\Pi^{p,c}_{\ast}\Gamma^{z,{m}}_{\ast} (\Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast})^{\alpha}(\Gamma^{z,cbi}_{\ast})^{1-\alpha}) and  \phi^{\pi,gdp},  \phi^{\Delta \pi,gdp},  \phi^{h,gdp}, and  \phi^{\Delta h,gdp} denote the weights in the feedback rule.


4 Equilibrium

Before characterizing equilibrium in this model, we define three additional variables, the price of installed non-residential capital  Q^{nr}_{t}(k), the price of installed consumer durables capital  Q^{cd}_{t}(k), and the price of installed residential capital  Q^{r}_{t}(k). These variables are the lagrange multiplier on the capital evolution equations that would be implied by the  kth capital owner's profit-maximization problems (described in equations 17, 18, and 19).

Equilibrium in our model is an allocation:

    \displaystyle \left\{H^{gdp}_{t}\!, X^{cbi}_{t}\!,\{X^{cbi}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1}, X^{kb}_{t}\!,\{X^{kb}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \{E^{nr}_{t}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{E^{r}_{t}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{E^{cd}_{t}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \{E^{cnn}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1}, \{\Lambda^{r}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1}, \{\Lambda^{cd}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1},\{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1}, \{\Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1},\{\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1},  
    \displaystyle \{L^{cbi}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1},\{\{L^{cbi}_{t}(i,j)\}_{i=0}^{1}\}_{j=0}^{1}, \{L^{kb}_{t}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1},\{\{L^{kb}_{t}(i,j)\}_{i=0}^{1}\}_{j=0}^{1}, \{U^{cbi}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1},\{U^{kb}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1},  
    \displaystyle \{K^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1},\{K^{u,nr,kb}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \{K^{nr,cbi}_{t}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{K^{nr,kb}_{t}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{K^{nr}_{t+1}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},  
    \displaystyle \left. \{K^{r}_{t+1}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{K^{r}_{t+1}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1}, \{K^{cd}_{t+1}(k)\}_{k=0}^{1},\{K^{cd}_{t+1}(i)\}_{i=0}^{1} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

and a sequence of values
    \displaystyle \left\{\Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}\!, \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}\!,\{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \Pi^{p,kb}_{t}\!,\{\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}(j)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}\!,\{\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}(i)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \Pi^{w,kb}_{t}\!,\{\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}(i)\}_{j=0}^{1}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \frac{P^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\left\{\frac{P^{kb}_{t}(j)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{j=0}^{1}\!\!, \frac{W^{cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\left\{\frac{W^{cbi}_{t}(i)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{i=0}^{1}\!\!, \frac{W^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\left\{\frac{W^{kb}_{t}(i)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{i=0}^{1}\!\!, \frac{R^{nr,cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{R^{nr,kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{R^{nr}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},  
    \displaystyle \left. \frac{R^{r}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{R^{cd}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \left\{\frac{MC^{cbi}_{t}(j)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{j=0}^{1}\!\!, \left\{\frac{MC^{kb}_{t}(j)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{j=0}^{1}\!\!, \left\{\frac{Q^{nr}_{t}(k)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{k=0}^{1}\!\!, \left\{\frac{Q^{r}_{t}(k)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{k=0}^{1}\!\!, \left\{\frac{Q^{cd}_{t}(k)}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\right\}_{k=0}^{1}\!\!,R_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

that satisfy the following conditions: In solving these problems agents take as given the initial values of  K^{nr}_{0},  K^{r}_{0},  K^{cd}_{0}, and  R_{-1}, and the sequence of exogenous variables
\displaystyle \left\{ \Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\Gamma^{z,m}_{t}\!, \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}\!,\Theta^{x,kb}_{t}\!, \Theta^{l}_{t}\!, A^{nr}_{t}\!,A^{r}_{t},A^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cnn}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{r}_{t},\Xi^{l}_{t}, E^{gf}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}
implied by the sequence of shocks
\displaystyle \left\{ \epsilon^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{z,m}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\theta,x,cbi}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\theta,x,kb}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\theta,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{a,nr}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,cd}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,cd}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{gf}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{r}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}.
We estimate the log-linearized, symmetric and stationary version of the model described above. Equilibrium in the symmetric and non-stationary version of the model is defined in appendix A of the paper, and equilibrium in the symmetric and stationary version of the model is defined in appendix B. The log-linearization of our model equations is performed symbolically by the software that we use to parse the model into its estimable form; we therefore do not included the log-linearized equations in this documentation. The steady-state solution to the symmetric and stationary version of the model is, however, an input into the model's estimation and so is presented in appendix C.


5 Data

The model is estimated using 11 data series listed below. Except where noted, the series are from the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts (U.S. NIPA) published by the Bureau of Economic Analysis.

  1. Nominal gross domestic product.
  2. Nominal consumption expenditures on non-durables and non-housing services.
  3. Nominal consumption expenditure on durables.
  4. Nominal residential investment expenditure.
  5. Nominal business investment expenditure (which equals nominal gross private domestic investment minus nominal residential investment and thus includes inventory investment).
  6. The rate of GDP price inflation.
  7. The rate of inflation for prices of consumer non-durables and non-housing services (which represents inflation in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector).
  8. The rate of inflation for prices of consumer durables (which represents inflation in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector).
  9. Hours, which equals hours of all persons in the non-farm business sector (from the Bureau of Labor Statistics) scaled up by the ratio of nominal production in our model to nominal non-farm business sector output.4
  10. Wage inflation, which equals compensation per hour in the non-farm business sector (from the Bureau of Labor Statistics).
  11. The federal funds rate (from the Federal Reserve Board).

Some of the series are not those used in previous research with the Federal Reserve's FRB/US model. However, price and nominal quantity indices for each of the model's expenditure and output variables can be retrieved easily from the U.S. NIPA. The construction of these series are as follows:

Nominal expenditures on consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services (  P^{ECNN} ECNN) is the sum of nominal personal consumption expenditures on non-durable goods and nominal personal consumption expenditures on services (Table 1.1 of the NIPA) with owner-occupied nonfarm dwellings and tenant-occupied nonfarm dwellings (Table 2.4) subtracted.

Nominal expenditures on consumer durable goods (  P^{ECD} ECD) is nominal personal consumption expenditures on durable goods (Table 1.1).

Nominal expenditures on residential investment ( P^{ER} ER) is nominal gross private domestic residential investment (Table 1.1).

Nominal expenditures on non-residential investment (  P^{ENR} ENR) is the sum of nominal gross private domestic non-residential investment and the change in nominal private inventories (Table 1.1).

Nominal production in the slow-growing part of the business and institutions sector (  P^{XCBI} XCBI) is the sum of nominal expenditures on consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services (  P^{ECNN} ECNN) and nominal expenditures on residential investment ( P^{ER} ER).

Nominal production in the fast-growing part of the business sector (  P^{XKB} XKB) is the sum of nominal expenditures on consumer durable goods (  P^{ECD} ECD) and nominal expenditures on non-residential investment (  P^{ENR} ENR).

In summary,

\displaystyle P^{XCBI} XCBI \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECNN} ECNN + P^{ER} ER, \mathrm{and} , (31)
\displaystyle P^{XKB} XKB \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECD} ECD + P^{ENR} ENR. (32)

In the NIPA, there is a different price index for every expenditure and output variable. Our theoretical model has only one price per output good.5

To bring our data in line with our model the series must be modified slightly. Although the three price indices  P^{XCBI},  P^{ECNN}, and  P^{ER} are not identical they do not display any dramatic relative price swings. Similarly, the indicies  P^{XKB},  P^{ECD}, and  P^{ENR}, while not identical, do not exhibit any large swings. Consequently, we make the following modification to the data. We re-write equations (32) and (33) as

\displaystyle P^{ECNN}\left[\frac{P^{XCBI}XCBI}{P^{ECNN}}\right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECNN}ECNN + P^{ECNN}\left[\frac{P^{ER}ER}{P^{ECNN}}\right], \mathrm{and}  
\displaystyle P^{ECD}\left[\frac{P^{XKB}XKB}{P^{ECD}}\right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECD}ECD + P^{ECD}\left[\frac{P^{ENR}ENR}{P^{ECD}}\right] ,  


\displaystyle \mathrm{and let } XCBI^{adj}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{P^{XCBI}XCBI}{P^{ECNN}}, ER^{adj}=\frac{P^{ER}ER}{P^{ECNN}}, \mathrm{and}  
\displaystyle XKB^{adj}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{P^{XKB}XKB}{P^{ECD}}, ENR^{adj}=\frac{P^{ENR}ENR}{P^{ECD}}.  

Equations (32) and (33) can then be written as:
\displaystyle P^{ECNN} XCBI^{adj} \!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECNN} ECNN + P^{ECNN} ER^{adj} , \mathrm{and} (33)
\displaystyle P^{ECD} XKB^{adj} \!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle P^{ECD} ECD + P^{ECD} ENR^{adj}. (34)

The above renormalization of the data implies that the series for real expenditures on residential investment ( ER^{adj}) and for expenditures on non-residential investment ( ENR^{adj}) are no longer the series published in the NIPA. The qualitative patterns in the data are unaltered by these normalizations, although the precise values of the series do change thereby resulting in a slight bias in the adjusted series. This divergence can be handled, if and when a focus on the behavior of these real series is desired, by the standard assumption that the data that we are using for residential investment and for nonresidential investment is measured with error.

Our decision for choosing the price index of consumer non-durables and non-housing services as our price index for the slow-growing sector and the price index of consumer durables as our price index for the fast-growing sector is that the PCE price deflator is ultimately the price index that we are most interested in from a policy perspective. Consequently, it is the components of this index that we wish to model.



6 The Empirical Model

6.1 Estimation

We take a log-linear approximation to our model, cast this resulting dynamical system in its state space representation for the set of (in our case 11) observable variables, use the Kalman filter to evaluate the likelihood of the observed variables, and form the posterior distribution of the parameters of interest by combining the likelihood function with a joint density characterizing some prior beliefs. Since we do not have a closed-form solution of the posterior, we rely on Markov-Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) methods.

We add measurement errors processes, denoted  \eta_{t}, for all of the observed series used in estimation except the nominal interest rate and the aggregate hours series. The measurement errors explain less than 5 percent of the observed series.6

6.2 Model Parameters

The model' calibrated parameters are presented in Table 3, while the estimated parameters are presented in Tables 4 and 5. We based out decision on which parameters to calibrate and which to estimate on how informative the data were likely to be on the parameter, as well as identification and overparameterization issues. The first three columns of Table 4 and 5 outline our assumptions about the prior distributions of the estimated parameters, the remaining columns describe the parameters' posterior distributions, which we now proceed to discuss.

We consider first the parameters related to household-spending decisions. The parameters related to habit-persistence are uniformly large. For nondurables and services excluding housing, the habit parameter is about 0.8, close to the value in found by Fuhrer [2000]. For consumer durables capital the habit parameter is somewhat smaller, while for residential capital it is smaller still. Since most DSGE models do not consider utility functions with this level of disaggregation, there is little consensus on these values. In addition, simulations indicate that habit and adjustment cost parameters--both present in our model--are closely related, further complicating any comparison. Indeed, we estimate investment adjustment costs to be very significant for residential investment but of modest importance for consumer durables.7 Nonetheless, habit-persistence and investment adjustment costs are important in generating "hump-shaped" responses of these series to monetary policy shocks.8 The estimated value of the remaining preference parameter, the inverse of the labor supply elasticity, is, at a bit over one, a little higher than suggested by the balance of microeconomic evidence (see Abowd and Card  [1989]).

With regard to adjustment cost parameters for non-residential investment, we estimate significant costs to the change in investment flows, which imply an elasticity of investment to marginal q of about 1/3. We also find an important role for the sectoral adjustment costs to labor: In our multisector setup, shocks to productivity or preferences in one sector of the economy result in strong shifts of labor towards that sector, which conflicts with the high degree of sectoral co-movement in the data. The adjustment costs to the sectoral mix of labor input ameliorate this potential problem, as in Boldrin et al.  [2001].

Finally, adjustment costs to prices and wages are both estimated to be important, although prices appear "stickier" than wages. Our quadratic costs of price and wage adjustment can be translated into frequencies of adjustment consistent with the Calvo model; these are about six quarters for prices and about one quarter for wages. However, these estimates are very sensitive to the specifics of our model and would be altered by reasonable assumptions regarding "real rigidities" such as firm-specific factors or "kinked" demand curves. We find only a modest role for lagged inflation in our adjustment cost specification (around 1/3), equivalent to modest indexation to lagged inflation in other sticky-price specifications. This differs from some other estimates, perhaps because of the focus on a more recent post-1983 sample (similar to results in Kiley [2007] and Laforte [2007]).

6.3 Variance Decompositions

Tables 6 to 11 present forecast error variance decompositions at various (quarterly) horizons at the posterior mode of the parameter estimates for key variables and shocks. We run through the key results here.

Volatility in aggregate GDP growth is, in the near horizon, accounted for predominantly by economy-wide technology shocks, non-residential investment efficiency shocks, and exogenous spending shocks. In the far horizon, volatility is accounted for primarily by capital-specific and economy-wide technology shocks.

Volatility in GDP price inflation is, in the near horizon, accounted for by mark-up shocks in the slow-growing (CBI) sector and economy-wide and capital-specific technology shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by economy-wide and capital-specific technology shocks.

Volatility in the nominal interest rate is, in the near horizon, accounted for primarily by shocks in the policy rule, non-residential investment efficiency shocks, exogenous spending shocks, and mark-up shocks in the slow-growing (CBI) sector. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by non-residential investment efficiency shocks and to a much lesser extent consumption preference shocks.

Volatility in expenditures on consumer non-durables and non-housing services is, in the near horizon, accounted for predominantly by economy-wide technology shocks and to a lesser extent its own preference shock. In the far horizon, volatility is accounted for primarily by capital-specific and economy-wide technology shocks, and non-residential investment efficiency shocks.

Volatility in expenditures on consumer durables is, in the near horizon, accounted for predominantly by non-residential investment efficiency shocks, and its own preference and investment efficiency shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for primarily by capital-specific and non-residential investment efficiency shocks.

Volatility in expenditures on residential investment is, in the near horizon, accounted for predominantly by its own investment efficiency shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for primarily by non-residential investment efficiency shocks and to a lesser extend economy-wide and capital-specific technology shocks.

Volatility in expenditures on non-residential investment is, in both the near and far horizon, accounted for almost exclusively by non-residential investment efficiency shocks.

Volatility in hours is, in the near horizon, accounted for primarily by economy-wide technology shocks and non-residential investment efficiency shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by labor supply shocks.

Volatility in wage inflation is, in the near horizon, accounted for primarily by mark-up shocks in the labor market and labor supply shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by non-residential investment efficiency shocks and economy-wide and capital specific technology shocks.

Volatility in price inflation in the slow-growing part of the business and institutions sector is, in the near horizon, accounted for primarily by mark-up shocks in its sector and to a lesser extent economy-wide technology shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by economy-wide and non-residential investment efficiency shocks.

Volatility in price inflation in the fast-growing part of the business sector is, in the near horizon, accounted for primarily by mark-up shocks in its sector and captial specific technology shocks. In the far horizon, its volatility is accounted for by economy-wide technology shocks and non-residential investment efficiency shocks.

Overall, technology shocks and non-residential investment efficiency shocks seem to be the most important in accounting for the volatility of the data. Notably, economy-wide technology shocks account for a significant portion of the variability of nondurable and nonhousing services consumption (as well as aggregate GDP), while non-residential investment efficiency shocks account for a sizeable share of the variability of both durables consumption and non-residential investment (as well as aggregate GDP). As a result our estimated model is able to deliver co-movement between expenditure expenditure categories and production aggregates despite the present of a large number of expenditure specific expenditure-specific household preference shocks and capital-specific efficiency shocks, which by themselves typically create problems for the model in matching the co-movement properties of the data.

6.4 Impulse Responses

Figures 2 to 15 present the impulse responses of key variables to the models four preference shocks (  \Xi^{cnn}_{t},  \Xi^{cd}_{t},  \Xi^{r}_{t}, and  \Xi^{l}_{t}), four capital efficiency shocks (  A^{nr}_{t},  A^{cd}_{t}, and  A^{r}_{t}), the autonomous spending shock ( H^{x,gf}), mark-up shocks (  \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t} and  \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}), technology shocks (  \Gamma^{x,m}_{t} and  \Gamma^{kb,m}_{t}), and monetary policy shock (  \epsilon^{r}).

The impulse responses to a monetary policy innovation (shown in figure 2) captures the conventional wisdom regarding the effects of such shocks. In particular, both household and business expenditures on durables (consumer durables, residential investment, and nonresidential investment) respond strongly (and with a hump-shape) to a contractionary policy shock, with more muted responses by nondurables and services consumption; each measure of inflation responds gradually, albeit probably more quickly than in some analyses based on vector autoregressions.

The impulse responses to a non-residential investment efficiency shock (shown in figure 3) boosts non-residential investment, initially at the expense of other investment expenditures. Consumption spending does not decline initially, but rather remains flat, reflecting household's expectation of higher levels of future output and consumption smoothing. After non-residential investment spending has been put in place and the economy's capital stock has expanded all components of spending rise above their steady-state level. The initial counter movements in investment spending is a result that is typically associated with expenditure specific shocks. The fact that non-residential investment adds to the economy's productive capactiy is the only reason that these opposing movements do not remain in the longer term. For example, the economy's other investment specific efficiency shocks for consumer durables and residential (shown in figures 4 and 5) lead to opposing movements in expenditure over the full duration of the effects of the shock; this is also the case for the economy's consumer non-durables and non-housing services and residential preference shocks (shown in figures 6 and 8). The consumer durables preference shock (shown in figures 7) displays some immediate co-movement although later the opposing movements in expenditures re-emerge. Naturally, the labor supply preference shock leads to co-movement between expenditure categories (see figure 9), although ultimately, as was evident from the variance decomposition results, this shock accounts for relatively little variation in these data.

The impulse responses to an economy-wide technology shock (shown in figure 10), reflect the typical non-residential capital deepending effects associated with such a shock. Hours in the fast-growing (KB) sector falls in the near term in response to the shock, since the increase in labor productivity exceeds the sluggish increase in demand for goods in this sector. Hours fall in the slow-growing (CBI) sector in response to the slow increase in consumption demand.

The impulse responses to a capital-specific technology shock (shown in figure 11), also reflects non-residential capital deepending, although this takes place with some delay. The delay reflects the very persistent nature of capital-specific technology shocks, which leads firms to expect an extended period of strong capital-specific technology shocks and therefore expect future price declines. This raises the real interest rate relevant to non-residential investment, which slows the initial response despite the decline in the relative price of non-residential investment goods.

6.5 Implied Paths

Figure 16 compares the one-step ahead DSGE model forecast to the actual observations for the data. These indicate that that the model has reasonable success in tracking fluctuations in most series.

Figures 17 and 18 reports on the model's structural shocks implied by estimation; showing the median and the 95 percent credible set of the smoothed paths of these shocks. The paths of these shocks over the model's estimation period provides us with an structural interpretation of the factors underlying recent macroeconomic phenomena. For example, the estimated paths of  \Xi^{cnn} and  \Xi^{cd}, the stochastic variables that multiply the utility derived from non-durable goods and non-housing services consumption and durable goods consumption (shown in the top two panels of figure 17) dropped sharply in late 1990 and early 1991. That is, at this time, for a given level of wealth, income, and habits, households desired to consume less. One explanation for this seemingly exogenous desire to consume less is a decline in consumer confidence, which is one of the widely accepted accounts for the 1990-91 recession. Note also that economy-wide technology growth,  \gamma^{z,m} (shown in the top panel of figure 18) also dropped sharply in late 1990, consistent with a more traditional RBC interpretation of the recession.

The model attributes the U.S. economy's exceptional performance in the second half of the 1990s to a sustained episode of well-above average investment-specific technology growth,  \gamma^{z,k} (shown in the second panel of figure 18) as well as a extended sequence of favorable labor supply shocks,  \Xi^{l} (shown in the second to last panel of figure 17). The rapid advances made in the 1990s in the production of high-tech investment and consumer durable goods is well documented and is accepted as one of the reasons why the U.S. economy was able to grow at so fast a rate over this period while generating relatively little inflation. The explanation for the 1990s phenomena based on a long sequence of favorable labor supply shocks is somewhat less appealing since it ultimately just reflects the fact that over this period it was possible to induce households to supply more labor without their demanding the higher rates of compensation that they typically would. Clearly, it would be more interesting to understand why this was the case.

Finally, the model attributes the 2001 recession to an adverse consumer confidence shock--albeit mostly in non-durable goods and non-housing services consumption,  \Xi^{cnn}--and a unfavorable shock to business investment spending,  A^{nr} (shown in the middle panel of figure 18), which made business capital accumulation appear less attractive that would typically be the case given underlying fundamentals. Again, the DSGE model's view of the 2001 recession does not seem inconsistent with alternatively derived interpretations. Note also, that the unfavorable shock to business investment expenditures,  A^{nr}, persists beyond the 2001 recession, possibly reflecting the effects of geo-political risks and corporate scandals that continued to restrain spending through the early years of the recovery.



7 Summing up

This paper has presented documentation for the large-scale estimated DSGE model of the U.S. economy used in Edge, Kiley, and Laforte (2007), which is being developed as part of an ongoing research project in the Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies section of the Federal Reserve Board aimed at developing a DSGE model that can be used to address practical policy questions. Since our work on this model is ongoing, refinements to the model presented in this paper will very likely take place at future dates; at such time, revised documentation will be made available to interested readers.

Bibliography

Abowd, J., Card, D., 1989.
On the covariance structure of earnings and hours changes. Econometrica 57, 411-445.
Altig, D., Christiano, C., Eichenbaum M., Linde, J., 2004.
An Estimated Model of US business cycles. Mimeo.
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., 1995.
Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 27-48.
Boldrin, M., Christiano, L., Fisher J., 2001.
Habit Persistence, Asset Returns, and the Business Cycle. American Economic Review 91, 149-166.
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 2005.
Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 1-45.
DiCecio, R., 2005.
Comovement: It's Not A Puzzle. Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Working Paper Working Paper 2005-035B.
Dynan, K., 2000.
Habit Formation in Consumer Preferences: Evidence from Panel Data. American Economic Review 90, 391-406.
Edge, R., Laubach, T., Williams, J.C., 2003.
The Responses of Wages and Prices to Techology Shocks. FEDS Working Paper 2003-65.
Edge, R., Kiley, M., Laforte, J.P., 2007.
Natural Rate Measures in an Estimated DSGE Model of the U.S. Economy. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2007-08.
Fisher, J., 2006.
The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114, 413-451.
Fuhrer, J., 2000.
Habit Formation in Consumption and Implications for Monetary-Policy Models. American Economic Review 90, 367-390.
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Krusell, P., 1997.
Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change. American Economic Review 8, 342-62.
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Krusell, P., 2000.
The Role of Investment-specific Technological Change in the Business Cycle. European Economic Review 44, 91-115.
Kiley, M., 2005.
Habit Persistence, Inattention, or Rule-of-Thumb Consumers: Which Accounts for the Predictability of Consumption Growth? Mimeo.
Kiley, M., 2007.
A Quantitative Comparison of Sticky-Price and Sticky-Information Models of Price Setting. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, 101-25.
Kohn, D., 2003.
The Strength in Consumer Durables and Housing: Policy Stabilization or Problem in the Making? Remarks at the Conference on Finance and Macroeconomics. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and SIEPR, February 28.
Laforte, J., 2007.
Pricing Models: A Bayesian DSGE Approach to the U.S. Economy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, 127-54.
Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2004.
Shocks and Frictions in the US Busines Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach. Mimeo.
Whelan, K., 2003.
A Two-Sector Approach to Modeling U.S. NIPA Data. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35, 627-56.


A. The Symmetric Equilibrium

The symmetric equilibrium is an allocation:

    \displaystyle \left\{H^{gdp}_{t}, X^{cbi}_{t},X^{kb}_{t}, E^{nr}_{t},E^{r}_{t},E^{cd}_{t},E^{cnn}_{t}, \Lambda^{r}_{t},\Lambda^{cd}_{t},\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}, \Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t},\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. L^{cbi}_{t},L^{kb}_{t},U^{cbi}_{t},U^{kb}_{t},K^{u,nr,cbi}_{t},K^{u,nr,kb}_{t}, K^{nr,cbi}_{t},K^{nr,kb}_{t},K^{nr}_{t+1},K^{r}_{t+1},K^{cd}_{t+1} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

and a sequence of values
    \displaystyle \left\{\Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}, \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t},\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}, \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t},\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}, \frac{P^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{W^{cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{W^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. \frac{R^{nr,cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{R^{nr,kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{R^{nr}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{R^{r}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{R^{cd}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{MC^{cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{MC^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}, \frac{Q^{nr}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{Q^{r}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},\frac{Q^{cd}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}},R_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

that satisfy the symmetric versions of the first order conditions implied by:
  • The intermediate-good producers' second cost-minimization problem (described in 15) and profit-maximization problem (described in 16);
  • The capital owners' profit-maximization problems (described in 17, 18, and 19); and
  • The households' utility maximization problems (described in 20);
and the symmetric versions of the model's other equilibrium conditions, specifically:
  • The model's market clearing conditions of which only the following need to be explicitly included:
    \displaystyle X^{cbi}_{t}=E^{cnn}_{t}+E^{r}_{t}, X^{kb}_{t}=E^{cd}_{t}+E^{nr}_{t}, K^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}=U^{cbi}_{t}K^{nr,cbi}_{t}, \mathrm{and} K^{u,nr,kb}_{t}=U^{kb}_{t}K^{nr,kb}_{t}.
  • The identities between real wages, relative prices, and wage and price inflation rates:
    \displaystyle \frac{P^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} =\frac{\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\frac{P^{kb}_{t-1}}{P^{cbi}_{t-1}}, \frac{P^{ch}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} =\frac{\Pi^{p,ch}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\frac{P^{ch}_{t-1}}{P^{cbi}_{t-1}}, \mathrm{and} \frac{W^{s}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} =\frac{\Pi^{w,s}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot \frac{W^{s}_{t-1}}{P^{cbi}_{t-1}} {\mathrm{for}} s=cbi,kb
  • Equations (30) and (31) that describe the behavior of monetary policy; and
  • Equations (28), and (29) that define the growth rate of the GDP aggregate and price index.
In solving these problems agents take as given the initial values of  K^{nr}_{0},  K^{r}_{0},  K^{cd}_{0}, and  R_{-1}, and the sequence of exogenous variables
\displaystyle \left\{ \Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\Gamma^{z,m}_{t}\!, \Theta^{y,cbi}_{t}\!,\Theta^{y,kb}_{t}\!,\Theta^{l}_{t}\!, A^{nr}_{t}\!,A^{r}_{t},A^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cnn}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{r}_{t},\Xi^{l}_{t},E^{gf}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}
implied by the sequence of shocks
\displaystyle \left\{ \epsilon^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{z,m}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\theta,y,cbi}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\theta,y,kb}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\theta,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{a,nr}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,cd}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,cd}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{gf}_{t} \epsilon^{r}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}.
Note that the first-order conditions implied by the final good producing firms' cost minimization problem (described in 13) and the first step of the intermediate-good producers cost-minimization problem (described in 14) hold but are redundant in the symmetric equilibrium.

The symmetric first-order conditions implied by the second step of the intermediate-goods producing firms' cost minimization problems (equation 15) are:

\displaystyle L^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(1-\alpha\right) \cdot X^{s}_{t} \cdot \frac{MC^{s}_{t}}{W^{s}_{t}}\!\!\!\! \mathrm{for} s=cbi,bk (35)
\displaystyle K^{u,nr,s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \alpha \cdot X^{s}_{t} \cdot \frac{MC^{s}_{t}}{R^{nr,s}_{t}}\!\!\!\! \! \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb. (36)
\displaystyle X^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(Z^{m}_{t}Z^{s}_{t}L^{s}_{t}\right)^{1-\alpha} \left(K^{u,nr,s}_{t}\right)^{\alpha}\!\!\!\! \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (\mathrm{with} Z^{cbi}_{t}\equiv 1). (37)

The key equation from the intermediate-goods producing firms' profit maximization problems (equation 16) are the price Phillips curves
\displaystyle \Theta^{x,s}_{t}MC^{s}_{t}X^{s}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\Theta^{x,s}_{t}-1\right)P^{s}_{t}X^{s}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle 100\cdot\chi^{p}\left(\Pi^{p,s}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,s}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,s}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,s}_{t}P^{s}_{t} X^{s}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle - \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}}\cdot 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{p} \left(\Pi^{p,s}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,s}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,s}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,s}_{t+1}P^{s}_{t+1}X^{s}_{t+1} \right\}  
    \displaystyle \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb. (38)

The symmetric first-order conditions implied by the non-residential part of the capital owners' profit-maximization problem (equation 17) are:
\displaystyle Q^{nr}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(R^{nr}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{nr})Q^{nr}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (39)
\displaystyle R^{nr,s}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{R^{nr}_{t}}{U^{s}_{t}} \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (40)
\displaystyle U^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1}{\kappa}\cdot\frac{R^{nr,s}_{t}}{P^{kb}_{t}}\right)^{\frac{1}{\psi}} \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (41)
\displaystyle P^{kb}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle Q^{nr}_{t} \left[A^{nr}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{nr}\!\! \left(\frac{E^{nr}_{t}\!-\! E^{nr}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t} } {K^{nr}_{t}}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}}\cdot Q^{nr}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{nr}\!\cdot\! \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1} \left(\frac{E^{nr}_{t+1}\!-\! E^{nr}_{t}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1} } {K^{nr}_{t+1}}\right)\!\!\right\} (42)
\displaystyle K^{nr}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{nr})K^{nr}_{t}\!\!+\!A^{nr}_{t}E^{nr}_{t} -\! \frac{100\cdot\chi^{nr}}{2}\! \left(\!\frac{E^{nr}_{t}\!\!-\! E^{nr}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t} }{K^{nr}_{t}}\!\right)^{2} K^{nr}_{t} (43)
\displaystyle K^{nr,cbi}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle + \displaystyle K^{nr,kb}_{t} =\!K^{nr}_{t} (44)

The symmetric first-order conditions implied by the consumer durables part of the capital owners' profit-maximization problem (equation 18) are:
\displaystyle Q^{cd}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(R^{cd}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{cd})Q^{cd}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (45)
\displaystyle P^{kb}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle Q^{cd}_{t} \left[A^{cd}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{cd} \left(\frac{E^{cd}_{t}\!-\! E^{cd}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} {K^{cd}_{t}}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \cdot Q^{cd}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{cd}\!\cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1} \left(\frac{E^{cd}_{t+1}\!-\! E^{cd}_{t}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1}} {K^{cd}_{t+1}}\right)\!\!\right\} (46)
\displaystyle K^{cd}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1-\delta^{cd})K^{cd}_{t}\!+\!A^{cd}_{t}E^{cd}_{t} -\frac{100\cdot\chi^{cd}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{cd}_{t}\!-\! E^{cd}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} {K^{cd}_{t}}\right)^{2}\!\!K^{cd}_{t} (47)

The symmetric first-order conditions implied by the residential part of the capital owners' profit-maximization problem (equation 19) are:
\displaystyle Q^{r}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(R^{r}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{r})Q^{r}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (48)
\displaystyle P^{cbi}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle Q^{r}_{t} \left[A^{r}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{r} \left(\frac{E^{r}_{t}\!-\! E^{r}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}} {K^{r}_{t}}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \cdot Q^{r}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{r}\!\cdot\! \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1} \times\!\left(\frac{E^{r}_{t+1}\!-\! E^{r}_{t}\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}} {K^{r}_{t+1}}\right)\!\!\right\} (49)
\displaystyle K^{r}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{r})K^{r}_{t}\!+\!A^{r}_{t}E^{r}_{t} -\!\frac{100\cdot\chi^{r}}{2} \left(\frac{E^{r}_{t}\!\!-\! E^{r}_{t-1}\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t} } {K^{r}_{t}}\right)^{2}\!\!\!\!K^{r}_{t} (50)

The symmetric (expenditure-related) first-order conditions implied by the households' utility-maximization problem are: (equation 20) are:
\displaystyle \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta R_{t} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}}{P^{cbi}_{t+1}} \right\} (51)
\displaystyle \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\Lambda^{cd}_{t}}{R^{cd}_{t}} (52)
\displaystyle \frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\Lambda^{r}_{t}}{R^{r}_{t}} (53)
\displaystyle \Lambda^{cnn}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{cnn} \cdot\frac{\Xi^{cnn}_{t}} {E^{cnn}_{t}-h^{cnn}E^{cnn}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{cnn} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{h^{cnn}\Xi^{cnn}_{t+1}} {E^{cnn}_{t+1}-h^{cnn}E^{cnn}_{t}}\right\} (54)
\displaystyle \Lambda^{cd}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{cd}\cdot\frac{\Xi^{cd}_{t}}{K^{cd}_{t}-h^{cd}K^{cd}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{cd} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{h^{cd}\Xi^{cd}_{t+1}} {K^{cd}_{t+1}-h^{cd}K^{cd}_{t}}\right\} (55)
\displaystyle \Lambda^{r}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{r}\cdot\frac{\Xi^{r}_{t}} {K^{r}_{t}-h^{r}K^{r}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{r} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{h^{r}\Xi^{r}_{t+1}} {K^{r}_{t+1}-h^{r}K^{r}_{t}}\right\}. (56)

The key equations from the households' labor-supply decision are the wage Phillips curves
    \displaystyle \Theta^{l}_{t}\cdot \frac{\Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot P^{cbi}_{t}L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle =\! \left(\Theta^{l}_{t}-1\right)W^{cbi}_{t}L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle - \Theta^{l}_{t}\!\!\cdot 100\cdot\chi^{l} \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{cbi}_{t} +\frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{kb}_{t} \right) \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{t}}{L^{kb}_{t}}\!-\!\eta^{l}\frac{L^{cbi}_{t-1}}{L^{kb}_{t-1}} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{l})\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)  
    \displaystyle + 100\cdot\chi^{w}\left(\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}W^{cbi}_{t} L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle -\beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. \times 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w} \left(\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t+1}W^{cbi}_{t+1}L^{cbi}_{t+1} \right\} (57)
\displaystyle   \displaystyle \Theta^{l}_{t}\cdot \frac{\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot P^{cbi}_{t}L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle =\! \left(\Theta^{l}_{t}-1\right)W^{kb}_{t}L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle + \Theta^{l}_{t}\!\!\cdot 100\cdot\chi^{l} \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{cbi}_{t} +\frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{kb}_{t} \right) \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{t}}{L^{kb}_{t}}\!-\!\eta^{l}\frac{L^{cbi}_{t-1}}{L^{kb}_{t-1}} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{l})\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)  
    \displaystyle + 100\cdot\chi^{w}\left(\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,kb}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,kb}_{t}W^{kb}_{t} L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle -\beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t+1}/P^{cbi}_{t+1}}{\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}/P^{cbi}_{t}} \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. \times 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w} \left(\Pi^{w,kb}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,kb}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,kb}_{t+1}W^{kb}_{t+1}L^{kb}_{t+1} \right\} (58)

where
\displaystyle \Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t}=\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}=\varsigma^{l} \Xi^{l}_{t}\left(L^{cbi}_{t}+L^{kb}_{t} \right)^{\nu} (59)

B. Equilibrium in the Symmetric and Stationary Model

The symmetric equilibrium is an allocation:

    \displaystyle \left\{H^{gdp}_{t}, \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t},\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}, \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t},\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t}, \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t}, \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t}, \widetilde{\Lambda}^{r}_{t},\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cd}_{t},\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}, \Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t},\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. L^{cbi}_{t},L^{kb}_{t},U^{cbi}_{t},U^{kb}_{t}, \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,cbi}_{t},\widetilde{K}^{u,nr,kb}_{t}, \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{t},\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{t},\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t+1}, \widetilde{K}^{r}_{t+1},\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t+1} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

and a sequence of values
    \displaystyle \left\{\Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}, \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t},\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}, \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t},\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}, \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t},\widetilde{W}^{cbi}_{t},\widetilde{W}^{kb}_{t}, \right.  
    \displaystyle \left. \widetilde{R}^{nr,cbi}_{t},\widetilde{R}^{nr,kb}_{t}, \widetilde{R}^{nr}_{t},\widetilde{R}^{r}_{t}, \widetilde{R}^{cd}_{t},\widetilde{MC}^{cbi}_{t},\widetilde{MC}^{kb}_{t}, \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t},\widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t},\widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t},R_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}  

that satisfy the stationary versions of the equations given in the preceding section, taking as given the initial values of  K^{nr}_{0},  K^{r}_{0},  K^{cd}_{0}, and  R_{-1}, and the sequence of exogenous variables
\displaystyle \left\{ \Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\Gamma^{z,m}_{t}\!, \Theta^{y,cbi}_{t}\!,\Theta^{y,kb}_{t}\!,\Theta^{l}_{t}\!, A^{nr}_{t}\!,A^{r}_{t},A^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cnn}_{t}\!,\Xi^{cd}_{t}\!,\Xi^{r}_{t},\Xi^{l}_{t},E^{gf}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}
implied by the sequence of shocks
\displaystyle \left\{ \epsilon^{z,kb}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{z,m}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\theta,y,cbi}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\theta,y,kb}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\theta,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{a,nr}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{a,cd}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,cd}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,r}_{t}\!,\epsilon^{\xi,l}_{t}\!, \epsilon^{gf}_{t} \epsilon^{r}_{t} \right\}_{t=0}^{\infty}.
The stationary versions of the equations reported in appendix A are presented in this section. Note also that definitions for all of the model's stationary variables can be found in appendix F.

The symmetric and stationary first-order conditions implied by the second step of the intermediate-goods producing firms' cost minimization problems (equation 15) are:

\displaystyle L^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(1-\alpha\right) \cdot \widetilde{X}^{s}_{t} \cdot \frac{\widetilde{MC}^{s}_{t}}{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{t}}\!\!\!\! \mathrm{for} s=cbi,bk (60)
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{u,nr,s}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \alpha \cdot \widetilde{X}^{s}_{t} \cdot \frac{\widetilde{MC}^{s}_{t}}{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{t}}\!\!\!\! \! \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb. (61)
\displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(Z^{m}_{t}Z^{s}_{t}L^{s}_{t}\right)^{1-\alpha} \left(\widetilde{K}^{u,nr,s}_{t}\right)^{\alpha} \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (\mathrm{with} Z^{cbi}_{t}\equiv 1). (62)

The stationary price Phillips curves that are implied by the intermediate-goods producing firms' profit maximization problems (equation 16) are
\displaystyle \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}\widetilde{MC}^{cbi}_{t}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}-1\right)\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle 100\cdot\chi^{p}\!\left(\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}\!\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle - \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{p} \left(\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t+1}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t+1} \right\} (63)
\displaystyle \Theta^{x,kb}_{t}\widetilde{MC}^{kb}_{t}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\Theta^{x,kb}_{t}-1\right)\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle 100\cdot\chi^{p}\left(\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}\!\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,kb}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,kb}_{t}\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t} \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle - \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{p}\! \left(\Pi^{p,kb}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{p}\Pi^{p,kb}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{p})\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{p,kb}_{t+1}\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t+1}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t+1} \right\} (64)

The symmetric and stationary first-order conditions implied by the non-residential part of the capital owners' profit-maximization problem (equation 17) are:
\displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1}} \left(\widetilde{R}^{nr}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{nr})\widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (65)


\displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{R}^{nr}_{t}}{U^{s}_{t}} \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (66)
\displaystyle U^{s}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1}{\kappa}\cdot\frac{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{t}}{\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t}}\right)^{\frac{1}{\psi}} \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb (67)
\displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t} \left[A^{nr}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{nr}\!\! \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t-1}} {\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t}}\cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{nr} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t+1}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t}} {\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t+1}}\cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1}\right)\right\} (68)
\displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1\!-\!\delta^{nr})\frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} +\!A^{nr}_{t}\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t} -\!\frac{100\cdot\chi^{nr}}{2} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t}\!\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t-1}}{\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t}} \cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}\right)^{2} \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} (69)
\displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{t}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle + \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{t} =\!\widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t} (70)

The symmetric and stationary first-order conditions implied by the consumer durables part of the capital owners'profit-maximization problem (equation 18) are:
\displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1}} \left(\widetilde{R}^{cd}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{cd})\widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (71)
\displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t} \left[A^{cd}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{cd} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t-1}}{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}}\cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot \widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{cd} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t+1}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t}}{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t+1}}\cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t+1}\right)\!\!\right\} (72)
\displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1-\delta^{cd})\frac{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}}\!+\!A^{cd}_{t}\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t} -\frac{100\cdot\chi^{cd}}{2} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t-1}}{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}} \cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}\right)^{2}\!\!\frac{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}}. (73)

The symmetric and stationary first-order conditions implied by the residential part of the capital owners' profit-maximization problem (equation 19) are:
\displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}} \left(\widetilde{R}^{r}_{t+1}+(1-\delta^{r})\widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t+1} \right)\right\} (74)
\displaystyle 1 \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t} \left[A^{r}_{t}-100\cdot\chi^{r} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{r}_{t-1}}{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}}\cdot \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}\right) \right]  
\displaystyle \displaystyle + \displaystyle \beta \mathcal{E}_{t}\! \left\{\!\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t+1}\!\cdot\!100\!\cdot\!\chi^{r}\!\cdot\!\eta^{r} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t+1}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{r}_{t}}{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t+1}}\cdot \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}\right)\!\!\right\} (75)
\displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{r}_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1-\delta^{r})\frac{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}} +\!A^{r}_{t}\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t} -\frac{100\cdot\chi^{r}}{2} \left(\frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t}\!-\! \widetilde{E}^{r}_{t-1}}{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}} \cdot \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}\right)^{2}\!\!\frac{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}}. (76)

The symmetric and stationary (expenditure-related) first-order conditions implied by the households' utility-maximization problem are: (equation 20) are:
\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta R_{t} \mathcal{E}_{t}\cdot \left\{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}\cdot \frac{1}{\Pi^{cbi}_{t+1}\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}} \right\} (77)
\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cd}_{t}\cdot\frac{1}{\widetilde{R}^{cd}_{t}} (78)
\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{r}_{t}\cdot\frac{1}{\widetilde{R}^{r}_{t}} (79)
\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{cnn} \cdot\frac{\Xi^{cnn}_{t}} {\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t}-(h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}) \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{cnn} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{(h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}) \Xi^{cnn}_{t+1}} {\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t+1} -(h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t+1}) \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t}}\right\} (80)
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cd}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{cd} \cdot\frac{\Xi^{cd}_{t}} {\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}-(h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t-1}) \widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{cd} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{(h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}) \Xi^{cd}_{t+1}} {\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t+1}-(h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}) \widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t}}\right\} (81)
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{r}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \varsigma^{r} \cdot\frac{\Xi^{r}_{t}} {\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}-(h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t-1}) \widetilde{K}^{r}_{t-1}} -\beta \varsigma^{r} \mathcal{E}_{t}\left\{\frac{(h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}) \Xi^{r}_{t+1}} {\widetilde{K}^{r}_{t+1}-(h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}) \widetilde{K}^{r}_{t}}\right\} (82)

The key equations from the households' labor-supply decision are the wage Phillips curves
    \displaystyle \Theta^{l}_{t}\cdot \frac{\Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle =\! \left(\Theta^{l}_{t}-1\right)\widetilde{W}^{cbi}_{t}L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle - \Theta^{l}_{t}\!\!\cdot 100\cdot\chi^{l} \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{cbi}_{t} +\frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{kb}_{t} \right) \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{t}}{L^{kb}_{t}}\!-\!\eta^{l}\frac{L^{cbi}_{t-1}}{L^{kb}_{t-1}} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{l})\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)  
    \displaystyle + 100\cdot\chi^{w}\left(\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}\widetilde{W}^{cbi}_{t} L^{cbi}_{t}  
    \displaystyle -\beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w} \left(\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,cbi}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,cbi}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t+1}\widetilde{W}^{cbi}_{t+1}L^{cbi}_{t+1} \right\} (83)
\displaystyle   \displaystyle \Theta^{l}_{t}\cdot \frac{\Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}}\cdot L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle =\! \left(\Theta^{l}_{t}-1\right)\widetilde{W}^{kb}_{t}L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle + \Theta^{l}_{t}\!\!\cdot 100\cdot\chi^{l} \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{cbi}_{t} +\frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot W^{kb}_{t} \right) \left(\frac{L^{cbi}_{t}}{L^{kb}_{t}}\!-\!\eta^{l}\frac{L^{cbi}_{t-1}}{L^{kb}_{t-1}} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{l})\frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{L^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)  
    \displaystyle + 100\cdot\chi^{w}\left(\Pi^{w,kb}_{t}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,kb}_{t-1} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,kb}_{t}\widetilde{W}^{kb}_{t} L^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle -\beta \mathcal{E}_{t} \left\{\frac{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t+1}}{\widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t}} \cdot 100\!\cdot\!\chi^{w} \left(\Pi^{w,kb}_{t+1}\!-\!\eta^{w}\Pi^{w,kb}_{t} -\!(1\!-\!\eta^{w})\Pi^{w,kb}_{\ast}\right) \Pi^{w,kb}_{t+1}\widetilde{W}^{kb}_{t+1}L^{kb}_{t+1} \right\} (84)

The model's other conditions for equilibrium, listed in appendix A for the non-stationary model, are transformed as follows in the stationary model:
  • The model's market clearing conditions become:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t}=\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t}+\widetilde{E}^{r}_{t}, \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}=\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t}+\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t}, \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}=U^{cbi}_{t}\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{t}, \mathrm{and} \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,kb}_{t}=U^{kb}_{t}\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{t}.
  • The identities between real wages, relative prices, and wage and price inflation rates become:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t} =\frac{\Pi^{p,kb}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t-1}, \widetilde{P}^{ch}_{t} =\frac{\Pi^{p,ch}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t-1} \mathrm{and} \widetilde{W}^{s}_{t} =\frac{\Pi^{w,s}_{t}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}}\cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}}\cdot \widetilde{W}^{s}_{t-1} {\mathrm{for}} s=cbi,kb
  • Equations (30) and (31) that describe the behavior of monetary policy are already described in terms of stationary variables;
  • The equations that define the growth rates of GDP growth and price inflation are given by:
    \displaystyle H^{gdp}_{t}\!= \!\left(\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}\!\!\cdot\wi... ...{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} +P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}}} (85)

    and
    \displaystyle \Pi^{p,gdp}_{t} H^{gdp}_{t} =\Pi^{p,cbi}_{t} \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}\cdot \frac{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t}+\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}+\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t}} {\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t-1}+\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t-1}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t-1}+\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{t-1}}. (86)

C. The Steady-state Solution to the Symmetric and Stationary Model

The steady-state growth rates in the fast- and slow-growing sectors of the economy are, respectively,

\displaystyle \Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \Gamma^{z,{m}}_{\ast} \Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast} \mathrm{and} (87)
\displaystyle \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \Gamma^{z,{m}}_{\ast} ( \Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast} )^{\alpha}. (88)

From the steady-state version of the Euler equation (equation 78), we know that the steady-state nominal interest rate is given by:
\displaystyle R_{\ast}=\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast} \Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast} =\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast} \Pi^{k}_{\ast} (89)

while the real interest rates relevant to consumers, capital owners, and producers respectively are:
\displaystyle \frac{R_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast} \mathrm{and} (90)
\displaystyle \frac{R_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast} =\!\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast} \cdot\frac{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}}. (91)

The steady-state values of the relative prices of fast-growing goods (  \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t}), installed non-residential capital goods (  \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t}) and installed consumer durables (  \widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t}) is equal to the steady-state relative mark-ups in the two sectors. Since we assume that  \Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}=\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}, these relative prices are all unity in the steady-state. The relative price of installed residential capital goods (  \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t}) is also unity. Specifically,
\displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} =\widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{\ast} =\widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{\ast} =\frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}=1 {\mathrm{and}} \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{\ast}=1.
The steady-state values of real marginal cost, the real rental rate, and the real wage can be calculated from the steady-state versions of equations (61), (62), (63), (64), (65), and (66). These are
\displaystyle \widetilde{MC}^{cbi}_{\ast}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{MC}^{kb}_{\ast}=\frac{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}, =\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast}\cdot\frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}, (92)
\displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr}_{\ast}= \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left(\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)\right) =\! \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left(\frac{R_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}}-\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right) \right), \mathrm{and} (93)
\displaystyle \widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{W}_{\ast} =\left(1-\alpha \right) \left( \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left( \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta -\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}} (94)

From our calibration of  \kappa, the parameter in the non-residential capital owners utilization function, we know from equation (68) that  U^{cbi}_{\ast}=U^{kb}_{\ast}=1. It is useful to note from the above equations that:
\displaystyle \left(\frac{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}\right)^{1-\alpha}\!\!\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}\cdot \widetilde{P}^{k}_{\ast}\cdot\frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \left(1-\alpha \right)^{1-\alpha} \left(\alpha \right)^{\alpha}  
\displaystyle \left(\frac{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}\right)^{\alpha} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}\cdot \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast}\cdot\frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \left(1-\alpha \right)^{1-\alpha} \left(\alpha \right)^{\alpha}  

From equations (72) and (75) note also that:
\displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{cd}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left(\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-\left(1-\delta^{cd} \right)\right) =\! \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left(\frac{R_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast}}-\left(1-\delta^{cd} \right) \right), \mathrm{and} (95)
\displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{r}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1}{\beta}\cdot\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}-\left(1-\delta^{r} \right)\right) =\!\left(\frac{R_{\ast}}{\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}}-\left(1-\delta^{r} \right) \right) (96)

The steady-state inflation rates of capital prices and of nominal wages are given by:
\displaystyle \Pi^{p,kb}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}(\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}/\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}) =\!\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast}( 1/\Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast} )^{1-\alpha}, \mathrm{and} (97)
\displaystyle \Pi^{w,{s}}_{\ast}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \Pi^{w}_{\ast} =\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast} \Gamma^{y,cbi}_{\ast} =\Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast} \Gamma^{z,m}_{\ast} (\Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast} )^{\alpha} , \mathrm{for} s=cbi,kb, (98)

where the steady-state inflation rate of consumption prices  \Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast} is set by the preferences of the central bank.

The steady-state ratios  L^{cbi}_{\ast}/\widetilde{Y}^{cbi}_{\ast},  \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast},  L^{kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{Y}^{kb}_{\ast}, and  \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}, which are calculated from the factor demand schedules (equations 61 and 62), are

\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot \frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}\right)^{1-\alpha} \left(\frac{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}\right)^{1-\alpha} =\frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta-(1-\delta^{nr})} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}, (99)
\displaystyle \frac{L^{cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1-\alpha}{\alpha}\right)^{\alpha} \left(\frac{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}\right)^{\alpha} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta-(1-\delta^{nr})} {\alpha} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}, (100)
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}\cdot \frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}\right)^{1-\alpha} \left(\frac{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}\right)^{1-\alpha} =\frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta-(1-\delta^{nr})} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}, \mathrm{and} (101)
\displaystyle \frac{L^{kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1-\alpha}{\alpha}\right)^{\alpha} \left(\frac{\widetilde{R}^{nr,s}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{W}^{s}_{\ast}}\right)^{\alpha} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta-(1-\delta^{nr})} {\alpha} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}. (102)

We can write these as
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} =\mathcal{A}, \frac{\widetilde{L}^{cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}=(\mathcal{A})^{-\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}, \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}\cdot\frac{1}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} =\mathcal{A}, {\mathrm{and}} \frac{\widetilde{L}^{kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}=(\mathcal{A})^{-\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}, (103)

where
\displaystyle {\mathcal{A}}= \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{y,kb}_{\ast}/\beta-(1-\delta^{nr})} \cdot \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}}

To solve for  L^{cbi}_{\ast},  \widetilde{K}^{cbi}_{\ast},  L^{kb}_{\ast}, and  \widetilde{K}^{kb}_{\ast} by themselves we need to solve first for  \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}. This takes a few steps, the first of which is to derive the ratio of  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}. As part of this excerise we must turn to considering the expenditure side of the model, and in particular the model's expenditure ratios.

To calculate the model's expenditure ratios, we start with what we know about the ratios between the inputs to the optimizing household's utility function, that is  E^{cnn}_{\ast},  K^{cd}_{\ast}, and  K^{r}_{\ast}. We know from equations (79) to (83) that

\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\varsigma^{cd}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot\frac{1-\beta h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}}{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1-h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}} \cdot\frac{1}{\widetilde{R}^{cd}_{\ast}}, \mathrm{and}  
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\varsigma^{r}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot\frac{1-\beta h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1-h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{1}{\widetilde{R}^{r}_{\ast}}  

We have expressions for  \widetilde{R}^{cd}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{R}^{r}_{\ast} in equations (96) and (97) and we know from the steady-state versions of equations (74) and (77) that
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{\ast}} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{cd})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \mathrm{and} \frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{K}^{r}_{\ast}} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{r})}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}} \right). (104)

These equations imply that the ratios of expenditures implied by the optimizing agents of the model are
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\varsigma^{cd}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot\frac{1\!-\!\beta h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}}{1\!-\!\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{1\!-\!h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1\!\!-h^{cd}/\Gamma^{x,kb}} \cdot\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}\!-\!(1\!-\!\delta^{cd})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \cdot\frac{1}{\widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast}} \cdot\frac{\beta}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}\!-\!\beta(1\!-\!\delta^{cd})} =\!\mathcal{D}  
      (105)
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\varsigma^{r}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot\frac{1\!-\!\beta h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1\!-\!\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{1\!-\!h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1\!-\!h^{r}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}} \cdot\frac{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}\!-\!(1\!-\!\delta^{r})}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}} \cdot\frac{\beta}{\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}\!-\!\beta(1\!-\!\delta^{r})} =\!\mathcal{R} (106)

We can now consider expenditures as shares of their sector's outputs. Recall from the equilibrium conditions listed in appendix A that

\displaystyle E^{cnn}_{\ast}+E^{r}_{\ast}\!=\!X^{cbi}_{\ast} \mathrm{and} E^{cd}_{\ast}+E^{nr}_{\ast}\!=\!X^{kb}_{\ast},
Consider first the market clearing condition for the slow growing sector. Since all aggregates in this equation grow at the same rate we can re-write the steady-state expression for  X^{cbi}_{t} as shown below (as well as in appendix B) and with some manipulations
\displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}+\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast} \mathrm{implies}  
\displaystyle 1 \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} +\frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} = \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} +\frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \cdot\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} = \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \left(1 + \frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}\right) = \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \left(1 + \mathcal{R}\right).  

This then allows us to write:
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \!=\!\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}\!+\!\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}} \!=\!\frac{1}{1\!+\!\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}/\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \!=\!\frac{1}{1\!+\!\mathcal{R}} \mathrm{and} \frac{\widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \!=\!1\!-\!\frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \!=\!1\!-\!\frac{1}{1\!+\!\mathcal{R}} \!=\!\frac{\mathcal{R}}{1\!+\!\mathcal{R}}, (107)

where  \mathcal{R} was defined in equation (107). For the fast-growing sector, we can re-write the market clearing condition (as in appendix B) as:
\displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} =\!\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}+\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast}.
and make similar tranformations as before. A useful relationship for these transformations is from equations (70) and (71), that is,
\displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \widetilde{K}^{nr}_{\ast} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \left(\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}+\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}\right).
The fast growing sector's market clearing condition can also be manipulated; specifically,
\displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}+\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast} \mathrm{implies}  
\displaystyle 1 \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} +\fra... ...\ast}} +\!\frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}\right)  

We have expressions for  \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}},  \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}},  \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}, and  \frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}. Substituting in these expressions yields
\displaystyle 1 \displaystyle = \displaystyle \mathcal{D}\left(\frac{1}{1+\mathcal{R}}\right) \cdot \frac{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} +\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \mathcal{A} \cdot \Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast} \left(\frac{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}+1\right),  

which can be re-arranged to
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} =\frac{\mathcal{D} +\left(1+\mathcal{R} \right)\left(\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{nr})\right) \mathcal{A}} {\left(1+\mathcal{R} \right) -\left(1+\mathcal{R} \right)\left(\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}-(1-\delta^{nr})\right)\mathcal{A} } =\mathcal{B}. (108)

This then allows us to write:
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}\!-\!(1\!-\!\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \left(\frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}\cdot \frac{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} \!+\!\frac{\widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}}\right) =\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}\!-\!(1\!-\!\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \mathcal{A}\cdot\frac{1\!+\!\mathcal{B}}{\mathcal{B}}, (109)

so that
\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} =1-\frac{\widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} =1 -\left(\frac{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}\!-\!(1\!-\!\delta^{nr})}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right) \mathcal{A}\cdot\frac{1\!+\!\mathcal{B}}{\mathcal{B}}. (110)

We now consider the household's supply of labor. First note from equations (60) and (81) that:

\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{l,cbi}_{\ast}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{l,kb}_{\ast}= \varsigma^{l}(L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{kb}_{\ast})^{\nu} \mathrm{and}  
\displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{\ast}\!\!\!\! \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\varsigma^{cnn}}{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}} \cdot\frac{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}  

Combining these steady-state values with the model's labor supply schedules (equations 84 and 85) and the expression for the steady-state real wage (equation 95), imply:
    \displaystyle (L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{kb}_{\ast})^{\nu} \cdot \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast} \cdot \frac{\varsigma^{l}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot \frac{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma_{\ast}^{x,cbi}}{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma_{\ast}^{x,cbi}}  
    \displaystyle =\left(1-\alpha \right) \left( \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left( \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta -\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \frac{(L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{kb}_{\ast})^{\nu +1}} {\frac{L^{cbi}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}} +\frac{L^{kb}}{\widetilde{X}^{kb}}\cdot\frac{\widetilde{X}^{kb}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}}} \cdot \frac{\widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}} \cdot \frac{\varsigma^{l}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot \frac{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}}  
    \displaystyle =\left(1-\alpha \right) \left( \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left( \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta -\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \frac{(L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{kb}_{\ast})^{\nu +1}} {(\mathcal{A})^{-\alpha/(1-\alpha)}(1+\mathcal{B})} \cdot \left(\frac{1}{1+\mathcal{R}}\right) \left(1-\frac{\widetilde{E}^{gf,cbi}_{\ast}}{\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}} \right) \cdot \frac{\varsigma^{l}}{\varsigma^{cnn}} \cdot \frac{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}  
    \displaystyle =\left(1-\alpha \right) \left( \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left( \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta -\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}}  

Letting  L^{cbi}_{\ast}+L^{kb}_{\ast}=L_{\ast} implies that:
\displaystyle L_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left[\left(1-\alpha \right) \left( \frac{\Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}-1}{\Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}} \right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{\ast} \left( \frac{\alpha}{\Gamma^{x,kb}_{\ast}/\beta -\left(1-\delta^{nr} \right)} \right)^{\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}} \right.  
    \displaystyle \times \left.\frac{1+\mathcal{B}}{(\mathcal{A})^{\alpha/(1-\alpha)}}\cdot (1+\mathcal{R}) \cdot \frac{\varsigma^{cnn}}{\varsigma^{l}} \cdot \frac{1-\beta h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,cbi}}{1-h^{cnn}/\Gamma^{x,kb}} \right]^{\frac{1}{\nu+1}}  
\displaystyle \displaystyle = \displaystyle \mathcal{L} (111)

Since the right-hand sides of equations (101) and (103) are identical,  \widetilde{L}^{cbi}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}=\widetilde{L}^{kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}. As a result,  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}=\mathcal{B} implies that  L^{kb}_{\ast}/L^{cbi}_{\ast}=\mathcal{B}, which means then that:
\displaystyle L^{cbi}_{\ast}=\frac{1}{1+\mathcal{B}}\cdot \mathcal{L} \mathrm{and} L^{kb}_{\ast}=\frac{\mathcal{B}}{1+\mathcal{B}}\cdot \mathcal{L}.
Solving for  L^{cbi}_{\ast} and  L^{kb}_{\ast} allows us to find the steady-state solutions for all of the other production, factor, and expenditure variables of the model. Specifically:
  •  L^{cbi}_{\ast} and  L^{cbi}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} (defined in equation 101) imply  \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast};
  •  L^{kb}_{\ast} and  L^{kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} (defined in equation 103) imply  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} (defined in equation 100) imply  \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast} and (since  U^{cbi}_{\ast}=1)  \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,cbi}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} (defined in equation 102) imply  \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast} and (since  U^{kb}_{\ast}=1)  \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,kb}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{\ast},  \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{\ast}, and the non-residential capital market clearing condition imply  \widetilde{K}^{nr}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} (both defined in equation 108) imply  \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast}/\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast} (defined in equations 110 and 111) imply  \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{\ast};
  •  \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}, and  \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{\ast}/\widetilde{K}^{cd}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{E}^{r}_{\ast}/\widetilde{K}^{r}_{\ast} (both defined in equation 105) imply  \widetilde{K}^{cd}_{\ast} and  \widetilde{K}^{r}_{\ast}; and,
  •  \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{\ast},  \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cd}_{\ast}, and  \widetilde{\Lambda}^{r}_{\ast} are then implied by the steady-state versions of equations (81) to (83), while  \Lambda^{l,cbi}_{\ast} and  \Lambda^{l,kb}_{\ast} are implied by the steady-state versions of equation (60).
Finally we have
\displaystyle H^{gdp}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}\right)^{\frac{P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast}+P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}} {P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} +P^{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}+P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}}} \left(\Gamma^{y,kb}_{\ast}\right)^{\frac{P^{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}} {P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{\ast} +P^{kb}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{kb}_{\ast}+P^{cbi}_{\ast}\widetilde{X}^{gf}_{\ast}}}  
\displaystyle \Pi^{p,gdp}_{\ast} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{H^{gdp}_{\ast}}\cdot \Pi^{p,cbi}_{\ast} \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{\ast}\cdot  

The reader can verify that we have in this section presented a steady-state value for all of the model variables that defined equilibrium in appendix B.


D. List of Model Parameters

 h^{cnn}= Habit-persistence parameter for the consumption of non-durable goods and non-housing services.

 h^{cd}= Habit-persistence parameter for the consumption of durable goods.

 h^{r}= Habit-persistence parameter for the consumption of housing services.

 \alpha= The elasticity of output with respect to capital.

 \beta= The household's discount factor.

 \delta^{cd}= The quarterly depreciation rate of consumer durables.

 \delta^{nr}= The quarterly depreciation rate of non-residential capital.

 \delta^{r}= The quarterly depreciation rate of residential capital.

 \eta^{cd}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of lagged investment spending in the consumer durables adjustment cost function.

 \eta^{nr}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of lagged investment spending in the non-residential capital adjustment cost function.

 \eta^{r}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of lagged investment spending in the residential capital adjustment cost function.

 \eta^{k}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of the lagged sectoral mix of non-residential capital in the non-residential capital sectoral adjustment cost function.

 \eta^{l}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of the lagged sectoral mix of labor in the labor sectoral adjustment cost function.

 \eta^{p}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of lagged price inflation in the adjustment cost function for prices.

 \eta^{w}= Parameter reflecting the relative importance of lagged wage inflation in the adjustment cost function for wages.

 \kappa= Variable capacity utilization scaling parameter.

 \nu= Inverse labor supply elasticity.

 \rho^{a,nr}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  A^{nr}_{t}.

 \rho^{a,cd}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  A^{cd}_{t}.

 \rho^{a,r}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  A^{r}_{t}.

 \rho^{z,kb}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}.

 \rho^{z,m}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Gamma^{z,m}_{t}.

 \rho^{\theta,x,cbi}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}.

 \rho^{\theta,x,kb}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Theta^{x,kb}_{t}.

 \rho^{\theta,l}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Theta^{l}_{t}.

 \rho^{\xi,cnn}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Xi^{cnn}_{t}.

 \rho^{\xi,cd}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Xi^{cd}_{t}.

 \rho^{\xi,r}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Xi^{r}_{t}.

 \rho^{\xi,l}= Persistence parameter in the AR(1) process describing the evolution of  \Xi^{l}_{t}.

 \varsigma^{cnn}= Co-efficient on the consumer non-durable goods and non-housing serives component of the utility function.

 \varsigma^{cd}= Co-efficient on the consumer durable goods component of the utility function.

 \varsigma^{r}= Co-efficient on the consumer housing serives component of the utility function.

 \varsigma^{l}= Co-efficient on the labor supply components of the utility function.

 \phi^{h,gdp}= Co-efficient on GDP growth in the monetary policy reaction function.

 \phi^{\Delta h,gdp}= Co-efficient on change in GDP growth in the monetary policy reaction function.

 \phi^{\pi,gdp}= Co-efficient on GDP price inflation in the monetary policy reaction function.

 \phi^{\Delta \pi,gdp}= Co-efficient on the change in GDP price inflation in the monetary policy reaction function.

 \phi^{r}= Co-efficient on lagged nominal interest rates in the monetary policy reaction function.

 \chi^{cd}= Investment adjustment costs in the consumer durables evolution equation.

 \chi^{nr}= Investment adjustment costs in the non-residential capital evolution equation.

 \chi^{r}= Investment adjustment costs in the residential capital evolution equation.

 \chi^{l}= Parameter reflecting the size of adjustment costs in the labor sectoral adjustment cost function.

 \chi^{p}= Parameter reflecting the size of adjustment costs in re-setting prices.

 \chi^{w}= Parameter reflecting the size of adjustment costs in re-setting wages.

 \psi= Elasticity of utilization costs.

E. List of Endogenous and Exogenous Model Variables

 A^{nr}_{t}= Non-residential investment efficiency shock.

 A^{r}_{t}= Residential investment efficiency shock.

 A^{cd}_{t}= Consumer durables investment efficiency shock.

 E^{nr}_{t}= Expenditures on goods in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector for use in non-residential investment.

 E^{r}_{t}= Expenditures on goods in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector for use in residential investment.

 E^{cd}_{t}= Expenditures on goods in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector for use in consumer durables investment.

 E^{cnn}_{t}= Expenditures on goods in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector for use in consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services.

 E^{gf,cbi}_{t}= Exogenous expendiutre (by the government and foreign sector).

 H^{gdp}_{t}= Growth rate of real (chain-weighted) GDP.

 K^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}= The amount of utilized non-residential capital used in the slow-growing "consumption"goods sector.

 K^{u,nr,kb}_{t}= The amount of utilized non-residential capital used in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 K^{nr,cbi}_{t}= The physical amount of non-residential capital used in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 K^{nr,kb}_{t}= The physical amount of non-residential capital used in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 K^{nr}_{t}= The aggregate non-residential capital stock.

 K^{r}_{t}= The residential capital stock.

 K^{cd}_{t}= The consumer durables capital stock.

 L^{cbi}_{t}= Labor used in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 L^{kb}_{t}= Labor used in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 MC^{cbi}_{t}= Marginal cost in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 MC^{kb}_{t}= Marginal cost in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 P^{cbi}_{t}= Price level in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 P^{kb}_{t}= Price level in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 Q^{nr}_{t}= Price of installed non-residential capital.

 Q^{r}_{t}= Price of installed residential capital.

 Q^{cd}_{t}= Price of installed consumer durables capital.

 R_{t}= Nominal interest rate.

 R^{nr,cbi}_{t}= The nominal rental rate on non-residential capital used in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 R^{nr,kb}_{t}= The nominal rental rate on non-residential capital used in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 R^{nr}_{t}= The aggregate nominal rental rate on non-residential capital.

 R^{r}_{t}= The nominal rental rate on residential capital.

 R^{cd}_{t}= The nominal rental rate on consumer durables capital.

 U^{cbi}_{t}= The utilization rate of non-residential capital used in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 U^{kb}_{t}= The utilization rate of non-residential capital used in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 W^{cbi}_{t}= The nominal wage in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 W^{kb}_{t}= The nominal wage in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 X^{cbi}_{t}= Production in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 X^{kb}_{t}= Production in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 (Z^{kb}_{t})^{1-\alpha}= Level of capital-specific MFP.

 (Z^{m}_{t})^{1-\alpha}= Level of economy-wide MFP.

 \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t}= Growth rate of output in the consumption (slow growth) sector consistent with the growth rate of technology. (Note  \Gamma^{x,cbi}_{t} is not in general equal to  \ln(X^{cbi}_{t}/X^{cbi}_{t-1}). Rather it is equal to  \Gamma^{z,m}_{t}(\Gamma^{z,kb}_{t})^\alpha.)

 \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t}= Growth rate of output in the consumption (slow growth) sector consistent with the growth rate of technology. (Note  \Gamma^{x,kb}_{t} is not in general equal to  \ln(X^{kb}_{t}/X^{kb}_{t-1}). Rather it is equal to  \Gamma^{z,m}_{t}\Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}.)

 (1-\alpha)\Gamma^{z,kb}_{t}= The growth rate of the level of capital-specific MFP.

 (1-\alpha)\Gamma^{z,m}_{t}= The growth rate of the level of economy-wide MFP.

 \Theta^{l}_{t}= The elasticity of subsitution between the differentiated labor inputs into production.

 \Theta^{x,cbi}_{t}= The elasticity of subsitution between the differentiated intermediate inputs in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 \Theta^{x,kb}_{t}= The elasticity of subsitution between the differentiated intermediate inputs in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 \Lambda^{r}_{t}= The marginal utility of residential capital.

 \Lambda^{cd}_{t}= The marginal utility of durable goods.

 \Lambda^{cnn}_{t}= The marginal utility of non-durable goods and non-housing services consumption.

 \Lambda^{l,cbi}_{t}= The marginal dis-utility of supplying labor in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 \Lambda^{l,kb}_{t}= The marginal dis-utility of supplying labor in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 \Xi^{cnn}_{t}= Consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services consumption preference shock.

 \Xi^{cd}_{t}= Consumer durable capital stock preference shock.

 \Xi^{r}_{t}= Residential capital stock preference shock.

 \Xi^{l}_{t}= Labor supply preference shock.

 \Pi^{p,gdp}_{t}= The inflation rate of the GDP deflator.

 \Pi^{p,cbi}_{t}= The inflation rate for prices in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 \Pi^{p,kb}_{t}= The inflation rate for prices in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

 \Pi^{w,cbi}_{t}= The inflation rate of nominal wages in the slow-growing "consumption" goods sector.

 \Pi^{w,kb}_{t}= The inflation rate of nominal wages in the fast-growing "capital" goods sector.

F. Definitions of Stationary Model Variables

In this section we provide definitions for all of the variables of the model that must be transformed in order to render them stationary. Note that in going through our list of model variables we leave out those that are already stationary.

The model's output variables in stationary form are:

    \displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{cbi}_{t} =\frac{X^{cbi}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{X}^{kb}_{t}=\frac{X^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  

The model's expenditure variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{nr}_{t} =\frac{E^{nr}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{r}_{t} =\frac{E^{r}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{cd}_{t} =\frac{E^{cd}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{E}^{cnn}_{t}=\frac{E^{cc}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  

The model's marginal utility variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{r}_{t} =\Lambda^{r}_{t}Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cd}_{t} =\Lambda^{cd}_{t}Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{\Lambda}^{cnn}_{t} =\Lambda^{cnn}_{t}Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}  

The model's capital stock variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}=\frac{K^{u,nr,cbi}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{u,nr,kb}_{t}=\frac{K^{u,nr,kb}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr,cbi}_{t}=\frac{K^{nr,cbi}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr,kb}_{t}=\frac{K^{nr,kb}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{nr}_{t+1}=\frac{K^{nr}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{r}_{t+1}=\frac{K^{r}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{K}^{cd}_{t+1}=\frac{K^{cd}_{t}}{Z^{m}_{t}Z^{kb}_{t}}  

The model's relative (KB) output price variable in stationary form is:
\displaystyle \widetilde{P}^{kb}_{t}=\frac{P^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(\frac{Z^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{cbi}_{t}}\right)^{1-\alpha}
The model's real wage variables are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{W}^{cbi}_{t}=\frac{W^{cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\!\cdot\! \frac{1}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{W}^{kb}_{t}=\frac{W^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}\!\cdot\! \frac{1}{Z^{m}_{t}(Z^{kb}_{t})^{\alpha}(Z^{cbi}_{t})^{1-\alpha}}  

The model's real rental rate variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr,cbi}_{t}=\frac{R^{nr,cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr,kb}_{t}=\frac{R^{nr,kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{nr}_{t}=\frac{R^{nr}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{r}_{t}=\frac{R^{r}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{R}^{cd}_{t}=\frac{R^{cd}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(\frac{Z^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{cbi}_{t}}\right)^{1-\alpha}  

The model's real marginal cost variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{MC}^{cbi}_{t}=\frac{MC^{cbi}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{MC}^{kb}_{t}=\frac{MC^{kb}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(\frac{Z^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{cbi}_{t}}\right)^{1-\alpha}  

The model's relative price of installed capital variables in stationary form are:
    \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{nr}_{t}=\frac{Q^{nr}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(\frac{Z^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{cbi}_{t}}\right)^{1-\alpha}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{r}_{t}=\frac{Q^{r}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}}  
    \displaystyle \widetilde{Q}^{cd}_{t}=\frac{Q^{cd}_{t}}{P^{cbi}_{t}} \left(\frac{Z^{kb}_{t}}{Z^{cbi}_{t}}\right)^{1-\alpha}  


Table 1: Average Growth and Relative Price Changes (1984q1 to 2004q4).
  Average Real
Growth Rate
Average Nominal
Growth Rate
Average
Price Change*
Consumer non-durable goods and non-housing services 3 1/4 percent 6 1/4 percent n.a.
Consumer housing services 2 1/2 percent 6 1/4 percent 3/4 percent
Consumer durable goods 6 3/4 percent 6 1/2 percent -3 percent
Res. investment goods 3 3/4 percent 7 1/2 percent 1/2 percent
Non-res. investment goods 6 1/4 percent 6 1/4 percent -2 3/4 percent

*Relative to cons. non-durable goods & non-housing services prices.


Table 2: Cross Correlations: GDP and Major Private Expenditure Components
  -4 -3 -2 -1 0 +1 +2 +3 +4
Cons. non-dur. goods & non-hous. services -0.03 0.08 0.23 0.28 0.43 0.37 0.28 0.28 0.18
Cons. dur. goods 0.10 0.06 0.14 0.25 0.32 0.06 0.06 0.08 0.07
Res. inv. goods 0.15 0.19 0.34 0.31 0.44 0.15 - 0.08 - 0.12 - 0.15
Non-res. inv. goods 0.12 0.01 0.17 0.14 0.61 0.31 0.26 -0.09 -0.02


Table 3: Calibrated Parameters
 \beta  \alpha  \psi  \delta^{nr}  \delta^{cd}  \delta^{r}  \Theta^{x,cbi}_{\ast}  \Theta^{x,kb}_{\ast}  \Theta^{l}_{\ast}  \Gamma^{z,m}_{\ast}  \Gamma^{z,kb}_{\ast}  H^{x,gf}_{\ast}
0.990 0.260 5 0.030 0.055 0.004 7.000 7.000 7.000 1.003 1.004 0.250


Table 4: Prior and Posterior Distributions of the Model's Behavioral and Policy Parameters
Param. Prior
Type
Prior
Mean
Prior
S.D.
Posterior
Mode
Posterior
S.D.
Posterior
10th perc.
Posterior
50th perc.
Posterior
90th perc.
 h^{cnn} B 0.500 0.122 0.766 0.048 0.707 0.770 0.828
 h^{cd} B 0.500 0.122 0.571 0.196 0.372 0.600 0.919
 h^{r} B 0.500 0.122 0.500 0.128 0.328 0.490 0.665
 \nu G 2.000 1.000 1.287 0.735 0.805 1.554 2.600
 \chi^{p} G 2.000 1.000 2.331 0.808 2.294 3.193 4.338
 \eta^{p} B 0.500 0.224 0.257 0.124 0.163 0.313 0.481
 \chi^{w} G 2.000 1.000 1.555 1.478 1.268 2.750 4.944
 \eta^{w} B 0.500 0.224 0.296 0.147 0.138 0.328 0.529
 \chi^{nr} G 2.000 1.000 0.831 0.397 0.676 1.053 1.665
 \chi^{cd} G 2.000 1.000 0.145 0.082 0.055 0.181 0.275
 \chi^{r} G 6.000 1.000 10.198 2.590 8.085 10.852 14.793
 \chi^{l} G 2.000 1.000 0.766 1.703 0.412 1.366 3.615
 \eta^{l} B 0.500 0.224 0.779 0.202 0.377 0.702 0.910
 r^{\pi} N 2.000 1.000 3.532 0.515 2.947 3.561 4.251
 r^{\triangle{\pi}} N 0.500 0.400 -0.041 0.080 -0.137 -0.040 0.070
 r^{h,gdp} N 0.500 0.400 0.210 0.026 0.183 0.216 0.250
 r^{\triangle{h,gdp}} N 0.500 0.400 -0.084 0.025 -0.124 -0.092 -0.059
 \rho^r B 0.750 0.112 0.900 0.018 0.876 0.902 0.922


Table 5: Prior and Posterior Distributions of the Model's Shock Parameters
Param. Prior
Type
Prior
Mean
Prior
S.D.
Posterior
Mode
Posterior
S.D.
Posterior
10th perc.
Posterior
50th perc.
Posterior
90th perc.
 \rho^{a,nr} B 0.750 0.112 0.894 0.032 0.839 0.884 0.920
 \rho^{a,cd} B 0.750 0.112 0.842 0.115 0.619 0.802 0.908
 \rho^{a,r} B 0.500 0.150 0.527 0.103 0.379 0.519 0.648
 \rho^{\xi,cnn} B 0.750 0.112 0.795 0.079 0.660 0.778 0.867
 \rho^{\xi,cd} B 0.750 0.112 0.899 0.080 0.733 0.859 0.931
 \rho^{\xi,r} B 0.750 0.112 0.793 0.113 0.615 0.787 0.907
 \rho^{\xi,l} B 0.750 0.112 0.940 0.030 0.884 0.930 0.962
 \rho^{\gamma,m} B 0.500 0.150 0.305 0.079 0.211 0.315 0.418
 \rho^{\gamma,kb} B 0.750 0.112 0.927 0.051 0.823 0.903 0.949
 \rho^{x,gf} B 0.750 0.112 0.982 0.014 0.957 0.978 0.990
 \sigma_{a,nr} I 4.000 2.000 6.631 2.056 5.986 8.032 11.069
 \sigma_{a,cd} I 2.000 2.000 1.795 0.839 1.385 2.367 3.465
 \sigma_{a,r} I 4.000 2.000 8.168 2.505 6.181 8.724 12.737
 \sigma_{\xi,cnn} I 3.000 2.000 1.555 0.319 1.344 1.634 2.089
 \sigma_{\xi,cd} I 3.000 2.000 3.304 1.995 2.192 3.670 6.967
 \sigma_{\xi,r} I 3.000 2.000 2.453 4.550 2.094 3.976 11.102
 \sigma_{\xi,l} I 3.000 2.000 2.175 0.877 2.049 2.973 4.273
 \sigma_{r} I 0.200 2.000 0.112 0.011 0.101 0.114 0.130
 \sigma_{\gamma,m} I 0.500 2.000 0.766 0.067 0.688 0.769 0.859
 \sigma_{\gamma,kb} I 0.500 2.000 0.294 0.105 0.269 0.357 0.529
 \sigma_{x,gf} I 1.000 2.000 1.507 0.154 1.363 1.533 1.744
 \sigma_{\theta,x,cbi} I 0.500 2.000 0.526 0.200 0.496 0.703 0.995
 \sigma_{\theta,x,kb} I 0.500 2.000 0.394 0.164 0.326 0.485 0.752
 \sigma_{\theta,w} I 0.500 2.000 0.667 0.088 0.563 0.667 0.786


Table 6: Variance Decomposition of Main Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  H^{gdp}  \Pi^{p.gdp}  R
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 1 (0.02,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.02)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 5 (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.04,0.05,0.06)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.03,0.04,0.05)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.03,0.05,0.06)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 1 (0.01,0.03,0.04) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 5 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.02,0.04,0.07)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.03,0.06)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 1 (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.03,0.04,0.05) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 5 (0.03,0.04,0.05) (0.08,0.10,0.14) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 10 (0.04,0.05,0.07) (0.07,0.09,0.12) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{r}: 1 (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.02,0.02,0.03) (0.50,0.57,0.63)
 \epsilon^{r}: 5 (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.05,0.07,0.09) (0.05,0.07,0.08)
 \epsilon^{r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.06,0.08,0.10) (0.01,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.04,0.06,0.08) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.03,0.04,0.06) (0.01,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 5 (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.12,0.15,0.19) (0.02,0.04,0.06)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 10 (0.07,0.09,0.12) (0.19,0.24,0.29) (0.02,0.04,0.06)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 40 (0.49,0.59,0.69) (0.43,0.54,0.65) (0.00,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 1 (0.32,0.36,0.40) (0.18,0.22,0.27) (0.01,0.03,0.05)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 5 (0.29,0.35,0.41) (0.44,0.50,0.56) (0.01,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 10 (0.31,0.38,0.44) (0.40,0.46,0.53) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 40 (0.28,0.37,0.47) (0.20,0.27,0.35) (0.02,0.03,0.05)


Table 7: Variance Decomposition of Main Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  H^{gdp}  \Pi^{p.gdp}  R
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 1 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.51,0.58,0.66) (0.07,0.10,0.13)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.02,0.03,0.05)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 5 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 1 (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 1 (0.02,0.04,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.03,0.04)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 5 (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.03,0.07,0.11)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.04,0.07)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.03)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 1 (0.21,0.25,0.29) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.09,0.11,0.14)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 5 (0.43,0.50,0.56) (0.00,0.01,0.03) (0.54,0.59,0.65)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 10 (0.35,0.43,0.51) (0.00,0.01,0.04) (0.73,0.77,0.81)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 40 (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.04,0.07,0.10) (0.75,0.80,0.84)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 1 (0.21,0.23,0.26) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.06,0.08,0.10)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 5 (0.03,0.03,0.04) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.03,0.03,0.04)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 10 (0.02,0.03,0.03) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.01,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 40 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.02,0.03)


Table 8: Variance Decomposition of Demand Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  \widetilde{E}^{cnn}  \widetilde{E}^{r}  \widetilde{E}^{cd}  \widetilde{E}^{nr}
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 1 (0.15,0.18,0.20) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 5 (0.22,0.26,0.31) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.01,0.02,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 10 (0.20,0.25,0.31) (0.03,0.04,0.08) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 40 (0.02,0.02,0.04) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.13,0.26,0.44) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.12,0.27,0.45) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.11,0.31,0.49) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.06,0.16,0.31) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.04) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 5 (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.02,0.03,0.05) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 10 (0.03,0.05,0.07) (0.07,0.10,0.13) (0.01,0.02,0.02) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 40 (0.04,0.06,0.09) (0.06,0.09,0.13) (0.06,0.09,0.13) (0.02,0.04,0.07)
 \epsilon^{r}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.02,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{r}: 5 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{r}: 10 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.02,0.04,0.05) (0.01,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 5 (0.01,0.02,0.04) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.03,0.04,0.06) (0.01,0.02,0.04)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 10 (0.05,0.08,0.13) (0.07,0.09,0.13) (0.04,0.05,0.07) (0.01,0.02,0.04)
 \epsilon^{z,kb}: 40 (0.27,0.35,0.43) (0.05,0.08,0.14) (0.13,0.21,0.30) (0.00,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 1 (0.73,0.76,0.80) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 5 (0.55,0.61,0.67) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 10 (0.47,0.55,0.62) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 40 (0.13,0.17,0.21) (0.09,0.12,0.16) (0.01,0.02,0.04) (0.01,0.02,0.03)


Table 9: Variance Decomposition of Demand Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  \widetilde{E}^{cnn}  \widetilde{E}^{r}  \widetilde{E}^{cd}  \widetilde{E}^{nr}
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 5 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 10 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.85,0.88,0.91) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.68,0.76,0.83) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.46,0.58,0.67) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.19,0.34,0.50) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.10,0.23,0.40) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.05,0.15,0.33) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.02,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 1 (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.03,0.05,0.07) (0.20,0.24,0.29) (0.95,0.97,0.98)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 5 (0.02,0.04,0.06) (0.02,0.05,0.10) (0.27,0.33,0.40) (0.95,0.97,0.98)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.03) (0.24,0.34,0.43) (0.94,0.96,0.98)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 40 (0.25,0.34,0.43) (0.54,0.64,0.71) (0.24,0.34,0.46) (0.87,0.92,0.95)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)


Table 10: Variance Decomposition of Supply Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  L  \Pi^{w}  \Pi^{p,c}  \Pi^{p,k}
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 1 (0.03,0.04,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 5 (0.03,0.04,0.05) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 10 (0.02,0.03,0.03) (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cnn}: 40 (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 1 (0.02,0.05,0.08) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 5 (0.02,0.04,0.06) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 10 (0.01,0.02,0.04) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\xi,cd}: 40 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 1 (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.05,0.09,0.14) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.02,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 5 (0.05,0.07,0.10) (0.31,0.41,0.52) (0.09,0.12,0.15) (0.03,0.03,0.05)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 10 (0.13,0.18,0.25) (0.14,0.21,0.30) (0.09,0.12,0.16) (0.02,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{\xi,l}: 40 (0.47,0.60,0.71) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{r}: 1 (0.05,0.06,0.07) (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.02,0.02) (0.01,0.02,0.02)
 \epsilon^{r}: 5 (0.04,0.05,0.07) (0.08,0.10,0.13) (0.06,0.08,0.10) (0.02,0.03,0.04)
 \epsilon^{r}: 10 (0.03,0.04,0.05) (0.07,0.10,0.13) (0.08,0.10,0.12) (0.02,0.02,0.03)
 \epsilon^{r}: 40 (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.05,0.07,0.12) (0.08,0.11,0.13) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{z,k}: 1 (0.03,0.05,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.30,0.38,0.47)
 \epsilon^{z,k}: 5 (0.04,0.05,0.07) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.62,0.69,0.74)
 \epsilon^{z,k}: 10 (0.03,0.04,0.06) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.04) (0.76,0.81,0.85)
 \epsilon^{z,k}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.09,0.16,0.25) (0.05,0.11,0.20) (0.91,0.94,0.96)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 1 (0.24,0.28,0.32) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.13,0.17,0.22) (0.11,0.14,0.18)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 5 (0.09,0.12,0.16) (0.00,0.00,0.02) (0.51,0.57,0.63) (0.13,0.17,0.22)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 10 (0.02,0.04,0.06) (0.01,0.03,0.06) (0.53,0.59,0.65) (0.08,0.11,0.15)
 \epsilon^{z,m}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.16,0.22,0.29) (0.43,0.51,0.59) (0.03,0.04,0.06)


Table 11: Variance Decomposition of Supply Aggregates (1, 5, 10, and 40 quarter horizon)
Shocks  L  \Pi^{w}  \Pi^{p,c}  \Pi^{p,k}
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 1 (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.66,0.73,0.79) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 5 (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.04,0.06,0.08) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,c}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 1 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.25,0.35,0.45)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 5 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,x,k}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 1 (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.80,0.87,0.92) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.01,0.02,0.02)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 5 (0.01,0.02,0.02) (0.07,0.12,0.21) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.01,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 10 (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{\theta,l}: 40 (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 1 (0.01,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 5 (0.01,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 10 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,r}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 1 (0.04,0.08,0.11) (0.00,0.00,0.00) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 5 (0.03,0.06,0.09) (0.01,0.01,0.03) (0.00,0.01,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 10 (0.01,0.02,0.05) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.01,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{a,cd}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 1 (0.29,0.34,0.39) (0.00,0.01,0.02) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.01,0.02,0.04)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 5 (0.41,0.47,0.53) (0.12,0.20,0.32) (0.00,0.01,0.04) (0.00,0.01,0.03)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 10 (0.47,0.53,0.60) (0.43,0.56,0.66) (0.00,0.02,0.06) (0.00,0.01,0.02)
 \epsilon^{a,nr}: 40 (0.21,0.31,0.42) (0.34,0.46,0.58) (0.10,0.15,0.22) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 1 (0.02,0.03,0.03) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 5 (0.02,0.02,0.03) (0.02,0.03,0.05) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.01,0.01)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 10 (0.01,0.02,0.02) (0.02,0.03,0.04) (0.01,0.02,0.03) (0.00,0.00,0.01)
 \epsilon^{x,gf}: 40 (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.01) (0.00,0.00,0.00)


Figure 1: Model Overview
Figure 1 is a diagrammatic representation of the model.  It reports all of the agents of the model and the  exchanges of factors and goods that take place between the agents.  Private agents are represented by rectangular  boxes in the figure; the central bank is represented by an oblong in the lower right corner of the diagram.   Shown in the extremes of the diagram are boxes for the following private agents: households (shown by a box in  the top left corner of the figure); non-residential capital owners (shown by a box in the bottom left corner of  the figure); residential capital owners (shown by a box on the right edge of the figure); and, consumer durable  capital owners (shown by a box on the right edge of the figure just below the box for residential capital owners).   Shown in the center part of the diagram are boxes for the following private agents: monopolistically competitive  intermediate CBI goods producers (shown by a box in the upper left portion of the center of the diagram);  monopolistically competitive intermediate KB goods producers (shown by a box in the lower left portion of the  center of the diagram); final CBI goods producers (shown by a box in the upper right portions of the center of  the diagram); and, final KB goods producers (shown by a box in the lower right portions of the center of the  diagram).  The boxes representing the agents in the model are connected with lines with arrows, which show the  exchanges of factors and goods that take place between the agents.  The following exchanges are shown in the  diagram: household rent labor to monopolistically competitive intermediate CBI goods producers and  monopolistically competitive intermediate KB goods producers; non-residential capital owners rent non-residential  (utilized) capital to monopolistically competitive intermediate CBI goods producers and monopolistically  competitive intermediate KB goods producers; monopolistically competitive intermediate CBI goods producers sell  CBI intermediate goods to final CBI goods producers; monopolistically competitive intermediate KB goods producers  sell KB intermediate goods to final KB goods producers; final CBI goods producers sell final CBI goods to both  household and to residential capital owners; final KB goods producers sell final KB goods to both non-residential  capital owners and consumer durable capital owners; residential capital owners rent residential capital to  households; and consumer durable capital owners rent consumer durables to households.  Three arrows are shown  stemming from the central bank in the lower right corner of the diagram.  These denote the influence of the  nominal interest rate, which is set by the central bank and influence all components of private spending in the  model.
Notes:
  1. CBI represents the economy's slow growing sector, so denoted because consumption [C] goods and services account for most of its output and it is produced by the business and institutions [BI] sector of the economy.
  2. KB represents the economy's fast growing sector, so denoted because its output is capital [K] goods and it is produced by the business [B] sector of the economy.


Figure 2: Impulse Responses: Monetary Policy Shock
Figure 2 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a monetary  policy shock.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the individual charts the  horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes out to 30 quarters in  each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis are marked only for the  charts in the bottom row of Figure 2.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown  (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures  on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked  in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -4.5  with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -1, -2, -3, and -4; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0 to -2 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.5, -1, -1.5, and -2.  In the second row of the figure  the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods  sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and  hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 1  to -8.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -2, -4, -6, and -8; the vertical axis for the fourth  chart runs from 5 to -10 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 5, 0, -5, and -10.  In the third row of the  figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the  ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price  inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to  -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.2 and -0.4; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs  from 1 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 1, 0.5, 0, and -0.5.  The impulse response functions  for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  In all cases the  largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4  quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector  of the economy and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is smaller than -1 percent  of its baseline value; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about -3 percent; the  largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -1.2 percent; the largest response  for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy, expenditures on durable consumption goods,  expenditures on nonresidential investment, and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -5 percent;  the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector, the rate of price  inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector, and the rate of GDP price inflation is about -3.5 percent; and the  largest response for the nominal interest rate is about +0.75 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either  side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse  response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 3: Impulse Responses: Capital Efficiency Shock (Non-Res. Goods)
Figure 3 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a capital  efficiency shock to non-residential goods.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all  12 of the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy;  this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.   The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 3.  In the first row of the figure the  following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption''  goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures  on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first  three of these charts runs from 1 to -0.25 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 1, 0.5, and 0; the  vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.2 to -0.2 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0.1,  0, -0.1, and -0.2.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the  left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption  goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical  axes for the first three of these charts runs from 2 to -0.75 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 1.5,  1, 0.5, 0, and -0.5; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 1 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 1, 0.5, 0, -0.5.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown  (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price  inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The  vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 12 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  10, 5, 0, and -5; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.03 to -0.01 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 0.03, 0.02, 0.01, 0, and -0.01.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables included in  the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted, the largest response (in an absolute  sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock. The  largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy and expenditures on  nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services remains very close to its baseline value; the largest  responses for expenditures on residential investment dips from about -0.1 percent to about 0.7 percent by the  25th quarter; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.75 percent;  the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about 0.6 percent,  expenditures on durable consumption goods dips from about -0.5 percent to about 0.5 around the 20th quarter,  expenditures on nonresidential investment is about 1.4 percent, and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector  is about 0.5 percent; the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is  about 2 percent in the 25th quarter, the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about 5  percent and then dips to about -2.5 percent by the 10th quarter, the rate of GDP price inflation is about -1  percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about 0.025 percent.  Two thin dotted  lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent  credible set for each impulse response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their  corresponding solid line.


Figure 4: Impulse Responses: Capital Efficiency Shock (Dur. Goods)
Figure 4 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a capital  efficiency shock to durable goods.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of  the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this  goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The  axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 4.  In the first row of the figure the following  impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector  of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential  investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of  these charts runs from 0.1 to -0.25 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.1, and -0.2; the vertical  axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.04 to -0.04 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.04, 0.02, 0,  -0.02 and -0.04.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the  left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption  goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical  axes for the first three of these charts runs from 2 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  2, 1, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 1 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels  shown at 1, 0.5, 0, and -0.5.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting  from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation in  the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes  for the first three of these charts runs from 15 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 10, 5 and 0;  the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.03 to -0.01 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  0.03, 0.02, 0.01, 0, and -0.01.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables included in the figure are  shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  In all cases the largest response (in an absolute sense) in the  impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest  responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy and expenditures on  nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services remains very close to its baseline value; the largest  responses for expenditures on residential investment is about 0.3 percent; the largest response for hours worked  in the ''consumption'' goods sector varies from -0.02 to +0.01 percent; the largest response for output in the  fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about 0.4 percent, expenditures on durable consumption  goods is about 1.4 percent, expenditures on nonresidential investment remains very close to its baseline value,  and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about 0.5 percent; the largest response for the rate of  price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 10 percent; the rate of price inflation in the  ''capital'' goods sector is about 10 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about 10 percent; and the  largest response for the nominal interest rate is about 0.0225 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on  either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for  each impulse response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding  solid line.


Figure 5: Impulse Responses: Efficiency Shock (Res. Goods)
Figure 5 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to an  efficiency shock to residential investment.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all  12 of the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy;  this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.   The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 5.  In the first row of the figure the  following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods  sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on  residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first  three of these charts runs from 0.5 to -0.1 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.2, and 0; the  vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.06 to -0.02 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.06,  0.04, 0.02, 0, -0.02.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from  the left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable  consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.   The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.01 to -0.07 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels  shown at 0, -0.02, -0.04, and -0.06; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.02 to -0.06 with  tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.02, 0, -0.02, -0.04, and -0.06.  In the third row of the figure the  following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption''  goods sector; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and  the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 20 to -2 with  tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 20, 15, 10, 5, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  4 to -2 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 4, 2, 0 and -2.  The impulse response functions for the  12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  In all cases the largest  response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters)  of the initial shock.  The responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy  and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services remains at about their baseline value  throughout the simulation period; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about  0.3 percent; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 0.025 percent;  the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.025  percent, expenditures on durable consumption goods is about -0.035 percent, expenditures on nonresidential  investment is about -0.025 percent, and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.025 percent;  the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 10 percent,  the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about 7.5 percent, and the rate of GDP price  inflation is about 10 percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about 2.5 percent.   Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions  of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are  quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 6: Impulse Responses: Preference Shock (Non-Dur. Goods & Serv.)
Figure 6 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a preference  shock to non-durable goods and services.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12  of the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this  goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis  are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 6.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse  responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the  economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential  investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of  these charts runs from 0.3 to -0.65 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0, -0.2, -0.4, and -0.6;  the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.6 to -0.2 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  0.6, 0.4, 0.2, 0 and -0.2.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting  from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable  consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.   The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.1 to -0.6 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 0, -0.2, and -0.4; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.4 to -0.4 with tick-marks  and tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.2, 0, -0.2 and -0.4.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse  responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector;  the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal  interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 15 to -1 with tick-marks and  tick-mark labels shown at 10, 5 and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.03 to 0 with tick-marks  and tick-mark labels shown at 0.03, 0.02, 0.01, and 0.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables  included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  In all cases the largest response (in  an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the  initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy  and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is about 0.2 percent of its baseline  value; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about -0.4 percent; the largest  response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is a little above 0.2 percent; the largest  response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.2 percent, expenditures  on durable consumption goods is about -0.4 percent, expenditures on nonresidential investment is near -0.2 percent,  and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.2 percent; the largest response for the rate of price  inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 8 percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital''  goods sector is about 6 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about 7 percent; and the largest response for  the nominal interest rate is smaller than 0.02 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either side of the  thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse response  function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 7: Impulse Responses: Preference Shock (Durable Goods)
Figure 7 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a preference  shock to durable goods.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the individual  charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes out to 30   quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis are marked only   for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 7.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse responses are   shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy;   expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and   hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from  0.2  to -0.9 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0, -0.2, -0.4, -0.6 and -0.8; the vertical axis  for the fourth chart runs from 0.1 to -0.3 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.1, 0, -0.1, -0.2   and -0.3.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left):  output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods;  expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes  for the first three of these charts runs from 0.3 to -0.4 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  0.2, 0, -0.2, and -0.4; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.4 to -0.4 with tick-marks and  tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.2, 0, -0.2 and -0.4. In the third row of the figure the following impulse  responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector;  the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal  interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.4 to -0.05 with tick-marks  and tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.3, 0.2, 0.1, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.15 to -0.05 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.15, 0.1, 0.05, 0, and -0.05.  The impulse response  functions for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless  noted the largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year  (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption''  goods sector of the economy and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is about  -0.1 percent of its baseline value; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about  -0.5 percent; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.15 percent;  the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.2 in the  initial quarters but later turns up and is about 0.2 percent around the 15th quarter; expenditures on durable  consumption goods is about -0.2 in the initial quarters but later turns up and is about 0.2 percent around the  15th quarter; expenditures on nonresidential investment is about -0.2 in the initial quarters but later turns  up and is about 0.2 percent around the 15th quarter; the largest response for hours worked in the ''capital''  goods sector is about -0.2 in the initial quarters but later turns up and is 0.2 percent around the 15th quarter;  the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 0.3 percent;  the response rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector remains near its baseline value; the rate  of GDP price inflation is about 0.3 percent; and the largest response of the nominal interest rate is about  0.05 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and  lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted  lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 8: Impulse Responses: Preference Shock (Res. Goods)
Figure 8 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a preference  shock to residential goods.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the individual  charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes out to 30  quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis are marked only   for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 8.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse responses are   shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures  on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked  in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.4 to 0  with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.3, 0.2, 0.1, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.03 to -0.01 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.03, 0.02, 0.01, 0 and -0.01.  In the second row of  the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital''  goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment;  and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from  0 to -0.06 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.02, and -0.04; the vertical axis for the fourth chart  runs from  0.01 to -0.03 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.01, 0, -0.01, -0.02 and -0.03.  In the  third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price  inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate  of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs   from 10 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 5, 0, and -5; the vertical axis for the fourth chart   runs from 2 to 0 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 2, 1.5, 1, 0.5, and 0.  The impulse response functions  for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted, the  largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4  quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector  of the economy and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services remains at about their  baseline value throughout the simulation period; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment   is about 0.05 percent; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about .0025  percent; the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about  -0.005 percent; expenditures on durable consumption goods is about -0.0075 percent, expenditures on nonresidential  investment is about -0.005 percent; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.005 percent; the  largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 1 percent; the rate  of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about 0.5 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about  0.5 percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about 0.25 percent.  Two thin dotted  lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent  credible set for each impulse response function. These dotted lines in the output in the slow growing ''consumption''  goods sector of the economy remain very close to the corresponding solid line; in expenditures on nondurable  consumption goods and nonhousing services the lines also remain very close to the corresponding solid line; for  expenditures on residential investment the upper dotted line peaks around 0.35; and in hours worked in the  ''consumption'' goods sector the upper dotted line peaks around 0.02. In output in the fast growing ''capital''  goods sector of the economy, the lower dotted line dips to around -0.035; in expenditures on durable consumption  goods the lower dotted line dips to -0.05; in expenditures on nonresidential investment the lower line dips to  -0.02; and in hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector the line drops to -0.03. In the rate of price inflation  in the ''consumption'' goods sector the upper line peaks a little above 5; in the rate of price inflation in the  ''capital'' goods sector the upper line peaks around 7; in the rate of GDP price inflation the upper line peaks  around 6; and in the nominal interest rate upper line peaks at about 1.5.


Figure 9: Impulse Responses: Preference Shock (Labor Supply)
Figure 9 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a preference  shock to the labor supply.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the individual  charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes out to 30  quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis are marked only   for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 9.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse responses are   shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures  on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked  in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -0.9  with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.2, -0.4, -0.6,  and -0.8; the vertical axis for the fourth  chart runs from 0 to -0.4 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.1, -0.2, -0.3, and -0.4. In the second  row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast growing   ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential   investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts  runs from 0 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.2, and -0.4; the vertical axis for the   fourth chart runs from  0.2 to -0.6 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0, -0.2, -0.4, and -0.6. In  the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price  inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate  of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs   from 25 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 20, 10, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart   runs from 10 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 10, 5, 0, and -5.  The impulse response  functions  for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted, the largest  response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of  the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy  is about -0.1 percent and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is about -0.05; the  largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about -0.6 percent near the 15th quarter; the largest  response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.15 percent; the largest response for output  in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.3 percent; expenditures on durable  consumption goods is about -0.2 percent; expenditures on nonresidential investment is just above -0.4 percent near  the 10th quarter; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.3 percent in the 8th quarter; the  largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 17 percent; the rate  of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about 15 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about  15 percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is 4 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which  lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set  for each impulse response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding  solid line.


Figure 10: Impulse Responses: Permanent Economy-wide MFP Shock
Figure 10 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables of a  permanent economy-wide MFP shock.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12   of the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the   economy; this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every   10 quarters.  The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 10.  In the first row   of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow   growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and   nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption''   goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 5 to -1 with tick-marks   and tick-mark labels shown at 4, 2, and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.5 to -1   with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.5, 0, -0.5, and -1.  In the second row of the figure the   following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital''   goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential   investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of   these charts runs from 3 to 0 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 3, 2, 1 and 0; the vertical   axis for the fourth chart runs from  1 to -1 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 1, 0.5, 0,   -0.5, and -1.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from   the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation   in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The   vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -0.20 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels  shown at 0, -0.05, -0.1 and -0.15; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.15 to -0.05 with  tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.15, 0.1, 0.05, 0 and -0.05.  The impulse response functions  for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted  the largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year  (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock. The largest responses for output in the slow growing  ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy is about -1 percent and expenditures on nondurable consumption  goods and nonhousing services is about -1; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment  steadily rises to about 4 percent by the end of the 30 quarters; the largest response for hours worked in  the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.75 percent; the largest response for output in the fast  growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about 2 percent, expenditures on durable consumption  goods is about 1.5 percent, expenditures on nonresidential investment is just above 2 percent, and hours  worked in the ''capital'' goods sector dips initially to about -0.25 and then moves up to 0.75 percent by  about the 10th quarter; the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods  sector is about -0.125 percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.125  percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about -0.125 percent; and the largest response for the nominal  interest rate is 0.05 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report  the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse response function.  In all 12  cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 11: Impulse Responses: Permanent Capital-specific MFP Shock
Figure 11 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables of a   permanent capital-specific MFP shock.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all  12 of the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the   economy; this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every   10 quarters.  The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 11.  In the first row   of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow   growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and   nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption''   goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 5 to -10 with tick-marks   and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -5, and -10; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.5 to -1   with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.5, 0, -0.5, and -1.  In the second row of the figure the   following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital''   goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential   investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of   these charts runs from 22.5 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 20, 15, 10, 5 and 0; the   vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  5 to -5 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 5, 0   and -5.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the   left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation in   the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical  axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -0.7 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown  at 0, -0.2, -0.4 and -0.6; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs  from 0.2 to -0.2 with tick-marks  and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0.1, 0, -0.1 and -0.2.  The impulse response functions for the 12  variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted the largest  response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4  quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods  sector of the economy is about -1.5 percent and expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing   services is about -1.5 percent; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about   -4 percent which occurs around the 20th quarter; the largest response for hours worked in the   ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.5 percent which occurs around the 25th quarter; the largest   response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy grows to about 10 percent   by the 30th quarter, expenditures on durable consumption goods is about 7.5 percent by the 30th quarter,   expenditures on nonresidential investment rises to just above 10 percent by the 30th quarter, and hours   worked in the ''capital'' goods sector dips to about -3 and then grows to about 3 percent by about the 25th quarter; the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about  -0.05 percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector dips from about -0.5 percent and   grows to about -0.1 percent by the 30th quarter; the rate of GDP price inflation is about -0.15 percent;   and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about -0.1 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which  lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible  set for each impulse response function.  In all cases these dotted lines are quite close to their  corresponding solid line, except the Residential Inventory where the top line is about 4 and the bottom line  reaches about -9.


Figure 12: Impulse Responses: Price Markup Shock (CBI sector)
Figure 12 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables of a price  markup shock in the CBI sector.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of  the individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy;  this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.   The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 12.  In the first row of the figure the  following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption''  goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services;  expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical  axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.2 to -0.9 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown  at 0.2, 0, -0.2, -0.4, -0.6 and -0.8; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.1 to -0.3 with  tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.1, 0, -0.1, -0.2, and -0.3.  In the second row of the figure  the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left):  output in the fast growing ''capital''  goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential  investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first three of  these charts runs from 0.3 to -0.45 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0, -0.2 and -0.4;  the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.4 to -0.4 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at  0.4, 0.2, 0, -0.2 and -0.4.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown  (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of  price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest  rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.45 to -0.1 with tick-marks and  tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.3, 0.2, 0.1 and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.15 to  -0.05 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.15, 0.1, 0.05 and -0.05.  The impulse response functions  for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted the  largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4  quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods  sector of the economy is about -0.15 percent; the largest response for expenditures on nondurable consumption  goods and nonhousing services is about -0.1 percent; the largest responses for expenditures on residential  investment is about -0.5 percent; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is  about -0.15 percent; the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy  dips from nearly -0.2 percent and grows to +0.2 percent by the 10th quarter, expenditures on durable consumption  goods dips from -0.2 percent and grows to 0.2 percent by the 10th quarter, expenditures on nonresidential  investment dips from -0.15 percent and grows to about 0.2 percent by the 15th quarter, and hours worked in the  ''capital'' goods sector dips from about -0.2 percent and grows to about 0.2 percent by about the 10th quarter;  the largest response for the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about 0.3 percent;  the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector remains at its baseline value throughout the  simulation period; the rate of GDP price inflation is about 0.25 percent; and the largest response for the  nominal interest rate is about 0.075 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either side of the thick  solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse response function.   In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 13: Impulse Responses: Price Markup Shock (KB sector)
Figure 13 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables of a price  markup shock in the KB sector.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the  individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes  out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis  are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 13.  In the first row of the figure the following  impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector  of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services; expenditures on  residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for the first  three of these charts runs from 0.3 to -0.3 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.2, 0, and -0.2; the  vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.15 to -0.05 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.15,  0.1, 0.05, 0 and -0.05.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting  from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable  consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.   The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -1 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels  shown at 0, -0.5 and -1; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.5 to -1 with tick-marks and  tick-mark labels shown at 0.5, 0, -0.5 and -1.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses  are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of   price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.   The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.4 to -0.1 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels  shown at 0.4, 0.3, 0.2, 0.1 and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.02 to -0.02 with tick-marks  and tick-mark labels shown at 0.02, 0.01, 0, -0.01 and -0.02.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables  included in the figure are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  Unless noted the largest response (in an  absolute sense) in the impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the initial  shock.  The largest responses for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy is about  0.05 percent; the largest response for expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is  about 0.05 percent; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about 0.15 percent and  dips to about -0.2 percent by the 30th quarter; the largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption''  goods sector is about 0.05 percent; the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector  of the economy is about -0.55 percent; expenditures on durable consumption goods is about -0.55 percent;  expenditures on nonresidential investment is about -0.55 percent; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods  sector is about -0.55 percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector remains at its  baseline value throughout the simulation period; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is  about 0.3 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about 0.05 percent; and the largest response for the nominal  interest rate grows from just over 0.01 percent to -0.0175 percent.  Two thin dotted lines--which lie on either  side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible set for each impulse  response function.  In all 12 cases these dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line.


Figure 14: Impulse Responses: Wage Markup Shock
Figure 14 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to a wage markup shock.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the individual charts the horizontal  axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with  tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.  The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom  row of Figure 14.  In the first row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left):  output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods  and nonhousing services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.    The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.7 to 0 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown  at 0.6, 0.4, 0.2 and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.4 to 0 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 0.4, 0.3, 0.2, 0.1 and 0.  In the second row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown  (starting from the left): output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable  consumption goods; expenditures on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The  vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0.8 to -0.1 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown  at 0.8, 0.6, 0.4, 0.2 and 0; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  1 to -0.5 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 1, 0.5, 0 and -0.5.  In the third row of the figure the following impulse responses are shown  (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector; the rate of price inflation  in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes  for the first three of these charts runs from 0.02 to -0.06 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.02, 0,  -0.02 , -0.04 and -0.06; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0.01 to -0.02 with tick-marks and tick-mark  labels shown at 0.01, 0, -0.01 and -0.02.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables included in the figure  are shown by a thick solid line in each chart.  In all 12 cases the largest response (in an absolute sense) in the  impulse response function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses  for output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy is about 0.1 percent; the largest response  for expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is about 0.1 percent; the largest responses  for expenditures on residential investment is about 0.4 percent; the largest response for hours worked in the  ''consumption'' goods sector is about 0.15 percent; the largest response for output in the fast growing ''capital''  goods sector of the economy is just above 0.4 percent; expenditures on durable consumption goods is about 0.4 percent;  expenditures on nonresidential investment is about 0.45 percent; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is  about 0.5 percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.04 percent; the rate  of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.04 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about  -0.04 percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about -0.015 percent.  Two thin dotted  lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the 90 percent credible  set for each impulse response function.  These dotted lines are quite close to their corresponding solid line in all  cases except the residential investment response where the upper line reaches 0.6 percent and the lower line is about  0.2 around the 10th quarter.


Figure 15: Impulse Responses: Autonomous Spending Shock
Figure 15 is a 12 panel chart that reports the impulse response functions of key model variables to an   autonomous spending shock.  The individual charts are shown in 3 rows and 4 columns.  For all 12 of the   individual charts the horizontal axis shows the number of quarters since the shock hits the economy; this   goes out to 30 quarters in each chart with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown for every 10 quarters.    The axis are marked only for the charts in the bottom row of Figure 15.  In the first row of the figure   the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the slow growing   ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing   services; expenditures on residential investment; and hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector.    The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs from 0 to -0.225 with tick-marks and tick-mark   labels shown at 0, -0.05, -0.1 -0.15 and -0.2; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from 0 to   -0.08 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -0.02, -0.04, -0.06 and -0.08.  In the second row   of the figure the following impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): output in the fast   growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy; expenditures on durable consumption goods; expenditures   on nonresidential investment; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector.  The vertical axes for   the first three of these charts runs from 0.05 to -0.04 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0,   -0.1, -0.2, -0.3 and -0.4; the vertical axis for the fourth chart runs from  0.4 to -0.4 with tick-marks   and tick-mark labels shown at 0.4, 0.2, 0, -0.2 and -0.4.  In the third row of the figure the following   impulse responses are shown (starting from the left): the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption''   goods sector; the rate of price inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector; the rate of GDP price   inflation; and the nominal interest rate.  The vertical axes for the first three of these charts runs   from 2 to -22 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0, -5, -10, -15, and -20; the vertical axis   for the fourth chart runs from 0.04 to -0.02 with tick-marks and tick-mark labels shown at 0.04, 0.02, 0   and -0.02.  The impulse response functions for the 12 variables included in the figure are shown by a   thick solid line in each chart.  The largest response (in an absolute sense) in the impulse response   function takes place within a year (that is 4 quarters) of the initial shock.  The largest responses for   output in the slow growing ''consumption'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.04 percent; the   largest response for expenditures on nondurable consumption goods and nonhousing services is about -0.025   percent; the largest responses for expenditures on residential investment is about -0.15 percent; the   largest response for hours worked in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -0.06 percent; the largest   response for output in the fast growing ''capital'' goods sector of the economy is about -0.25 percent;   expenditures on durable consumption goods is about -0.275 percent; expenditures on nonresidential   investment is about -0.25 percent; and hours worked in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -0.3   percent; the rate of price inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector is about -15; the rate of price   inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector is about -15 percent; the rate of GDP price inflation is about   -15 percent; and the largest response for the nominal interest rate is about 0.03 percent.  Two thin   dotted lines--which lie on either side of the thick solid line--report the upper and lower regions of the   90 percent credible set for each impulse response function.  These dotted lines are quite close to their   corresponding solid line in all cases.


Figure 16: Observable series: realized paths and one-step ahead forecasts.
Figure 16 is an 11 panel charts that reports the realized paths and one-step ahead forecasts of the model's observable series.  Note that the series plotted in these charts are all expressed relative to the variable's  steady-state so are always centered around zero.  A negative value of the series therefore means below  steady-state; a positive value of the series means above steady-state.  The individual charts are shown in  4 rows and 3 columns; there is no chart in the third column of the fourth row.  For all 11 of the individual  charts the horizontal axis is the estimation period for the model, that is 1984:Q1 to 2005:Q4; tick marks are  shown for 1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000.  In the first row of the figure realized paths and one-step ahead  forecasts are shown (starting from the left) for: nominal GDP growth; nominal non-durable consumption goods  and nonhousing services growth; and nominal nonresidential investment growth.  The vertical axis for the nominal  GDP growth chart ranges from about -2 percent to about 1-1/2 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0, and 1.  The  realized path of nominal (quarterly) GDP growth fluctuates within the bounds of -1/2 percent to 1/2 percent  for the first couple of years of the sample before spiking several times to around 3/4 to 1 percent between  1987 and 1990.  In 1991 the realized series drops sharply to a bit lower than -1 percent.  For most of the  remainder of the decade the realized series remains between the bounds of -1/2 percent to 1/2 percent although  in 1994 it drops to about -3/4 percent and in 1999 it reaches about 3/4 percent.  From late 2000 to about 2003  nominal GDP growth is negative at about -3/4 percent, after this growth is between 0 to 1/2 percent.  The  one-step ahead forecast is less volatile than the realized path.  The one-step ahead forecast does not spike  as much as the realized path between 1987 and 1990; it also misses a few quarters of negative nominal growth  in the realized path during the 1990s, and it is not as negative as the realized path in 2000 to 2003.  The  vertical axis for the nominal non-durable consumption goods and nonhousing services growth chart ranges from  about -2 percent to about 1-1/2 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0, and 1.  The realized path of nominal  (quarterly) non-durable consumption goods and nonhousing services growth dips to -1 percent in 1985 and then  fluctuates between 0 and 1 percent for the remainder of the decade.  In 1991 it dips to almost -1 percent  before spiking to 1 percent the next year.  It then fluctuates close around 0 percent until the late 1990s  when it moves up to fluctuate around 3/4 percent.  It drops to -1 percent in 2001 before fluctuating around  0 percent for a couple of years and then spiking to 1 percent in 2004.  The one-step ahead forecast is less  volatile than the realized path.  The one-step ahead forecast does not spike down as much as the realized  path in 1985 and is lower than the realized path over the rest of the decade.  For the remainder of the sample  the one-step ahead forecast follows the realized path but the former moves around about half as much as the  latter.  The vertical axis for the nominal nonresidential investment growth chart ranges from -10 percent to  10 percent with tick-marks at -10, 0, and 10 percent.  The realized path of nominal (quarterly) nonresidential  investment growth is very volatile.  The series dips to around -5 percent for a number of quarters in 1985 and  1986.  It then spikes up to 10 percent in about 1987 before dropping down to about -8 percent the next year and  spikes up to about 5 percent shortly after.  The series spikes down to about -7 percent a couple of times in  the early 1990s.  It jumps back up to about 5 percent and then for the rest of the decade fluctuates sharply  between -5 and 5 percent.  It drops down to about -8 percent in 2001 and for a couple years after that before  moving up to fluctuate around 0 percent until the end of the sample.  In the chart the one-step ahead forecast  appears to follow the realized path quite closely; this is a bit of an illusion since the one-step ahead  forecast actually follows the realized path with a lag but given the volatility of the realized path in the  chart the series appear to move together closely.  In the second row of the figure realized paths and one-step  ahead forecasts are shown (starting from the left) for: nominal durable consumption goods; nominal residential  investment growth; and wage inflation.  The vertical axis for the nominal durable consumption goods growth chart  ranges from about -7 percent to about 8 percent with tick-marks at -5, 0, and 5.  The realized path of nominal  (quarterly) durable consumption goods growth is also very volatile.  For about the first three years of the sample  the realized path of nominal (quarterly) durable consumption goods growth fluctuates between -5 and 5 percent.   The series then grows at a slightly positive rate the remainder of the decade before falling below zero in the  first few years of the 1990s.  From about 1992 to about 2001 the series fluctuates between about -3 and 3 percent;  in 2002 it spikes up to 5 percent, after which is fluctuates quite close to zero for the remainder of the sample  period.  In the chart the one-step ahead forecast appears to follow the realized path quite closely, with the  exception of the early 1990s, where the one-step ahead forecast does not drop as much as the realized series.   As with nominal nonresidential investment growth the general concorrence of the two series is a bit of an illusion  since the one-step ahead forecast actually follows the realized path with a lag but given the volatility of the  realized path in the chart the series appear to move together closely.  The vertical axis for the nominal  residential investment growth chart ranges from about -8 percent to 5 percent with tick-marks at -5, 0, and 5.   The realised path of nominal (quarterly) residential investment growth spikes to 5 percent in 1986, it then drops  negative--although only to about -1 or -2 percent--before dropping down sharply in 1991 to -8 percent for a could  of quarters.  It moves back positive after this, fluctuating between 0 and 3 percent until about 1994, when it  again drops down to about -4 percent.  From about 1996 to 2002 the series fluctuates between about -2 and 2 percent,  before posting consistently high growth rates of around 4 percent in the last two years of the sample period.  The  one-step ahead forecast does not follow the path of the realized series very closely at all.  Although the  one-step ahead forecast does capture the spike in the realized series in 1986, for the rest of the sample it  moves up and down with the realized series but always by a noticably less amount.  In particular, in the last  couple of years of the sample, when the realized series fluctuates aroudn 4 percent, the one-step ahead forecast  fluctuates around zero percent.  The vertical axis for the wage inflation chart ranges from about -2 percent to  3 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0, 1, and 2.  Wage inflation moves between -1 and 1 percent from the begining  of the sample to about 1994.  Between 1984 and 1989 wage inflation is above and below zero for roughly the same  fractions of the sample.  From 1990 to 1992 wage inflation is entirely above zero while over 1993 and 1994 it is  entirely below zero.  Around 1995 wage inflation spikes down to slightly below -1 percent and remains below  0 percent (although above -1 percent) until 1997.  In 1998 and 1999 wage inflation fluctuates sharply between -1 and 1 percent, but is negative a bit more often than it is positive. In 2000 it spikes very sharply above  2 percent, it then drops down to -3/4 percent.  For the remainder of the sample, wage inflation fluctuates  between -1 and 1/2 percent. The one-step ahead forecast is considerably less volatile than the realized path.   During the 1984 to 1999 period, when the realized path of wage inflation fluctuates between -1 and 1 percent the one-step ahead forecast fluctuates between about -1/2 to 1/2 percent.  The one-step ahead forecast also  does not capture some movements in the realized series.  For example, for a large part of the 1990 to 1992  interval when the realized path of wage inflation is above zero the one-step ahead forecast is mostly below  zero and over the 1993 to 1997 interval when the realized path is negative the one-step ahead forecast  fluctuates very close to zero.  For the remainder of the sample the one-step ahead forecast follows smoothly the volatile realized series.  In the third row of the figure realized paths and one-step ahead forecasts  are shown (starting from the left) for: hours; the rate of inflation for GDP prices; and the rate of inflation  for prices in the ''consumption'' goods sector.  The vertical axis for the hours chart ranges from about  -5 percent to 7 percent with tick-marks at -4, -2, 0, 2, 4, and 6.  The realized series in the hours chart is  considerably smoother than the realized paths for most other variables.  The series starts the sample at  0 percent before dropping sharply in the second quarter of the sample to about -3 percent.  The series dips  again to about -5 percent after which it moves up steadily reaching 2 percent in 1988.  It remains at about  that level for about a year before moving down back to -5 percent in 1992.  From this trough until 1998 the  series moves up steadily to 6 percent although the series flattens out for about a year around 1995.  The realized series for hours remains at 6 percent for about 2 years.  From the end of 2000 to 2004 the series moves down to trough at -2-1/2 percent.  It edges up slightly after that and ends the sample at about  -2 percent.  The one-step ahead forecast is almost indistinguishable from the realized series.  The vertical  axis for the rate of inflation for GDP prices chart ranges from about -1 percent to 1 percent with tick-marks  at -1/2, 0, 1/2, and 1.  The realized series for the rate of inflation for GDP prices moves in a jagged manner around the a low frequency path that starts the sample at 0 percent, moves up to about 1/4 percent by 1987,  then moves down to about -1/4 percent by 1997, before moving back to around 0 percent in 2001 where it  remains for the remainder of the sample.  The one-step ahead forecast follows the same low frequency path  but is noticably less volatile than the realized series.  The vertical axis for the rate of inflation in the  ''consumption'' goods sector chart ranges from about -1-1/2 percent to 1-1/2 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0,  1.  The realized series for the rate of inflation in the ''consumption'' goods sector moves in a jagged manner around the a low frequency path that starts the sample at 0 percent, moves up to about 1/2 percent by 1990, before moving down back to 0 percent in about 1994 where the low frequency path remains for the remainder  of the sample.  The realized path is much more volatile around the low frequency path in the late 1980s where  it is as low a -1 percent in 1986 and as high 1 percent in 1989.  From 1990 to 2000 the realized series fluctuates between about -1/2 and 1/2 percent.  In 2001 the series spikes a little below -1/2 percent after which it moves up above zero and then spikes down, up again, and down again in the remaining years of the  sample.  The one-step ahead forecast follows the same low frequency path but is noticably less volatile than  the realized series.  In the fourth row of the figure realized paths and one-step ahead forecasts are shown  (starting from the left) for: the rate of inflation for prices in the ''capital'' goods sector; and the  nominal funds rate.  The vertical axis for the rate of inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector chart ranges  from about -2 percent to 1 percent with tick-marks at -2, -1, 0, and 1.  The realized series for the rate of  inflation in the ''capital'' goods sector fluctuates between about -1/2 and 1/2 percent from the start of the  sample to about 1995.  The series is reasonably volatile during this period with some noticable spikes in  1986, 1988, and 1990.  The realized series moves down, albeit in a jagged fashion, to -1 percent.  The series  then fluctuates around -1 percent for the remainder of the sample with a noticable dip in about 2003 and a sharp spike in 2004.  The one-step ahead forecast follows the realized series reasonably closely but is  less volatile.  The vertical axis for the nominal federal funds rate chart ranges from about -2 percent to  1-1/2 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0, and 1.  The realized series in the nominal federal funds rate chart is  considerably smoother than the realized paths for most other variables (except for hours, which is equally smooth).  The realized series starts the sample at 0 percent before moving up to about 1/2 percent where it  remains for about one year.  It then moves back down to 0 percent where it remains for about a year before moving up to 1 percent in 1988.  It then moves back down to -3/4 percent by 1993 where it remains for about  one year.  It then moves up to around 0 percent, where it remains for about 3 years before dipping and then moving up just a little above 0 percent in 2000.  After this the realized series moves down quickly to  -1 percent where it remains until the end of the sample.  The one-step ahead forecast follows the realized  series very closely.


Figure 17: Smoothed Paths of Key Persistent Shocks
Figure 17 is the first of two 5 panel charts that report the smoothed paths of key persistent shocks in the  model.  Three lines are shown for each chart: A black line which represents the median value for each path  and two grey dashed lines, which lie above and below the black line, which represent the upper and lower  bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets.  The individual charts are shown in 5 rows and a single column.   The persistent shocks are all plotted relative to the variable's steady-state so are always centered around  zero.  The 5 persistent shocks shown in this figure are (from top to bottom): the consumer non-durable goods  and nonhousing services preference shock; the consumer durable capital stock preference shock; the residential  capital stock preference shock; the labor supply preference shock; and a shock to the growth rate of real  (chain-weighted) GDP, which represents an autonomous spending growth shock.  For all of the 5 individual charts  the horizontal axis is the estimation period for the model, that is 1984:Q1 to 2005:Q4; tick marks are shown  for 1986, 1988, 1990, 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000, 2002, and 2004.  The vertical axis for the consumer  non-durable goods and nonhousing services preference shock chart ranges from about -7 percent to 6 percent  with tick-marks at -5, 0, and 5.  The median value of this shock path begins the sample at about 0 percent where it remains for about a year.  It moves down to -6 percent in early 1986 and then moves back up to 0 percent  by early 1987.  It remains near 0 percent until early 1988 after which it moves up to about 4 percent at  which it keeps until early 1991.  For the next two year it moves several times down and then up between about  3 percent and 0 percent.  In early 1993 the series dips to about -2 percent then returns to about 0 percent later that year.  From this time until about 1999 the shock path fluctuates very closely around 0 percent. The shock path then moves up to about 4 percent in 2000 where it holds for about a year before moving down  to about -4 percent in mid 2001.  From here until the end of sample in 2005 the series moves up gradually  to 0 percent--albeit with a some fluctuations.  The lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the  paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the median value of the shock path extremely closely.  The vertical  axis for the consumer durable goods capital stock preference shock chart ranges from about -18 percent  to 18 percent with tick-marks at -10, 0, and 10.  For the first three years of the sample the median value of  the shock path fluctuates between about 0 and 8 percent.  From early 1987 to early 1990 the shock path  fluctuates around 10 percent.  It then moves down steadily reaching -5 percent in about 1993 before it moves  up to reach 0 percent in early 1995.  From this point until early 2001 the shock path fluctuates but  nonetheless remains very close to 0 percent.  After this the shock path moves down (with a few fluctuations)  to about -12 percent by early 2004 where it about remains until the end of the sample.  For most of the  sample period the lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets  follow the mediam value of the shock path reasonably closely, however in the interval 1987 to 1990 and 2002  to 2005 the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets lie about 3 or so percentage points  above and below the median path.  The vertical axis for the residential capital stock preference shock  chart ranges from about -8 percent to 6 percent with tick-marks at -5, 0, and 5.  The median value of this shock  path remains very close to 0 percent for all of the sample period.  A few exceptions are in 1986 when the  shock path moves up to about 2 percent, 1991 when it moves down to about -2 percent and 2004 when it is about  2 percent again.  The lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets  diverge noticably from median-value shock path although it is generally only one of these series--that is,  either the upper bound or the lower bound--that diverge from the median-value shock path.  Over the interval  1984 to 1987 the upper bound of the credible set averages about 4 percentage points above the median-value  shock path, while the lower bound lies very close to it.  Over the interval 1989 to 2002 the lower bound of  the credible set lies below the median-value shock path, while the upper bound lies very close to it. For most of the time between 1989 and 1995 the lower bound lies of the credible set lies about 3 to 4 percentage  points below the median-value shock path, although in 1990 and 1991 it lies about 8 percentage points below. For most of the time between 1996 and 2002 the lower bound lies of the credible set lies only a couple of  percentage points below the median-value shock path.  Over the interval 2003 to 2005 the upper bound of the  credible set averages about 4 percentage points above the median-value shock path, while the lower bound lies  very close to it.  The vertical axis for the labor supply preference shock chart ranges from about  -20 percent to 15 percent with tick-marks at -20, -10, 0, and 10.  The median value of this shock path begins  the sample at about 12 percent from where it moves down steadily reaching about 2 percent in 1989.  It then  moves up to about 8 percent in 1990 where it remains for about 2 years.  It then moves down steadily to about -18 percent in 1997, where it remains for about 2 years, before moving up steadily to 0 percent by 2005. The  lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the median value  of the shock path reasonably closely.  For most of the sample these lines lie about one percentage point  above and below the median shock path; over 1996 to 2001, however, these lines lie a couple of percentage  points above and below the median shock path.  The vertical axis for the shock to the real GDP growth rate  shock (that is autonomous spending growth shock) ranges from about -15 percent to 25 percent with tick-marks  at -20, 0, 10, and 20.  The median value of this shock path begins the sample at about 10 percent from where  it drifts up gradually until it reached about 20 percent in 1991.  From here it moves up quite sharply to  25 percent in mid 1991 after which is moves down again reaching about 5 percent in late 1994.  The median  value of the shock path remains at about 5 percent until around 1997 after which it continues to move down  to about -8 percent in 2001.  It then moves up to 0 percent in 2002 before heading down again, this time to  15 percent by the end of the sample. The lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths'  90 percent credible sets follow the median value of the shock path reasonably closely.  These lines lie  about one percentage point above and below the median shock path for most of the sample; from 1998 onwards,  however, the lines are essentially equal to the median shock path.


Figure 18: Smoothed Paths of Key Persistent Shocks
Figure 18 is the second of two 5 panel charts that report the smoothed paths of key persistent shocks in the  model.  Three lines are shown for each chart: A black line which represents the median value for each path  and two grey dashed lines, which lie above and below the black line, which represent the upper and lower  bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets.  The individual charts are shown in 5 rows and a single column.   The persistent shocks are all plotted relative to the variable's steady-state so are always centered around  zero.  The 5 persistent shocks shown in this figure are (from top to bottom): the growth rate of economy-wide  MFP shock; the growth rate of capital-specific MFP shock; the non-residential investment efficiency shock;  the consumer durables investment efficiency shock; and the residential investment efficiency shock. The vertical axis for the growth rate of economy-wide MFP shock chart ranges from about -3 percent to 3 percent  with tick-marks at -2, 0, and 2.  The median value of this shock path begins the sample at about 0 percent and  until about 1990 fluctuates within 1/2 percentage point around 0 percent.  In 1991 the series spikes down to about  2-1/4 percent after which it returns to 0 percent from where it fluctuates within about 1 percentage point  around 0 percent until early 2003.  In 2003 and 2004 the series displays two upward spike in the series to about  2 percent.  The lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the  median value of the shock path extremely closely.  The vertical axis for the growth rate of capital-specific MFP  shock chart ranges from about -1-1/2 percent to 3 percent with tick-marks at -1, 0, 1, and 2.  The median value  of this shock path begins the sample at about 1/2 percent before moving down to about -1/4 percent in late 1986. It then moves up, peaking slightly at 1 percent in 1988, after which is edges down to about 1/2 percent over 1989 before moving back up to 1 percent in mid 1990.  The series then moves down steadily to about -1/2 percent in 1994  before moving up to reach about 1-1/2 percent in 1997.  It remains at about this level until 2002 when it moves up a touch more the about 2 percent.  After this it steps down to about 1/2 percent in 2004 and 2005.  The lines  representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the median value of the  shock path extremely closely.  The vertical axis for the non-residential investment efficiency shock chart ranges  from about -40 percent to 30 percent with tick-marks at -20, 0, and 20.  The median value of this shock path  begins the sample at about 20 percent, spikes down to 10 percent and back up to 20 percent in 1986.  The series then moves down to 0 percent in 1987 before moving up--albeit with some fluctuations--to about 25 percent in 1988. Immediately after the series spikes down to 0 percent before jumping back up to about 10 percent.  It remains at  about until about 1990, albeit with a few fluctuations.  The series then moves down to 0 percent in 1991 and until 2000 fluctuates around zero with notable departures only in 1992 and 1994 when the series spikes down to about -15 percent.  After 2000 the series moves down to reach about -35 percent in 2002.  It jumps immediately back up to -20 percent after which it edges down very slightly to just below -20 percent by the end of the sample.  The lines  representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the median value of the  shock path extremely closely.  The vertical axis for the consumer durables investment efficiency shock chart ranges  from about -10 percent to 12 percent with tick-marks at -10, 0, and 10.  The median value of this shock path  fluctuates within about 3 percentage points of 0 percent from the start of the sample to about 1988, it then moves up to 5 percent over 1989 and then spikes about about 8 percent in 1990.  The series then moves back down to  0 percent in 1992, -4 percent in 1993 and then back up to 0 percent in 1995.  From this point until 2001 the series fluctuates between about 0 and 3 percent.  The series then moves down--albeit with fluctuations--to about -5 percent in 2004 where it remains for the rest of the sample.  For most of the sample period the lines representing the  upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent credible sets follow the mediam value of the shock path quite  closely, however in the interval 1987 to 1990 and 2002 to 2005 the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent  credible sets lie about 3 or so percentage points above and below the median path.  The vertical axis for the  residential investment efficiency shock chart ranges from about -40 percent to 25 percent with tick-marks at -20, 0,  and 20.  The median value of this shock path begins the sample at about 0 percent and moves up to about 18 percent in 1986.  It then moves back down to 0 percent in 1987 where it fluctuates between -10 and 10 percent until 1990. The series drops down sharply to about -30 percent in late 1990 and early 1991, it then jumps up to 0 percent where it fluctuates again between about -10 and 10 percent unitl late 1994.  After this series moves down to about -20 percent in 1995.  It jumps up them to about 10 percent and then fluctuates around zero until about 2001 when it spikes down to -20 percent.  From here until the end of the sample the series moves up--albeit with  fluctuations.  In 2004 the series reaches about 20 percent from where it edges down a little and by the end of the  sample the series is at about 5 percent.  The lines representing the upper and lower bounds of the paths' 90 percent  credible sets follow the median value of the shock path extremely closely.



Footnotes

* Rochelle M. Edge ([email protected]), Michael T. Kiley ([email protected]), and Jean-Philippe Laforte ([email protected]) are affiliated with the Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies Section of the Federal Reserve Board. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors alone and should not be attributed to the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or any other members of its staff. Return to Text
2. In developing the model we experimented with the possibility of one common capital efficiency shock and two specific efficiency shocks, (to the non-residential capital and consumer durables evolution equations). The model with uncorrelated shocks, however, offered the better fit, likely due to the fact that expenditure patterns on these different types of capital have been quite different, especially of late. Return to Text
3. As with the capital evolution equations we did, in developing the model, experiment with having one preference shock that was common to all goods-derived components of utility and two shocks that were specific to the flow of services from consumer durables and from residential investment. This assumption does not materially alter the overall fit of the model, since these types of preference shocks have so small a role in accounting for aggregate fluctuations. Return to Text
4. This transformation provides us with a scaling of hours that is more consistent with the output of our model economy. Return to Text
5. This model therefore implies a number of equalities that are not consistent with U.S. NIPA prices measurements, notably  P^{XCBI}\neq P^{ECNN}\neq P^{ER} and  P^{XKB}\neq P^{ECD}\neq P^{ENR}. Return to Text
6. The exception to this, however, is non-durable goods and non-housing services consumption growth. Issues associated with the ability of DSGE models to explain consumption are also observed in Smets and Wouters [2004]. Return to Text
7. These adjustment costs parameters imply an elasticity of investment with respect to the capital-stock specific measure of marginal q of about one for consumer durables and about 1/7 for residential investment. Return to Text
8. We note some skepticism regarding the structural interpretation of the habit parameters given that microeconomic evidence (Dynan [2000]), and some macroeconomic evidence (Kiley [2005]) suggest that the support for habit persistence is quite weak. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text