The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Foreign Holdings of U.S. Treasuries and U.S. Treasury Yields

Daniel O. Beltran, Maxwell Kretchmer, Jaime Marquez, and Charles P. Thomas

NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.


Abstract:

Foreign official holdings of U.S. Treasuries increased from $400 billion in January 1994 to about $3 trillion in June 2010. Most of this growth is accounted for by a handful of emerging market economies that have been running large current account surpluses. These countries are channeling their savings through the official sector, which is then acquiring foreign exchange reserves. Any shift in policy to reduce their current account surpluses or dampen the rate of reserves accumulation would likely slow the pace of foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasuries. Would such a slowing of foreign official purchases of Treasury notes and bonds affect long-term Treasury yields? Most likely yes, and the effects appear to be large. By our estimates, if foreign official inflows into U.S. Treasuries were to decrease in a given month by $100 billion, 5-year Treasury rates would rise by about 40-60 basis points in the short run. But once we allow foreign private investors to react to the yield change induced by the shock to foreign official inflows, the long-run effect is about 20 basis points.

Keywords: Foreign official inflows, treasury yields, reserves, capital flows

JEL classification: F31, F32, F34



1  Introduction

As economies are becoming increasingly financially integrated, longer-term bond yields are increasingly determined in international markets. This calls into question the ability of central banks to influence longer-term interest rates by the setting of short-term rates. For example, Greenspan (2005) was concerned about the failure of the longer-term interest rates to rise after the Fed began tightening monetary policy starting in mid-2004 (figure 1). During this period, foreign purchases of Treasury notes and bonds were particularly strong (figure 2), and some studies (Warnock and Warnock (2009) and Bernanke, Reinhart, and Sack (2004)) found evidence that these purchases contributed to lower bond yields. Such a decoupling of long-term interest rates from the short-term interest rate, which is set by the monetary authority, has important implications for the effectiveness of monetary policy. In addition, unexpected shifts in foreign demand for U.S. Treasuries could cloud the signals extracted from movements in long-term interest rates.

Bernanke (2005) has attributed some of the decline in long-term interest rates in the United States and other advanced economies since 2000 to a "global savings glut." Indeed, global foreign exchange reserves have risen sharply since 2000 (figure 3). A significant share of global foreign exchange reserves are invested in U.S. Treasury securities- the share was 36 percent as of June 2010. As shown by the red area in figure 4, foreign official holdings of U.S. Treasuries increased from $400 billion in January 1994 to about $3 trillion in June 2010. Most of this growth is accounted for by a handful of emerging market economies that have been running large current account surpluses. Figure 5 plots the geography of total foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities over time. As shown by the combined pink areas, China, Japan, and the other emerging market countries experienced the fastest growth. These countries are channeling their savings through the official sector, which is then acquiring foreign exchange reserves. Any shift in policy to reduce their current account surpluses or dampen the rate of reserves accumulation would likely slow the pace of foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasuries.

Would such a slowing of foreign official purchases of Treasury securities affect their yields? As acknowledged by Wu (2005), answering this question is difficult for many reasons, most of which have not been adequately addressed in the literature. First, the direction of causation between foreign demand for Treasury securities and their prices (or yields) is likely to go both ways. Second, long-term interest rates are influenced by forward looking variables which are typically unobservable, such as expectations of long-run inflation and other macroeconomic variables, which makes identifying the effects of foreign official inflows more difficult. Third, changes in asset prices induced by shifts in foreign official demand may be, in time, partially offset by the actions of private investors. So not taking these actions into account may bias the estimated effect of foreign official purchases. Finally, data on interest rates, macroeconomic variables, and foreign holdings are often highly autocorrelated or even non-stationary, so the potential for "discovering" spurious relationships is great when fitting the levels of the economic time series (Granger and Newbold (1974)). The goal of this paper is to uncover the relationship between foreign purchases of U.S. Treasury securities and their yields while avoiding these traps. This task requires a more sophisticated modeling approach than the single-equation methodology popular in the literature.

The first of these traps is neglecting the interdependency between Treasury prices and foreign demand. Nearly all previous studies assume that foreign governments do not optimize their foreign reserves portfolio, thus treating foreign official inflows as exogenous.1 However, surveys of central banks suggest that most reserve managers in fact do change their reserve portfolios in response to changes in Treasury prices and other macroeconomic variables. For example, a recent survey by the BIS found that reserve managers are increasingly behaving like private asset managers, emphasizing returns relative to liquidity and capital preservation (Borio, Galati, and Heath (2008)).2 The BIS survey indicated that over two-thirds of central banks employ external managers, that almost all central banks use value-at-risk methodologies to measure market risk. Papaioannou, Portes, and Siourounis (2006) and others have found evidence suggesting that central banks pursue a mean-variance portfolio diversification strategy. Indeed, as shown below, our statistical tests strongly reject the null hypothesis that foreign official inflows into U.S. Treasuries are exogenous to changes in Treasury prices. Foreign private flows are also likely to be endogenous, but we did not find strong and valid instruments for them.

To address the second concern- that long-term interest rates are influenced by forward looking expectations which are typically unobservable- we use two measures of risk premia: the term-premium derived from the three-factor affine term-structure model of D'Amico, Kim, Wei (2010), and realized excess holding period returns. By construction, both of these measures of risk premia are undistorted by the effects of expected changes in the Fed's monetary policy stance.

To avoid the potential for discovering spurious relationships from regressions on highly correlated or non-stationary data, we difference the data to obtain flow measures for our variables. By using data expressed in first differences, we are estimating the short run elasticity between foreign official flows and changes in yields. Previous studies use cumulated 12-month flows (Warnock and Warnock (2009)) and the level of foreign holdings (Bertaut, DeMarco, Kamin, and Tryon (2011)) to estimate the long-run effect on yields. However, the variables used in these studies are either highly autocorrelated, non-stationary, or trend-stationary.3 Thus, when estimating the long-run effect, we use a cointegrated vector auto-regression (VAR) model which is suitable for regressing non-stationary variables.

Controlling for the actions of foreign private investors to any misalignments in Treasury yields induced by changes in foreign official demand requires a more sophisticated model. Foreign private investors may trade both short- and long-term securities for hedging or speculative purposes, and may also view U.S. sovereign bonds and say, German sovereign bonds as close substitutes. Our VAR model captures the interactions between foreign official and foreign private flows into long-term Treasuries.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section we describe the data used to estimate our models. In section 3 we examine the effects of foreign inflows into U.S. Treasuries on the term premium, using OLS, two-stage least squares, and cointegrated VAR models. The following section conducts a similar analysis on realized excess returns. In section 5 we place our results in the context of the existing literature. The last section concludes.


2  Data

2.1  Interest Rates and Risk Premia

Following Dai and Singleton (2002), we define the term premium for an $ n-$period bond as

$\displaystyle TP_{t}^{n}\equiv R_{t}^{n}-\underbrace{\frac{1}{n}\sum\limits_{i=0}^{n-1}E_{t}(r_{t+i})}_{\text{EH component}}$ (1)

where $ R_{t}^{n}$ is the yield of an $ n$-period zero-coupon bond at time $ t$ , and $ r_{t}\equiv R_{t}^{1}$ is the short rate. Equation 1 can be used to decompose the long-term rate into the "expectations hypothesis" (EH) component, which measures the expected path of the short rate, and the term-premium component, which measures inflation risk, liquidity risk, and other risk factors that affect the long-rate. Thus, in principle, the term premium is undistorted by the expected changes in Fed's monetary policy stance.

We focus on the 5-year term-premium for U.S. Treasury securities because this maturity is close to the average maturity of U.S. Treasury and agency securities held by foreigners, and because prices of 5-year Treasury notes are readily observed.4 The expected path of the short rate in equation 1 is not observable, which makes the term premium unobservable as well. Both are derived from the arbitrage-free 3-factor term-structure model of D' Amico, Kim, and Wei (2010) which builds upon the model of Kim and Wright. The model uses a continuous-time nominal stochastic discount factor to derive the price of an n-period nominal zero-coupon bond. Arbitrage-free pricing implies that once risk is factored into account, there are no arbitrage opportunities from buying one security and shorting some combination of other securities. Three underlying latent factors are used to describe the behavior of the yield curve through time. Although these factors have no macroeconomic interpretation, they are often related to the level, slope, and curvature of the yield curve.5

The term-premium described above is a model-dependent and ex-ante measure of risk premium. But we also consider an ex-post measure of risk premia that is not model dependent: realized excess returns. More specifically, we use the holding period return from buying a 6-year bond at time $ t$ and selling it as a 5-year bond 1 year later, minus the return of a 1-year bond:

$\displaystyle D_{t+1}^{6}=\ln \frac{P_{t+1}^{5}}{P_{t}^{6}}-r_{t}.$ (2)

We compute $ D_{t+1}^{6}$ using the fitted zero-coupon yield curve estimates of Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright (2007).

Figure 6 illustrates the timing of bond-purchases that give rise to the excess returns realized one-year ahead. At time $ t$, the investor borrows funds for 1-year at a fixed rate $ r_{t}$ to purchase a 6-year Treasury bond. The investor holds the bond for 1 year (the holding period), during which its price will fluctuate because of changing macroeconomic fundamentals and possibly (as we will test) changes in foreign demand for Treasury securities. Excess returns are realized at time $ t+1$ when the 6-year bond is sold as a 5-year bond, and the 1-year loan is paid off.

Our two measures of risk premium are conceptually related to each other- the term premium is equal to the average of future realized excess returns for bonds of decreasing maturity.6 Figure 7 compares our ex-ante measure of risk premium (the 5-year term-premium) to our ex-post measure of risk premium (excess holding period return of a 6-year bond realized 1-year in the future). Although realized excess returns are more volatile then the term premium, the two measures are positively correlated (the Pearson's product-moment correlation is 0.45 with a t-statistic of 6.36).

Because foreign official flows occur during the holding period, they can only influence the price of the 5-year bond (originally purchased as a 6-year bond) when it is sold at the end of the holding period, $ P_{t+1}^{5}$. Thus our a-priori hypothesis is that unanticipated foreign bond purchases occurring during the holding period would exert upward pressure on $ P_{t+1}^{5}$, thus increasing excess returns realized at time $ t+1$.

2.2  Foreign Holdings of Treasury Securities

We use monthly data from the Treasury International Capital (TIC) reporting system, which is the most complete source for data on foreign official and foreign private net purchases of U.S. Treasury notes and bonds, (gross purchases by foreign residents minus gross sales by foreign residents).7

A well known problem with the monthly TIC transactions data is that they undercount foreign official acquisitions of U.S. securities because they do not capture acquisitions through foreign intermediaries (Bertaut, Griever, and Tryon (2006)).8 To estimate the "missing flows," we make use of the detailed and more accurate annual reports on foreign holdings of U.S. securities (as in Bertaut and Tryon (2007) and Warnock and Warnock (2009)), as well as data on custodial holdings at FRBNY.9Further, the adjusted flows are "survey consistent" because they insure that the change in measured holdings between two annual surveys equals the sum of cumulated flows during the period and the estimated valuation change; this approach for estimating flows improves upon the approach of Warnock and Warnock (2009) and Beraut and Tryon (2007) because we perform an additional adjustment based on changes in custody holdings at FRBNY.10

As noted earlier, foreign official investors have been acquiring Treasuries at a much faster pace than foreign private investors. The share of all Treasuries held by official investors has climbed from 15 percent in 1994 to 46 percent in 2007 (figure 8). Foreign investors have also shown an increasing preference for longer-maturity Treasuries. As shown by the black line in figure 9, the share of long-term Treasuries (notes and bonds) held by foreigners has steadily climbed from 30 percent in 1994 to 75 percent in 2007. Meanwhile, the share of short-term Treasuries (bills) held by foreigners, the dashed green line, remained in the 30 to 40 percent range. In this paper we focus our attention on the effects of foreign purchases of long-term Treasuries. Figure 10 shows that the share of long-term Treasuries held by foreign officials steadily increased from 10 to 50 percent between 1994 and 2007, while the private share trailed the official share until 1998 and then flattened out at around 20 percent.

Our sample comprises monthly data from January 1994 to June 2007. The beginning date is restricted by the availability of data for our explanatory variables (discussed later), and the end period is chosen to intentionally exclude the financial crisis period. During the 2007-2011 period, financial markets (and Treasury yields) were very volatile. During this turbulent period, events such as the Lehman bankruptcy and subsequent implosion of repo markets, the near-collapse of AIG and the government agencies Freddie and Fannie, the implementation of the Troubled Asset Relief Program, the commencement of large scale asset purchases by the Fed, and the various episodes of the European sovereign debt crisis would likely obscure the relationships we care about.

2.3  Other Control Variables

To control for other factors which might affect the term premium, our regressions include the following explanatory variables: (1) Implied volatility of options on U.S. and German five-year sovereign note futures; (2) Liquidity premium ($ LP$) measured as the difference between the synthetic off-the-run and on-the-run five-year Treasury note yields; (3) VIX index of stock market volatility which is correlated with flight-to-safety flows and dollar appreciations; (4) Year-over-year change in industrial production ( $ \Delta IP)$; (5) VAR estimates of exogenous oil-specific demand shocks using the data from Kilian (2009); (6) U.S. federal government budget balance; (7) Cochrane and Piazessi factors ( $ CP_{t}^{1-5}$ and $ CP_{t}^{6-9}$), linear combinations of forward rates that have been shown to forecast future realized excess returns quite well (Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005)), and (8) a measure of global risk appetite developed by Credit Suisse which captures the relative performance of safe assets like government bonds versus volatile assets like equities and emerging country bonds.11


3  Foreign Inflows Into Treasuries and the Term Premium

Our a-priori hypothesis is that increases in foreign official and private holdings of U.S. Treasuries exert upward pressure on bond prices, thus lowering yields and the term premium (assuming the expected path of the short-rate remains unchanged). To examine the short-run dynamics between foreign inflows into long-term Treasuries and the 5-year term premium we estimate a model using monthly flow data. We then examine the long-run relationships between foreign inflows and the term premium by estimating a cointegrated VAR model.

3.1  Instrumental Variables Approach

The instrumental variables model is specified as

$\displaystyle TP_{t}^{60}-TP_{t-1}^{60}=\Delta TP_{t}^{60}=\alpha +\gamma t+\mathbf{X} _{t}\beta _{1}+\mathbf{Z}_{t}\beta _{2}+u_{t},$  $\displaystyle u_{t}\sim N(0,\sigma ^{2})$ (3)

where $ \mathbf{X}_{t}$ is the vector of regressors assumed to be exogenous and $ \mathbf{Z}_{t}$ is the vector of regressors assumed to be endogenous. The explanatory exogenous variables are those described in section 2.3, expressed as changes. The endogenous regressor is the monthly foreign official flow into U.S. Treasury notes and bonds as a share of marketable Treasury notes and bonds outstanding. Because we did not find strong and valid instruments for foreign private flows, we treat this variable as exogenous. When we tried estimating the model treating both private and official flows as endogenous, the estimated coefficient on foreign official flows was practically unchanged, but using weak instruments made the estimated coefficient on foreign private flows extremely sensitive to slight changes in the specification.

We experiment with several instrumental variables that are related to foreign exchange reserve accumulation (which are heavily invested in U.S. Treasuries) but not directly related to risk premia. The instruments are listed below:

The strength of these instruments will be accessed by examining the Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic. When two or more instruments are used, we judge their validity by the Hansen J-statistic (under the null that the instruments are uncorrelated with the error terms).

Table 1 shows OLS and two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimates; the latter approach treats foreign flows as endogenous. Counter to what we would expect, the coefficient on foreign official and foreign private flows are positive in the OLS specification (column 1), but small. In columns 2 and 3, we use two-stage least squares (2SLS) and scale foreign flows by marketable Treasury securities outstanding. Column 2 shows the first stage results for the regression on foreign official inflows. Japanese interventions and the exogenous oil supply shocks are both associated with stronger official inflows. Increases in the VIX index have a negative effect on foreign official inflows, perhaps because the VIX is an indicator of flight-to-safety behavior by private investors. When the VIX is high, investors are nervous and flee to the relative safety of U.S. Treasuries- the dollar appreciates and the pressure for emerging market countries to intervene to combat the appreciation of their currencies is reduced. Column 3 shows the second stage results, the coefficient on foreign official flows suggests that an inflow equal to one percent of the amount of Treasuries outstanding lowers the 5-year term premium by 13.5 basis points. In June 2007, the amount of marketable long-term Treasuries outstanding held by the public (excluding holdings of the Federal Reserve System) was $2,915 billion. Therefore, our coefficient implies that an inflow of $100 billion into U.S. Treasury notes and bonds would lower the 5-year term premium (and hence the 5-year yield) by 46 basis points (100/29.15*(-13.5)).

In columns 4 and 5, we do the same 2SLS estimation but instead of scaling foreign flows by the amount of Treasuries outstanding, we scale them by U.S. nominal GDP. Because GDP is larger than the amount of Treasuries outstanding, the coefficient becomes larger. U.S. GDP was roughly $14 trillion in June 2007, so the coefficient of -0.696 implies that an inflow of $100 billion into Treasury notes and bonds would lower the 5-year term premium by -50 basis points (100/140*(-69.6)).

The Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic in specification 3 of 15.7 is a bit below the critical value 19.9 of the Stock and Yogo (2005) size test with size $ r=0.10$, so our instruments are not that strong. However, in specification 5 we may have a weak instruments problem because the Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic of 9.9 does not pass the 10 percent size test (it does pass the 20% size test). For both IV specifications, the instruments appear to be valid according to the Hansen J statistic; we fail to reject the null that the instruments are uncorrelated with the error terms. For both IV regressions, the Hausmann-Wu endogeneity test rejects the null hypothesis that foreign official flows are exogenous at the 5 percent level of significance. And in both cases, the Pagan-Hall tests fail to reject the null that the residuals are homoscedastic. However, we find some evidence that the residuals may be autocorrelated, as the Cumby-Huizinga tests reject the null that the errors are non-autocorrelated at the 5 percent level. This is somewhat surprising because the variables are already expressed in first differences. Even so, to address the potential problem of autocorrelated residuals, we report Newey-West heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent (HAC) standard errors.

In columns 1 and 2 of table 2, we try different combinations of included instruments. In specification 1, the instruments appear to be fairly strong and uncorrelated with the error terms, whereas they are weaker in specification 2. But in both cases the second stage coefficients on foreign official flows are similar in magnitude to the one reported in column 3 of table 1. In the third specification, we use foreign official inflows from Japan and instrument them with Japanese foreign exchange interventions.13 The Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic of 98 indicates that the instrument is strong, and the coefficient on Japanese official inflows is similar to those found in specifications 1 and 2. In specifications 4 and 5 we examine the effects of official purchases from China and the Mid-East oil exporters, but the instruments are clearly weak in both cases, making these estimates unreliable.14

Referring back to figure 2, the widening gap between the blue and red lines between 2004 and 2007 indicate that foreign official investors began diversifying their portfolio of U.S. securities by acquiring increasing amounts of agency securities. To the extent that Treasury and agency securities are close substitutes (at least during our sample period) and foreigners purchased large quantities of both, we consider a broader measure comprising both types of foreign inflows. Using this broader measure of foreign official inflows (scaled by GDP), we run several instrumental variable regressions and present the results in table 3. The instruments appear to be weak as none of the specifications pass the Stock and Yogo (2005) weak instruments test using a 10 percent size. The estimated coefficients from these regressions imply that a $100 billion foreign official inflow into Treasuries and agencies would lower the 5-year term premium by 43 to 70 basis points.

Summarizing the results from the term-premium regressions using instrumental variables, when the instruments are strong, valid, and the residuals pass the usual tests, the point estimates of the effect of a $100 billion foreign official inflow into U.S. Treasury notes and bonds on the 5-year term-premium range from -46 basis points to -50 basis points. Furthermore, conditional on having valid and strong instruments, the Hausman and Wu endogeneity tests strongly reject the null hypothesis that foreign official inflows are exogenous, justifying the need to use two-stage least squares.

3.2  Cointegrated VAR Approach

We now apply Johansen's cointegration method to both recognize the endogeneity of the term premium and foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities and to characterize the long-run and short-run dynamics between changes in the term premium and foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities. The system of equations is as follows:

$\displaystyle \Delta \mathbf{X}_{t}=\underset{short-run}{\underbrace{ \sum_{k=1}^{n}\underset{3\times 3}{\Gamma _{k}}\cdot \Delta \mathbf{X}_{t-k}+ \underset{3\times 5}{\Psi }\cdot \left( \begin{array}{c} 1 \\ y_{t} \\ vol.us_{t} \\ vol.ger_{t} \\ vix_{t} \end{array} \right) }+}\underset{long-run}{\underbrace{\underset{3\times 3}{\Pi }\cdot \mathbf{X}_{t-1}}}+\underset{3\times 1}{\mathbf{v}_{t}},$     where (4)

$\displaystyle \mathbf{v}_{t}\sim IN(0,\underset{3\times 3}{\Omega }),$     and  $\displaystyle \Delta \mathbf{X}_{t}\equiv \left( \begin{array}{c} \Delta TP_{t} \\ \Delta FOI_t \\ \Delta FPVT_t \end{array} \right).$    

In equation 4, $ n$ is the number of lags, $ \Psi $ and $ \Gamma _{k}$ are matrices of parameters characterizing short-run responses, and $ \Pi $ is a matrix of parameters of long-run responses. Foreign official ($ FOI_t$) and foreign private ($ FPVT_t$) are scaled by the amount of marketable Treasury notes and bonds outstanding (excluding holdings of the Federal Reserve system).

Central to the Johansen method is the estimation of the number of long-run relations, which is given by the rank of $ \Pi $. To this end, one needs to specify $ n$ and we consider several values$ :$ 1, 2 4, 6, 8, 10, and 12. For each value of $ n$, we apply FIML to equation (4), and test whether the distribution of $ \mathbf{v}_{t}$ is consistent with the maintained hypotheses. If there is support for these hypotheses, we then test the rank of $ \Pi $ using the Trace and Max tests, both with and without correction for degrees of freedom.

Table 4 shows the results along with statistical criteria (AIC, SC, and HQ) for choosing $ n$. For $ n<2$, the residuals appear to be either autocorrelated, heteroscedastic, or not normally distributed. The SC and HQ criteria would select the models with 1 and 2 lags, respectively, which do not have well-behaved residuals. The AIC criteria favors the model with 4 lags, whose residuals are more like white noise. For $ n>2,$ the rank of $ \Pi $ is at most one regardless of the test used, suggesting that the there is only one long-run relation. Given this result, $ \Pi $ can be expressed as $ \Pi =\mathbf{\alpha }\cdot \mathbf{\beta },$ where $ \mathbf{\alpha }^{\prime }$= \begin{displaymath}\left( \begin{array}{ccc} \alpha _{1} & \alpha _{2} & \alpha _{3} \end{array}\right) \end{displaymath} and \begin{displaymath}\mathbf{\beta =}\left( \begin{array}{ccc} \beta _{1} & \beta _{2} & \beta _{3} \end{array}\right) ;\end{displaymath} the $ \alpha ^{\prime }s$ represent the speed of adjustment to departures from the long-run relation and the $ \beta ^{\prime }s$ represent the importance of each factor in determining the long-run. We identify the long-run relation by normalizing $ \beta _{1}=1$.

The long-run coefficients under this normalization are presented in table 5. The parameter estimates are fairly insensitive to the lag choice. The $ \beta$ coefficients on foreign official holdings in the term-premium equation range from 0.046 to 0.062, and they are all statistically significant. The coefficients on foreign private holdings are similar in magnitude, but only statistically significant for the specifications with 8 or more lags. The long run relation is given by

$\displaystyle \widehat{TP}_{t}^{60}=-0.046\cdot FOI_t-0.061\cdot FPVT_t.$ (5)

These estimates imply that a one percent increase in either foreign official or foreign private holdings of U.S. Treasuries (as a share of Treasuries outstanding) lowers the term premium by 5 to 6 basis points (or between 17 and 20 basis points per $100 billion inflow). They also suggest that a decline in foreign officials holdings that is offset by an increase in foreign private holdings would leave the term premium roughly unchanged. All told, when we allow foreign private investors to react endogenously to the yield changes induced by an exogenous shock to foreign official holdings, the effects of foreign official flows on the term premium are dampened.

Note that all three variables are endogenous but $ \widehat{FPVT}_t$ does not respond directly to deviations in the long relation because the estimate of $ \alpha _{3}$ is not different from zero. The long-run relation suggests that an increase in foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities lowers the term premium, regardless of whether the increase is undertaken by foreign official holders or by foreign private investors.


4  Foreign Holdings and Realized Excess Returns

So far the analysis has focussed on the effects of foreign official inflows on the term premium, which is an ex-ante and model dependent measure of the risk premium. In this section, we examine the effects of foreign inflows on (ex-post) realized excess returns, which is not model dependent. We estimate 2SLS regressions using the same instrumental variables as in the term-premium regressions. All flow variables are expressed as sums during the 1-year holding period ending at time $ t$. So in contrast to the short-run estimates derived earlier from regressions using monthly flow data, the effect we are estimating here is a medium term elasticity. Our a-priori hypothesis is that foreign official inflows during the holding period would increase excess returns by raising the price (or lowering the yield) of the 6-year bond when it is sold as a 5-year bond at the end of the holding period.

The first column of table 6 shows the OLS estimates for the variables measured in levels. The coefficients on foreign official and foreign private flows are positive but not statistically significant. In the column 2, we perform 2-stage least squares using Japanese foreign exchange interventions to instrument for foreign official flows. The second stage coefficient on foreign official inflows is 0.582, and it is significant at the 5 percent level. The coefficient on foreign private inflows is similar in magnitude, and also statistically significant. In order to convert the coefficient estimate of 0.595 into an equivalent effect on the 5-year yield, we let $ D_{t+1}^n=0.595$ in equation 2, and solve for the price of the 5-year bond at the end of the holding period ( $ P_{t+1}^{n-1}$) while holding the price of the 6-year bond at the beginning of the holding period ($ P_{t}^{n}$) and the one-year rate constant. Doing so, we obtain that a 1 percentage point increase in foreign official flows into U.S. Treasuries notes and bonds over a one-year period (as a share of outstanding notes and bonds) lowers the yield on the 5-year bond at the end of that year by 12 basis points. Thus, if foreign official inflows into Treasury notes and bonds had been $100 billion higher than they were in the one-year period ending in June 2007, the 5-year Treasury yield would have been 42 basis points lower. The p-value associated with the Cumby-Huizinga test statistic suggests that the residuals are autocorrelated, which is why we report Newey-West HAC standard errors. To address the autocorrelation problem explicitly, we try estimating the short-run effect by re-estimating the regression using first differences of the variables (columns 4 and 5). The coefficient on foreign official inflows is still positive and of similar magnitude to the one in column 3, but is no longer statistically significant. This suggests that the short-run and medium-run elasticities may be similar to each other.

As a robustness check, we estimate the excess returns regression using different combinations of instruments. The results are shown in table 7. The instruments pass the weak instruments test in specifications 1 and 2 only. The coefficients on foreign official inflows in these specifications imply that a $100 billion increase in foreign official inflows into Treasury notes and bonds during the one-year period ending in June 2007 would have lowered the 5-year Treasury yield by 39 to 62 basis points.


5  Comparison with Other Studies

Table 8 compares the effects implied by our estimates to those obtained in other studies. The metric used is basis points per $100 billion in purchases. The top portion of the table compares estimates of the short-run effects, derived from regressions using weekly or monthly data on foreign official flows, or from event studies of interventions by the Japanese ministry of Finance, and the Fed's purchases of Treasuries through the Large-Scale Asset Purchase (LSAP) program. Our short-run elasticity estimates of roughly -50 basis points are roughly in line with those of the other studies. In some cases, the similarity in the estimates may be pure coincidence. For example, McCauley and Jiang (2004) regress 5-year and 10-year Treasury yields on weekly changes in foreign official holdings held in custody at the New York Fed. They acknowledge that their results are "not very robust" to changes in methodology because "widening the regression window to 52 weeks results in less reliable estimates."More importantly, McCauley and Jiang (2004) find a stronger relationship between the previous week's change in yields and the current week's change in custody holdings, suggesting that the direction of causation may well go from yields to flows. In contrast, Bernanke, Reinhart, and Sack (2004) and D' Amico, Kim, and Wei (2010) implicitly control for the joint endogeneity of yields and flows because they estimate the effects of interventions on yields during a narrow time window surrounding the interventions.

The estimates of the medium-term effects of foreign official flows on yields are derived from regressions using rolling sums of 12-month flows. In the previous section, using excess returns regressions we estimate that $100 billion in foreign official inflows during a 12-month period lower the 5-year yield by about 40 to 60 basis points. These estimates are similar to our short run elasticities. Warnock and Warnock (2009) find a similarly large effect, whereas Rudebusch, Swanson, and Wu (2006) find no significant effect. However, as documented by Beltran, Kretchmer, Marquez, and Thomas (2010), the results in these studies are not robust to minor changes in specification.

The long-run elasticities shown in the bottom portion of table 8 are derived from regressions using holdings by foreign official investors, or cumulated purchases by the Fed through the LSAPs. Our estimates from the cointegration analysis are a bit higher than those of Bertaut, DeMarco, Kamin, and Tryon (2011) which regress nominal Treasury yields on the level of foreign holdings. A possible explanation for this difference is that Bertaut, DeMarco, Kamin, and Tryon (2011) treat the level of foreign official holdings as exogenous, whereas we allow it to respond to yields and other factors.

Our long-run estimates are also higher than those of the studies examining the efficacy of the LSAPs (Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011), D' Amico and King (2011), and Hamilton and Wu (2011)).15 There are several reasons for why the Fed LSAP purchases could, at least in theory, have a smaller impact on interest rates than foreign official purchases. First, the Fed's LSAP program was designed as a temporary stimulus program, and announced as such. In contrast, because foreign exchange reserves have steadily grown over the last couple of decades, purchases of U.S. Treasuries by foreign official investors are more likely to be perceived as permanent. Also, surveys of inflation forecasts show an increase in the dispersion of the forecast means around the time the LSAPs came into effect (figure 11), suggesting an increase in inflation uncertainty. If the LSAPs increased the amount of uncertainty surrounding the level of future inflation, the inflation risk premium would have risen, exerting upward pressure on long-term interest rates.16 In contrast, foreign official purchases of Treasuries are not likely to influence the inflation risk premium. Finally, there are some difficulties with gauging the effects of the the LSAPs using event studies that try to measure the reaction of yields within specific LSAP announcement windows (e.g. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011). If investors had already formed expectations of purchases prior to the announcement window, the response of yields may have occurred prior to the announcement window, and thus would not be captured in the announcement effect. Conversely, a portion of the LSAP effect may only be priced when the purchases actually occur (after the announcement window), as evidenced by the "flow effect" analysis of D' Amico and King (2011). In sum, these conceptual and methodological issues could explain why our estimates are higher than those of the LSAP event studies.


6  Conclusions

Previous studies that have tried to estimate the effect of foreign official inflows on U.S. long-term interest rates have failed to take into account the endogeneity of these inflows. We find strong evidence that foreign official inflows into the United States respond to such things as implied volatility of U.S. and German sovereign bonds, liquidity premium between on-the-run and off-the-run Treasury notes, the U.S. federal government's structural budget balance, and the implied volatility of the S&P500 stock market index, which serves as a proxy for investor risk aversion. When we treat foreign official inflows as an endogenous regressor, the estimated effect of these inflows on yields becomes stronger (more negative). One reason for this is that periods of high investor risk aversion are usually associated with strong private inflows into U.S. Treasuries, lower Treasury yields, and a stronger dollar. In turn, a stronger dollar alleviates the pressure on emerging economies to intervene to prevent their currencies from appreciating, reducing foreign official inflows. In sum, sharp increases in investor risk aversion usually result in slower official inflows together with falling yields. Therefore, a model that treats foreign official inflows as exogenous will associate lower yields with slower official inflows in periods of high investor risk aversion, dampening the estimated overall effect of official inflows on yields.

We find that a $100 billion increase in foreign official inflows into U.S. Treasury notes and bonds lowers the 5-year yield by roughly 40 to 60 basis points in the short run. However, our VAR analysis shows that in the long-run, when we allow foreign private investors to react to the effects induced by a shock to foreign official holdings, the estimated effect is roughly -20 basis points per $100 billion. Putting these results into context, between 1995 and 2010 China acquired roughly $1.1 trillion in U.S. Treasury notes and bonds. A literal interpretation of our long-run estimates suggests that if China had not accumulated any foreign exchange reserves during this period, and therefore not acquired these $1.1 trillion in Treasuries, all else equal, the 5-year Treasury yield would have been roughly 2 percentage points higher by 2010. This effect is large enough to have implications for the effectiveness of monetary policy.

Our estimates can be used to gauge the overall effect of the global savings glut on U.S. yields through high foreign savings that are invested in U.S. Treasury securities by the official sector. In other words, if countries stop accumulating reserves and as a result no longer invest in Treasuries, our estimates could be used to gauge the effect on Treasury yields. But our results should not be used to gauge the effect on Treasury yields if a large holder of U.S. Treasuries (such as China) were to shift its reserves away from U.S. Treasuries into say, German Bunds. Such re-allocation of reserves would likely put downward pressure on Bunds yields which, through private sector rebalancing, would in time put downward pressure on Treasury yields as well. Estimating this diversification effect would likely involve estimating a global portfolio balance model using time-series data on the composition of foreign exchange reserves and global cross-border flows, which are not publicly available. Given that there is ample evidence to suggest that reserves diversification is already taking place (see figure 12, for example), this is an important question for future research.17


References

Beltran, D., M. Kretchmer, J. Marquez, and C. Thomas (2010): "U.S. Treasury Yields and Foreign Holdings of U.S. Securities: An Interim Report," Working paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, http://www.gwu.edu/ forcpgm/JaimeMarquez-final-OxConference5.pdf.

Bernanke, B. S. (2005): "The Global Savings Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit," Homer Jones Lecture, April 14, http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/20050414/default.htm.

Bernanke, B. S., V. R. Reinhart, and B. P. Sack (2004): "Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical Assessment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 35(2004-2), 1-100.

Bertaut, C., L. P. DeMarco, S. Kamin, and R. Tryon (2011): "ABS inflows to the United States and the global financial crisis," International Finance Discussion Papers 1028, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Bertaut, C. C., W. L. Griever, and R. W. Tryon (2006): "Understanding U.S. cross-border securities data," Federal Reserve Bulletin, (May), A59-A75.

Bertaut, C. C., and R. W. Tryon (2007): "Monthly estimates of U.S. cross-border securities positions," International Finance Discussion Papers 910, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Borio, C., G. Galati, and A. Heath (2008): "FX reserve management: trends and challenges," BIS Papers 40, Bank for International Settlements. Cochrane, J. H., and M. Piazzesi (2005): "Bond Risk Premia," American Economic Review, 95(1), 138-160.

Dai, Q., and K. J. Singleton (2002): "Expectations Puzzles, Time-Varying Risk Premia, and Affine Models of the Term Structure," Journal Financial Economics, 63(3), 415-441.

D'Amico, S., D. H. Kim, and M. Wei (2010): "Tips from TIPS: the informational content of Treasury Inflation-Protected Security prices," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2010-19, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

D'Amico, S., and T. B. King (2011): "Flow and stock effects of large-scale Treasury purchases," Working paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Department of the Treasury (2011): "Report on Foreign Portfolio Holdings of U.S. Securities as of June 30, 2010," http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/tic/Documents/shla2010r.pdf.

Gagnon, J., M. Raskin, J. Remache, and B. Sack (2011): "Large-scale asset purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did they work?," Economic Policy Review, (441), 41-59.

Granger, C. W. J., and P. Newbold (1974): "Spurious regressions in econometrics," Journal of Econo- metrics, 2(2), 111-120.

Greenspan, A. (2005): "Testimony before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs," U.S. Senate, February 16, http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/hh/2005/february/testimony.htm.

Gurkaynak, R. S., B. Sack, and J. H. Wright (2007): "The U.S. Treasury yield curve: 1961 to the present," Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(8), 2291-2304.

Hamilton, J. D., and J. C. Wu (2011): "The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment," NBER Working Papers 16956, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Kilian, L. (2009): "Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: Disentangling Demand and Supply Shocks in the Crude Oil Market," American Economic Review, 99(3), 1053-69.

Kim, D. H., and J. H. Wright (2005): "An arbitrage-free three-factor term structure model and the recent behavior of long-term yields and distant-horizon forward rates," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2005-33, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

McCauley, R., and G. Jiang (2004): "Treasury Yields and foreign offcial holdings of U.S. bonds," BIS quarterly review (march), Bank for International Settlements.

Papaioannou, E., R. Portes, and G. Siourounis (2006): "Optimal currency shares in international reserves: The impact of the euro and the prospects for the dollar," Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 20(4), 508-547.

Pringle, R., and N. Carver (2002): How Countries Manage Reserve Assetschap. 1. London: Central Banking Publications.

Rudebusch, G. D., E. T. Swanson, and T. Wu (2006): "The Bond Yield "Conundrum" from a Macro- Finance Perspective," Monetary and Economic Studies, 24(S1), 83-109.

Sierra, J. (2010): "International Capital Flows and Bond Risk Premia," Working Papers 10-14, Bank of Canada.

Stock, J. H., and M. Yogo (2005): "Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression," in Identifi- cation and Inference for Econometric Models, ed. by D. W. K. Andrews, and J. H. Stock. Cambridge University Press.

Svensson, L. E. (1994): "Estimating and Interpreting Forward Interest Rates: Sweden 1992 - 1994," Working Paper 4871, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Warnock, F. E., and V. C. Warnock (2009): "International Capital Flows and U.S. Interest Rates," Journal of International Money and Finance, 28(6), 903-919.

Williams, J. C. (2011): "Unconventional monetary policy: Lessons from the past three years," FRBSF Economic Letter, (31).

Wu, T. (2005): "The long-term interest rate conundrum: Not unraveled yet?," FRBSF Economic Letter, (29).


Figure 1: Federal funds rate and Treasury yields.

Figure 1: The figure depicts the evolution of three interest rates: the federal funds rate, the five-year U.S. Treasury yield, and the ten-year U.S. Treasury yield.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  The vertical axis has the value of the three interest rates and it ranges from zero percent to 10 percent.  All three interest rates are close to each other at five percent until 2001.  Afterwards, the federal funds rate declines to about one percent and stays at that value until mid-2004 when it rises again gradually reaching five percent by mid-2007.

Figure 2: Foreign official inflows into Treasury and agency securities, expressed as a 6-month moving average.

Figure 2: The figure depicts the evolution of three measures of foreign official inflows expressed as six-month moving averages: total, into U.S. Treasuries, and into U.S. Treasuries and Agencies.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  The vertical axis shows the dollar value of these three inflows and it ranges from minus 20 billion of US dollars to 80 billion of US dollars.  From mid-1994 to mid-2001, the three measures of official inflows move close to each other and fluctuate around zero.  Afterwards, all measures become positive with total inflows reaching 40 billion by 2007.

Figure 3: Global foreign exchange reserves. Source: IMF.

Figure 3: The figure depicts the evolution of global foreign exchange reserves.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2011.  The vertical axis has the dollar value of these reserves, which increase gradually from 2 trillion US dollars in 1994 to 10 trillion US dollars in 2011.

Figure 4: Supply and demand for U.S. Treasury securities.

Figure 4: The figure depicts the evolution of outstanding U.S. Treasuries disaggregated into the various  holders: Federal Reserve, domestic excluding Federal Reserve, foreign private, and foreign official; these holdings are expressed in trillions of U.S. dollars.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2011.  The vertical axis shows the dollar value of these holdings and it ranges from zero to ten trillion of US dollars.  From 1994 to 2002, holdings are roughly constant with foreign private holdings having the smallest value.  From 2002 to 2007, all measures increase gradually.  From 2008 to 2011, all measures increase sharply with foreign official holdings having the largest value.

Figure 5: Geography of foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities.

Figure 5: The figure depicts the evolution of foreign holdings of U.S. Treasuries disaggregated by region: Europe, Japan, Oil Exporters, Other Emerging Market Economies, China, and Rest of the World; these holdings are expressed in trillions of U.S. dollars.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2011.  The vertical axis shows the dollar value of these holdings and it ranges from zero to about five trillion of US dollars.  From 1994 to 2002, holdings are roughly constant with oil exporters’ holdings having the smallest value.  From 2002 to 2007, all measures increase gradually.  From 2008 to 2011, all three measures increase sharply with foreign official holdings by China having the largest value.

Figure 6: Excess returns realized at time t + 1.

Figure 6: The figure represents the time line involved in the computation of the 1-year excess return.  The time line begins at time t with the borrowing of funds for 1 year to purchase a 6-year Treasury bond.  The time line ends at time t+1 with the sale of the 6-year bond as a 5-year bond and the payment of the loan obtained at time t.

Figure 7: 5-year term premium and future realized excess returns.

Figure 7: The figure depicts the evolution of the Treasury’s 5-year term premium and of the 6-year excess return realized 1-year ahead.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  There are two vertical axes – one for the 5-year term premium, ranging from minus four percent to 6 percent, and another for the excess return, ranging from minus ten percent to 15 percent.  The 5-year return declines gradually from two percent in 1994 to about zero by 2007.  The 1-year excess return fluctuates around zero.

Figure 8: Foreign official and foreign private holdings of U.S. Treasury securities as a share of Treasury securities outstanding.

Figure 8: The figure depicts the evolution of foreign official and foreign private holdings of U.S. Treasuries as shares of total Treasury securities outstanding.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  The vertical axis ranges from zero to 60 percent.  The share of foreign private rises gradually from 9 percent in 1994 to about 17 percent by mid-1998, staying at that level through 2007.  The share of foreign official rises gradually from 15 percent in 1994 to about 46 percent by 2007.

Figure 9: Foreign holdings of long-term (notes and bonds) and short-term (bills) as a share of these respective securities outstanding.

Figure 9: The figure depicts the evolution of foreign holdings of long-term Treasury securities, as a share of outstanding long-term Treasury securities, and foreign holdings of T-bills as a share of T-bills outstanding.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  The vertical axis ranges from 20 to 80 percent.  The share of foreign holdings of T-bills rises gradually from 30 percent in 1994 to about 40 percent by 1996, staying roughly at that level through 2007.  The share of foreign holdings of long-term Treasuries rises gradually from 30 percent in 1994 to about 75 percent by 2007.

Figure 10: Foreign official and foreign private holdings of Treasury notes and bonds as a share of Treasury notes and bonds outstanding.

Figure 10: The figure depicts the evolution of foreign official and foreign private holdings of U.S. longer Treasuries as shares of long-term Treasury securities outstanding.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in months, from 1994 to 2007.  The vertical axis ranges from zero to 60 percent.  The share of foreign private rises gradually from 10 percent in 1994 to about 20 percent by mid-1998, staying at that level through 2007.  The share of foreign official rises gradually from 11 percent in 1994 to about 50 percent by 2007.

Figure 11: Inflation uncertainty as measured by the dispersion of forecasts for year-ahead CPI inflation. Source: Survey of Professional Forecasters.

Figure 11: The figure depicts the evolution of inter-quartile range of the one-year ahead CPI inflation forecast and the 4-quarter moving average of CPI inflation.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in quarters, from 2000 to 2011.  The vertical axis ranges from 0.3 percent to 1.5 percent.  From 2000 to 2008, both measures fluctuate between 0.4 percent and 0.8 percent.  From 2009 to 2011, both measures fluctuate between 0.6 percent and 1.4 percent.

Figure 12: Left panel: Dollar-denominated share of foreign exchange reserves. Estimates based on COFER data adjusted for unallocated reserves and with non-dollar reserves valued at 2011- Q1 exchange rates. Right panel: Estimated U.S. share of Chinese new foreign exchange reserve accumulations. Authors' estimates based on CEIC, Peoples Bank of China, COFER, IFS, and Treasury International Capital Data.

Figure 12: The figure has two panels.  The panel on the left depicts the evolution of the share of foreign exchange reserves held in dollars by region: advanced economies, emerging market economies, and all countries.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in quarters, from 2003 to 2011; the vertical axis ranges from 55 percent to 70 percent.  The share for advanced economies fluctuates around 65 percent between 2003 and 2008.  Since then, this share has declined to 64 percent.  The share for emerging market economies fluctuates rises gradually from 60 percent in 2003 to 65 percent in 2008.  Since then, this share has declined to 57 percent.  The panel on the right depicts the evolution of China’s share of foreign exchange reserve accumulation held in dollars.  The horizontal axis represents the time dimension, in quarters, from 2003 to 2011; the vertical axis ranges from 20 percent to 100 percent.  The share shows large fluctuations between 62 percent in 2003 and 38 percent in 2011.

Table 1: Term premium regressions

 (1) OLS: ΔTPt(2) IV: 1st Stage: ΔFOIt / DEBTt-1(3) IV: 2nd Stage: ΔTPt(4) IV: 1st Stage: ΔFOIt / GDPt-1(5) IV: 2nd Stage: ΔTPt
Flow Variables: ΔFOIt / DEBTt-10.052*
(0.030)
 -0.135**
(0.061)
  
Flow Variables: ΔFPVTt / DEBTt-10.046**
(0.021)
-0.026
(0.052)
0.041
(0.027)
  
Flow Variables: ΔFOIt / GDP t-1    -0.696**
(0.343)
Flow Variables: ΔFPVTt / GDP t-1   0.017
(0.053)
0.182*
(0.1110)
Control Variables: ΔIPtyoy0.025*
(0.013)
0.005
(0.033)
0.027*
(0.014)
0.000
(0.008)
0.026*
(0.015)
Control Variables: ΔIPt-1yoy-0.033**
(0.013)
0.010
(0.033)
-0.033**
(0.015)
0.004
(0.008)
-0.031**
(0.015)
Control Variables: ΔVIXt-0.007**
(0.003)
-0.017**
(0.007)
-0.010***
(0.003)
-0.004**
(0.002)
-0.011***
(0.003)
Control Variables: ΔVIXt-1-0.001
(0.003)
-0.017**
(0.007)
-0.005
(0.003)
-0.004***
(0.002)
-0.005
(0.003)
Control Variables: ΔUS_VOLt-10.019
(0.020)
0.018
(0.052)
0.018
(0.022)
0.006
(0.012)
0.021
(0.022)
Control Variables: ΔDE_VOLt(0.011)
(0.026)
-0.056
(0.068)
0.006
(0.028)
-0.015
(0.016)
0.003
(0.030)
Control Variables: ΔSTR_BUDGET_BALANCEt0.089**
(0.040)
-0.235**
(0.101)
0.023
(0.042)
-0.042*
(0.023)
0.020
0.043
Control Variables: ΔLP5t-1-0.005
(0.004)
0.002
(0.010)
-0.004
(0.004)
0.000
(0.002)
-0.005
(0.004)
Control Variables: OIL_DEMAND_SHOCKt0.010
(0.010)
-0.026
(0.026)
0.005
(0.011)
-0.006
(0.006)
0.004
(0.012)
Control Variables: ΔCP1-5t-10.035*
(0.020)
-0.058
(0.051)
0.025
(0.024)
-0.014
(0.012)
0.022
(0.025)
Control Variables: ΔCP6-9t-10.018***
(0.006)
-0.010
(0.015)
0.016**
(0.006)
-0.002
(0.004)
0.016**
(0.007)
Instruments: JPYFXINTt 0.016**
(0.003)
 0.003**
(0.001)
 
Instruments: OIL_SUPPLY_SHOCKt 0.070
(0.045)
 0.016
(0.011)
 
Observation160160160160160
R-squared0.2660.4470.0700.3420.013
Durbin-Watson 1.8021.488 1.441 
Cragg-Donald Wald F-Stat   15.72 9.894
Stock-Yogo critical value, 10%   19.93 19.93
Pagan-Hall Test (P-Value)   0.671 0.789
Cumby-Huizinga Test (P-Value)   0.0159 0.0158
Endogeneity Test (P-Value)   0.0192 0.0339
Hansen J Test (P-Value)   0.3498 0.3147

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. $ ^{***} p<0.01$, $ ^{**} p<0.05$, $ ^{*} p<0.1$. All specifications include a constant and a linear trend.

Table 2: Alternative instrumental variable specifications for term premium regressions

 (1) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(2) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(3) IV: JAPAN(4) IV: CHINA(5) IV: MID-EAST OIL EXPORTERS
First stage: Instruments: JPYFXINTt0.019***
(0.003)
0.019***
(0.003)
0.017***
(0.002)
  
First stage: Instruments: ΔBOP_CNt0.006
(0.006)
0.007
(0.006)
 0.006**
(0.002)
 
First stage: Instruments: OIL_SUPPLY_SHOCKt 0.061
(0.051)
  0.019**
(0.008)
Second Stage: Official Flows: ΔFOIt / DEBTt-1-0.140**
(0.057)
-0.145**
(0.058)
   
Second Stage: Official Flows: ΔFOI_JAPANt / DEBTt-1  -0.147
(0.059)
  
Second Stage: Official Flows: ΔFOI_CHINAt / DEBTt-1   0.207
(0.423)
 
Second Stage: Official Flows: ΔFOI_MIDEASTt / DEBTt-1    -0.000
(0.862)
Observation126126160126160
R-squared - 2nd Stage 0.1060.0950.2100.3050.254
Cragg-Donald Wald F-Stat 18.2512.7197.596.0536.119
Stock-Yogo critical value, 10% 19.9322.3016.3816.3816.38
Endogenous Variables 11111
Exogenous Instruments 23111
Pagan-Hall Test (P-Value) 0.8620.8900.4290.5390.545
Cumby-Huizinga Test (P-Value) 0.1380.1270.01690.3870.192
Endogeneity Test (P-Value) 0.009320.008820.02290.9250.408
Hansen J Test (P-Value) 0.90740.9013n.an.an.a

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. $ ^{***} p<0.01$, $ ^{**} p<0.05$, $ ^{*} p<0.1$. All specifications include the same set of explanatory variables listed in Table 1.

Table 3 Term-premium regressions using foreign official inflows into both Treasuries and agencies

 (1) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(2) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(3) IV: ALL COUNTRIES
First stage: Instruments: JPYFXINTt0.002***
(0.001)
0.003***
(0.001)
0.003***
(0.001)
First stage: Instruments: ΔBOP_CNt 0.004**
(0.002)
0.004**
(0.002)
First stage: Instruments: OIL_SUPPLY_SHOCKt  0.008
(0.012)
Second Stage: Official Flows: ΔFOI_TAt / GDP t-1-0.983**
(0.489)
-0.606
(0.382)
-0.637*
(0.385)
Observation160126126
R-squared - 2nd Stage n.a0.1160.100
Cragg-Donald Wald F-Stat 7.82910.296.950
Stock-Yogo critical value, 10% 16.3819.9322.3
Endogenous Variables 111
Exogenous Instruments 123
Pagan-Hall Test (P-Value) 0.8500.8470.878
Cumby-Huizinga Test (P-Value) 0.01010.2010.185
Endogeneity Test (P-Value) 0.04330.06610.0577
Hansen J Test (P-Value) n.a0.34860.5437

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. $ ^{***} p<0.01$, $ ^{**} p<0.05$, $ ^{*} p<0.1$. All specifications include the same set of explanatory variables listed in Table 1.

Table 4a: Cointegration Test

 12 lags10 lags8 lags6 lags4 lags2 lags1 lag
Parameters1231058769513324
Log-likelihood2.7-15-30-41-52-73-88
SC4.073.673.242.742.251.971.88
HQ2.612.432.221.941.661.601.60
AIC1.601.581.521.401.261.341.42
Residual test: Serial Indep. 0.580.390.740.610.910.100.00
Residual test: Normality0.550.320.700.490.440.040.09
Residual test: Hetero0.260.200.500.720.360.160.01

Table 4b: Cointegration Test

 12 lags: Rank 012 lags: Rank 110 lags: Rank 010 lags: Rank 18 lags: Rank 08 lags: Rank 16 lags: Rank 06 lags: Rank 14 lags: Rank 04 lags: Rank 12 lags: Rank 02 lags: Rank 11 lag: Rank 01 lag: Rank 1
Trace test 55.69.1946.07.335.63.730.43.5436.06.6434.17.6724.26.82
(p-value)00.3500.550.010.920.040.930.010.630.010.510.20.60
Max test 46.48.9538.76.8231.93.6126.93.5329.46.1726.46.9117.35.82
(p-value) 00.3000.520.0010.890.010.900.000.600.010.510.160.64
Trace test 42.36.9936.95.8630.13.1326.93.1333.36.1332.87.3823.76.7
(p-value)0.000.590.010.710.050.950.110.950.020.680.020.540.220.62
Trace test 35.36.831.15.4727.03.0523.83.1227.15.725.46.6517.05.71
(p-value)00.520.000.680.010.930.020.930.010.660.010.540.180.66

Table 5: VAR Long-Run Coefficients

 12 lags10 lags8 lags6 lags4 lags2 lags
Cointegrating vector, $ \beta$: Term premium (normalized)111111
Cointegrating vector, $ \beta$: Foreign official0.0460.0550.0610.0620.0560.055
Cointegrating vector, $ \beta$: Foreign private0.0610.0680.0590.050.0240.037
T-stat - cointegration coef.: Foreign official5.7825.9395.3484.6333.8033.403
T-stat - cointegration coef.: Foreign private2.8832.7582.0161.5210.6760.952
Loading Factors, $ \alpha$: Term premium-0.481-0.341-0.23-0.21-0.201-0.186
Loading Factors, $ \alpha$: Foreign official-0.54-0.567-0.481-0.295-0.197-0.153
Loading Factors, $ \alpha$: Foreign private0.0960.2140.3380.230.14-0.017
T-stat. - loading factors: Term premium-5.831-5.091-4.164-4.559-5.145-5.129
T-stat. - loading factors: Foreign official-2.378-3.044-3.184-2.288-1.795-1.442
T-stat. - loading factors: Foreign private0.2740.7761.5141.2190.849-0.113

Table 6: Excess returns regressions

 (1) OLS: XR_6t(2) IV: 1st Stage: S12FOIt / DEBTt-12(3) IV: 2nd Stage: XR_6t(4) IV: 1st Stage: Δ(S12FOIt / DEBTt-12)(5) IV: 2nd Stage: ΔXR_6t
Flow Variables: Σ12FOIt / DEBTt-120.172
(0.119)
 0.595***
(0.184)
 0.424
(0.545)
Flow Variables: S12FPVTt / DEBTt-120.656***
(0.144)
0.056
(0.067)
0.616***
(0.137)
-0.036
(0.053)
-0.723***
(0.251)
Control Variables: IPtyoy-0.942***
(0.330)
0.198
(0.154)
-0.988***
(0.317)
-0.031
(0.074)
-0.282
(0.328)
Control Variables: IPt-1yoy0.293
(0.321)
-0.246
(0.150)
0.303
(0.310)
-0.093
(0.073)
0.106
(0.336)
Control Variables: VIXt0.156***
(0.057)
-0.047*
(0.027)
0.175***
(0.044)
-0.019*
(0.011)
0.139***
(0.049)
Control Variables: DE_VOLt-0.361
(0.491)
-0.704***
(0.251)
-0.155
(0.524)
-0.037
(0.097)
-0.730*
(0.427)
Control Variables: US_VOLt-10.026
(0.315)
-0.409***
(0.155)
-0.095
(0.300)
0.073
(0.069)
-0.514*
(0.312)
Control Variables: LP5t-10.001
(0.081)
-0.069*
(0.038)
0.040
(0.084)
-0.010
(0.015)
0.035
(0.070)
Control Variables: S12OIL_DEMAND_SHOCKt-0.267***
(0.112)
-0.063
(0.056)
-0.261***
(0.095)
-0.010
(0.037)
-0.061
(0.164)
Control Variables: CP1-5t-132.266***
(0.380)
-0.259
(0.176)
2.601***
(0.428)
0.059
(0.068)
-0.147
(0.294)
Control Variables: CP6-9t-13-0.423***
(0.143)
-0.052
(0.067)
0.395***
(0.144)
0.006
(0.023)
0.048
(0.111)
Control Variables: RISK APPETITE t0.494***
(0.124)
-0.050
(0.058)
-0.484***
(0.106)
-0.046
(0.048)
-0.501**
(0.198)
Control Variables: S12STR_BUDGET_BALt/GDPt-120.168
(0.310)
-0.730***
(0.145)
0.627**
(0.284)
-0.101
(0.182)
-0.549
0.892
Instruments: S12JPYFXINT 0.025***
(0.002)
 0.024***
(0.003)
 
Instruments: S12OIL_SUPPLY_SHOCKt 0.239***
(0.057)
 0.051
(0.040)
 
Observation158158158158158
R-squared0.7840.9150.7650.3650.104
Durbin-Watson 1.3260.421 1.486 
Cragg-Donald Wald F-Stat   92.79 32.77
Stock-Yogo critical value, 10%   19.93 19.93
Pagan-Hall Test (P-Value)   0.224 0.928
Cumby-Huizinga Test (P-Value)   6.84e-06 0.0970
Endogeneity Test (P-Value)   501e-06 0.00374
Hansen J Test (P-Value)   0.3563 0.3902

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. $ ^{***} p<0.01$, $ ^{**} p<0.05$, $ ^{*} p<0.1$. All specifications include a constant and a linear trend. \dagExplanatory variables in this specification are expressed as first differences.

Table 7: Alternative instrumental variable specifications for excess return regressions

 (1) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(2) IV: ALL COUNTRIES(3) IV: ALL COUNTRIES
First stage: Instruments:    
First stage: Instruments: S12JPYFXINTt0.026***
(0.002)
  
First stage: Instruments: S12OIL_SUPPLY_SHOCKt 0.357***
(0.079)
 
First stage: Instruments: S12BOP_CNt  -0.002
(0.010)
Second Stage: Official Flows: S12FOIt / DEBT t-120.547***
(0.195)
0.874**
(0.357)
-2.991
(11.170)
Observation158158115
R-squared - 2nd Stage 0.7700.7320.069
Cragg-Donald Wald F-Stat 150.320.250.0469
Stock-Yogo critical value, 10% 16.3816.3816.38
Endogenous Variables 111
Exogenous Instruments 111
Pagan-Hall Test (P-Value) 0.1570.6781
Cumby-Huizinga Test (P-Value) 7.43e-064.46e-050.830
Endogeneity Test (P-Value) 0.0002940.01530.549
Hansen J Test (P-Value) n.an.an.a

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. $ ^{***} p<0.01$, $ ^{**} p<0.05$, $ ^{*} p<0.1$. All specifications include a constant and a linear trend.

Table 8: Comparison of estimates of effects of purchases on Treasure yields

 Basic points per 100 $billion Invsetor type Data frequency
Short-run "flow" effect: 1. This study: Term-permium regs. -46 to -50 For Off. Monthly flows
Short-run "flow" effect: 2. D'Amico and King (2011) -67FedDaily purchases
Short-run "flow" effect: 3. Bernanke, Reinhart, and Sack (2004) -66Jpn. Official Daily interventions
Short-run "flow" effect: 4. McCauley and Jiang (2004) -70 to -100 For. Off. Weekly flows
Medium-run "flow" effect: 1. This study: Excess returns regs. -39 to -62 For. Off. 12-month flows
Medium-run "flow" effect: 2. Warnock and Warnock (2009) 68For. Off. 12-month flows
Medium-run "flow" effect: 3. Rudebusch, Swanson, and Wu (2006) no effect For. Off. 12-month flows
Long-run "stock" effect: 1. This Study: Cointegration -17 to -20 For. Off. Holdings (level)
Long-run "stock" effect: 2. Bertaut, Demarco, Kamin, and Tryon (2011) -11 to -15 For. Off. Holdings (level)
Long-run "stock" effect: 3. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011) -2 to -5 FedCumulated purchases
Long-run "stock" effect: 4. D'Amico and King (2011) -10FedCumulated purchases
Long-run "stock" effect: 5. Hamilton and Wu (2011) -4FedCumulated purchases

Note: The numbers reported here are taken directly from the studies and have not taken into account the growth in Treasuries outstanding since the end of the various different estimation samples. Such an adjustment would generally make the effect estimated by older studies smaller.



Footnotes

1.  One exception is Sierra (2010). Return to text

2.  An older survey by Pringle and Carver (2002) also suggests increased emphasis on returns or yield. Return to text

3.  We arrived at this conclusion by examining the augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic and autocorrelation function of the variables used in their regressions. Return to text

4.  Roughly half of the Treasury and agency securities held by foreign official investors mature in 5 years or less (Department of the Treasury (2011)). Return to text

5.  The D'Amico, Kim, and Wei (2010) model is estimated by applying the Kalman filter to the following data: zero coupon yields taken from the Svensson curve (Svensson (1994)) that is fitted to off-the-run Treasury coupon securities, 3-month and 6-month Treasury bill yields, CPI inflation, TIPS yields, the 6-month and 12-month ahead forecasts of the 3-month T-bill yield from Blue Chip Financial Forecasts, and the Blue Chip forecast of the 3-month T-bill yield over the next 5 to 10 years. Return to text

6.  It can be shown that for an n-year bond, $ TP_{t}^{n}=\frac{1}{n}\sum\limits_{i=1}^{n-1}E_{t}(D_{t+i}^{n-i+1})$Return to text

7.   The data come from the annual and monthly survey forms, and can be found on the Treasury Department's website at http://www.treasury.gov/ticwww.treasury.gov/tic. Return to text

8.   For example, an acquisition of a U.S. security by a foreign official institution from a private foreign entity on a foreign securities exchange will not be recorded in the TIC because it is not a U.S. cross-border transaction. Note, however, that the initial acquisition of the U.S. security by the foreign private investor should have been recorded in the TIC. Return to text

9.   We use confidential data on amounts held in custody accounts for individual countries at FRBNY to perform these adjustments. Return to text

10.   Rudebusch et al. use publicly available data on aggregate custody holdings at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York's (FRBNY) obtained from the H.4.1 statistical release. However, changes in these holdings account for just a fraction (about 60 percent) of overall foreign official flows. Return to text

11.  Sixty-four global assets are used in Credit Suisse's global risk appetite calculation. Return to text

12.  These interventions totalled $547 billion between April 1993 and March 2004, and were particularly strong in 2003 as the Ministry of Finance attempted to slow the yen's appreciation. Return to text

13.  The regressions in specifications 3-5, done as a robustness check, use confidential data on foreign official inflows from individual countries, which are not publicly available. Return to text

14.  The weak results for the China regression could be because, as shown in figure 5, total Chinese holdings of U.S. Treasuries began increasing rapidly only toward the end of our sample period, which ends in 2007. Return to text

15.  For a more comprehensive list of LSAP studies, see Williams (2011). Return to text

16. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011) use a survey-based measure of inflation forecast dispersion to try to control for this in their term-premium regressions. Return to text

17.   More recently, reserve holders have been diversifying their foreign exchange reserves away from dollar-denominated assets. Even after adjusting for exchange rate effects, the dollar share of foreign exchange reserves reported in the IMF COFER database has been gradually declining (left panel of figure 12). As shown in the right panel of figure 12, we estimate that since 2009 China appears to be diversifying its foreign exchange reserves by allocating a smaller share of newly acquired reserves into U.S. assets. Return to text


This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text

Home | Economic research and data | Publications and education resources
Accessibility | Contact us
Last update: May 14, 2013