The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Can Structural Reforms Help Europe?1

Gauti Eggertsson (Brown University), Andrea Ferrero (University of Oxford), and Andrea Raffo (Federal Reserve Board)

NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.


Abstract:

Structural reforms that increase competition in product and labor markets are often indicated as the main policy option available for peripheral Europe to regain competitiveness and boost output. We show that, in a crisis that pushes the nominal interest rate to its lower bound, these reforms do not support economic activity in the short run, and may well be contractionary. Absent the appropriate monetary stimulus, reforms fuel expectations of prolonged deflation, increase the real interest rate, and depress aggregate demand. Our findings carry important implications for the current debate on the timing and the design of structural reforms in Europe.

Keywords: Structural reforms, zero lower bound, monetary union

JEL classification: E52, E58, F33, F41


"...the biggest problem we have for growth in Europe is the problem of lack of competitiveness that has been accumulated in some of our Member States, and we need to make the reforms for that competitiveness.
...to get out of this situation requires...structural reforms, because there is an underlying problem of lack of competitiveness in some of our Member States."
José Manuel Durão Barroso
President of the European Commission
Closing Remarks following the State of the Union 2012
Strasbourg, September 12, 2012

1  Introduction

As the European Monetary Union (EMU) struggles to recover from the global financial crisis and the European debt crisis, conventional wisdom among academics and policymakers suggests that structural reforms that increase competition in product and labor markets are the main policy option to foster growth in the region.

This paper is bad news: In a standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model calibrated to match salient features of the EMU economy, we show that structural reforms do not improve output during a crisis. In fact, these reforms may entail near-term contractionary effects when monetary policy is constrained by the zero lower bound (ZLB). Even more disappointingly, if agents foresee that such reforms may be reversed (which may quite likely be the case, as several interest groups have strong incentives to oppose wide-ranging liberalizations), these policies can generate large short-term output losses, further deepening the ongoing recession.

Figure 1: Real GDP

Figure 1: Data for Figure 1 immediately follows.

Real GDP (= 100 in 2008Q3) in Germany (black), Greece (blue), Ireland (green), Italy (cyan), Portugal (magenta) and Spain (red).

Data for Figure 1

 GEGRIRIT PTSP
2008 - Q11.0080.9921.0201.0191.0071.008
2008 - Q21.0050.9971.0051.0131.0051.008
2008 - Q31.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.000
2008 - Q40.9800.9920.9630.9840.9890.989
2009 - Q10.9400.9810.9520.9490.9650.972
2009 - Q20.9420.9710.9370.9460.9680.962
2009 - Q30.9490.9650.9270.9500.9750.959
2009 - Q40.9590.9710.9170.9490.9750.958
2010 - Q10.9640.9530.9240.9570.9850.959
2010 - Q20.9830.9410.9200.9630.9910.961
2010 - Q30.9910.9260.9300.9670.9930.961
2010 - Q40.9990.9000.9180.9700.9900.963
2011 - Q11.0140.9010.9320.9710.9850.965
2011 - Q21.015 0.9440.9730.9840.964
2011 - Q31.020 0.9470.9720.9790.961
2011 - Q41.021 0.9500.9650.9620.957
2012 - Q11.027 0.9460.9540.9610.953
2012 - Q21.027 0.9500.9480.9520.948
2012 - Q31.029 0.9430.9440.9440.945
2012 - Q41.024 0.9410.9360.9260.937
2013 - Q11.024 0.9350.9300.9220.934
2013 - Q21.031 0.9390.9270.9320.933

The 2008-9 global financial crisis hit the EMU hard, resulting in large and widespread output contractions (Figure 1). While core EMU countries, such as Germany, have mostly recovered their output losses, the aftermath has been particularly difficult for peripheral countries (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain). These countries have remained in severe recessions ever since 2008, eventually triggering doubts about the sustainability of their public finances and putting in danger the entire Euro project. Understanding the reasons for this asymmetric response between the core and the periphery of the EMU and what kind of policies can address this situation are thus questions of first-order importance in the current debate.

Figure 2: Current Account and Real Exchange Rate (Relative to Germany)

Figure 2: Data for Figure 2 immediately follows.

Balance on the current account in % of GDP (left panel) and real exchange rate relative to Germany normalized to 100 in 2000Q1 (right panel) for Germany (black), Greece (blue), Ireland (green), Italy (cyan), Portugal (magenta) and Spain (red).

Data for Figure 2: Current Account

 GermanyGreeceIrelandItalyPortugalSpainNetherlandsFrance
2000 - Q1-1.4-4.6-0.20.5-11.2-3.72.91.7
2000 - Q2-1.4-6.01.5-0.6-11.3-4.12.42.1
2000 - Q3-2.4-7.2-1.5-0.3-9.4-4.7-1.31.2
2000 - Q4-2.2-6.3-1.2-0.4-9.7-3.64.30.8
2001 - Q1-1.2-3.7-0.40.3-10.3-4.02.01.6
2001 - Q2-0.7-4.1-0.5-0.1-11.6-4.41.41.1
2001 - Q30.6-7.2-0.1-0.2-10.8-3.54.42.3
2001 - Q41.3-5.6-1.81.1-8.7-3.92.72.0
2002 - Q11.2-6.9-0.80.4-9.1-3.33.01.3
2002 - Q21.6-7.5-4.3-0.8-8.5-3.1-0.41.3
2002 - Q32.8-5.00.1-0.3-7.7-2.74.01.1
2002 - Q42.2-8.10.6-1.1-7.7-3.94.01.3
2003 - Q10.7-7.4-0.5-1.3-5.7-3.52.30.8
2003 - Q21.3-6.80.0-1.5-7.1-3.36.00.7
2003 - Q32.8-5.3-0.1-0.3-6.1-3.56.30.6
2003 - Q42.8-7.30.3-0.2-6.9-3.77.70.9
2004 - Q14.0-5.11.60.2-7.3-4.46.30.8
2004 - Q25.5-6.1-0.6-0.7-7.6-5.37.41.0
2004 - Q34.4-5.7-1.50.2-8.8-5.67.20.2
2004 - Q44.5-6.5-2.0-1.1-9.6-5.79.80.3
2005 - Q14.9-7.4-3.0-0.7-9.9-7.47.3-0.6
2005 - Q25.0-6.4-3.1-0.9-10.5-7.08.0-0.2
2005 - Q35.3-7.9-3.7-1.1-10.2-7.37.5-0.4
2005 - Q44.7-8.8-4.3-0.9-10.7-7.76.9-0.7
2006 - Q14.8-13.6-3.1-1.8-11.8-8.410.2-0.4
2006 - Q26.1-11.6-3.2-1.7-11.0-8.310.0-0.9
2006 - Q36.1-10.1-3.6-1.5-10.5-9.49.4-0.7
2006 - Q47.8-11.0-4.5-1.1-9.5-9.77.8-0.3
2007 - Q16.8-14.1-5.3-1.2-9.1-8.78.2-0.1
2007 - Q27.8-13.5-4.3-1.1-9.2-9.76.3-1.5
2007 - Q37.5-14.2-4.6-1.1-10.3-10.95.2-0.9
2007 - Q47.8-16.7-7.4-1.9-11.7-10.87.0-1.5
2008 - Q17.1-13.2-6.2-2.8-11.9-10.55.7-1.4
2008 - Q26.9-15.8-5.4-1.9-12.5-10.24.7-2.2
2008 - Q35.8-16.1-7.8-3.2-13.4-9.05.4-2.1
2008 - Q45.0-14.9-3.4-3.6-12.8-8.91.2-1.3
2009 - Q14.4-10.3-2.7-2.5-11.1-5.72.7-0.9
2009 - Q25.5-11.6-2.3-2.1-10.3-4.06.3-1.9
2009 - Q36.5-11.5-2.3-2.1-10.1-4.15.7-0.6
2009 - Q47.4-11.3-2.1-1.3-12.1-5.55.8-1.9
2010 - Q16.0-13.50.5-3.0-10.3-4.17.6-1.0
2010 - Q25.7-7.00.6-3.8-12.8-5.27.3-1.3
2010 - Q36.1-10.91.9-3.7-9.3-4.38.4-1.9
2010 - Q46.8-8.91.5-3.7-10.0-4.77.7-2.2
2011 - Q16.9-10.2-1.9-3.9-8.0-4.39.5-2.3
2011 - Q25.8-10.72.3-3.6-9.9-3.510.0-2.1
2011 - Q36.2-10.61.9-3.0-5.9-3.010.5-2.1
2011 - Q46.1-8.42.0-1.9-4.2-3.610.3-1.4
2012 - Q16.8-5.30.4-1.5-4.4-3.410.6-2.4
2012 - Q26.9-4.09.0-0.6-1.0-1.69.2-2.7
2012 - Q37.6-0.95.5-0.5-0.4-0.110.0-2.1
2012 - Q47.0-1.1 0.2-0.41.99.9-2.5

Data for Figure 2: Real Exchange Rate (Relative to Germany)

 GERMANYGREECEIRELANDITALYPORTUGALSPAIN
2000 - Q1100100.00100.00100.00100.00100.00
2000 - Q2100100.40101.21100.34101.04100.59
2000 - Q3100100.79102.10100.59101.83101.45
2000 - Q4100101.59102.29100.40101.87101.32
2001 - Q1100101.59102.31100.41103.12101.35
2001 - Q2100101.94102.97100.56103.17101.60
2001 - Q3100102.70103.81100.67103.78101.65
2001 - Q4100103.40104.76101.23104.55102.38
2002 - Q1100103.93105.38101.15104.62102.67
2002 - Q2100104.65106.67101.70105.53103.91
2002 - Q3100105.43107.25102.25106.58104.28
2002 - Q4100105.98108.19102.69107.38105.06
2003 - Q1100106.60109.24102.92107.60105.43
2003 - Q2100107.40110.16103.79108.37105.95
2003 - Q3100107.82110.17104.01108.64106.34
2003 - Q4100108.22110.51104.33108.89106.78
2004 - Q1100108.54110.40104.23108.87106.75
2004 - Q2100108.69110.40104.23109.36107.28
2004 - Q3100108.82110.74104.34109.19107.72
2004 - Q4100109.31110.86104.34109.26108.13
2005 - Q1100110.33110.74104.66109.29108.44
2005 - Q2100110.36110.75104.66109.06108.82
2005 - Q3100110.47110.97104.45109.41109.10
2005 - Q4100110.69110.97104.45109.66109.53
2006 - Q1100111.49111.40104.76110.46110.55
2006 - Q2100111.83111.62104.86110.57110.80
2006 - Q3100112.45112.16105.17110.83111.19
2006 - Q4100112.74112.27105.16111.02111.00
2007 - Q1100112.61112.36104.85110.94111.12
2007 - Q2100112.58112.57104.75111.12111.30
2007 - Q3100113.06112.67104.75110.75111.46
2007 - Q4100113.35112.43104.65110.67112.06
2008 - Q1100114.06112.74105.24110.86112.73
2008 - Q2100114.54113.24105.43111.08113.10
2008 - Q3100114.71112.81105.52110.61113.26
2008 - Q4100114.87112.92105.92110.58112.89
2009 - Q1100115.30112.00105.92109.85112.47
2009 - Q2100115.27111.27106.11109.60112.10
2009 - Q3100116.04110.24106.11109.39112.60
2009 - Q4100116.77109.52106.30109.39112.81
2010 - Q1100117.98108.49106.49109.24113.07
2010 - Q2100119.86107.78106.58109.57113.48
2010 - Q3100121.09107.69106.77110.23113.60
2010 - Q4100120.73107.20106.75110.26113.82
2011 - Q1100120.72107.03106.73110.74114.30
2011 - Q2100120.66106.46106.81110.76114.26
2011 - Q3100120.49106.08106.80110.75113.95
2011 - Q4100120.66106.11107.72111.51113.84
2012 - Q1100119.85106.24107.89111.60113.69
2012 - Q2100119.53106.25108.34111.55114.07
2012 - Q3100119.01106.37108.32111.75114.79
2012 - Q4100118.95105.81108.39111.62115.12

A popular narrative for the poor performance of the European periphery is that this reflects the accumulation of "macroeconomic imbalances" since the introduction of the common currency (see, among others, Eichengreen, 2010; Chen et al., 2012). As shown in the left panel of Figure 2, peripheral euro-area countries persistently maintained current account deficits over the past decade, whereas core countries (represented in the chart by Germany, but Austria and the Netherlands followed a similar pattern) ran current account surpluses. This steep deterioration in the periphery's external borrowing position was associated with sizeable competitiveness losses. As shown in the right panel of Figure 2, the real exchange rate of peripheral countries appreciated, relative to Germany, between 6% (Italy) and 15% (Greece) over the period 2000-2008.2 Importantly, these appreciations largely reflect outsized increases in non-tradable good prices, such as housing and other services (see, for instance, Gaulier and Vicard, 2012).

Figure 3: Economic Rigidities

Figure 3: Data for Figure 3 immediately follows.

Scatter plot of product market (horizontal axis) and labor market (vertical axis) efficiency indexes (1 = minimum efficiency, 7 = maximum efficiency) for core (blue dots) and periphery (red dots) EMU countries.

Data for Figure 3

 PMRLMR
AUT5.333.92
BEL5.273.65
FIN4.984.14
FRA4.893.73
GER5.483.93
NET5.724.10
CORE5.073.87
GRE3.973.26
IRE4.964.51
ITA4.483.16
POR4.093.67
SPA4.763.41
PERIPHERY4.553.35

Amid limited policy options, including the impossibility of devaluing the currency, a broad consensus has emerged: Peripheral euro-area countries need to urgently adopt structural reforms that increase competition in product and labor markets. Such reforms would directly aim at the source of these macroeconomic imbalances, trying to achieve two complementary objectives in the context of the current crisis. First, reforms would effectively trigger a "real devaluation" of the periphery relative to the core, contributing to a reduction in the competitiveness gap accumulated over the past decade. Second, reforms would boost expectations about future growth prospects and stimulate current demand via wealth effects. This view is supported by the extensive empirical and survey-based evidence pointing to significantly higher economic rigidities in the periphery. Figure 3, for instance, presents indexes of economic flexibility obtained from the World Economic Forum (2012) that capture the degree of competition in product and labor markets.3 Indeed, peripheral countries score poorly along both dimensions.4 In light of these arguments--and evidence--it is perhaps not surprising that structural reforms are the cornerstone of both academics and international agencies' policy advice, as exemplified in the quote by the President of the European Commission Jose M.D. Barroso, reported above.

This paper investigates the effectiveness of structural reforms in an open economy version of the standard New-Keynesian model, with two sectors (tradable and non-tradable) and two countries that form a currency union. These two countries differ only in the extent to which policy barriers grant monopoly power to firms and unions. Structural reforms in one country (the "periphery" ) are introduced as a permanent reduction in product and labor market markups, in line with what is typically assumed in the literature (see, for instance, Bayoumi et al., 2004; Forni et al., 2010).

In our simulations, the long-run effects of structural reforms are unambiguously positive. A permanent reduction of product and labor market markups by 10 percentage points in the periphery service sector increases the level of output in that region by more than 5%, with positive spillovers to the core country.5 As output in the service sector expands and its prices fall, the periphery experiences a real exchange rate depreciation of more than 8%. Thus, these figures suggest that ambitious reforms implemented in peripheral EMU countries could greatly reduce the income and competitiveness gap observed between core and periphery.

Notwithstanding these long-run benefits, we find that the short-run transmission mechanism of these reforms critically depends on the ability of the central bank to provide policy accommodation. In normal times, reforms increase agents' permanent income and stimulate consumption. Amid falling aggregate prices, the central bank cuts the nominal interest rate and the currency union experiences a vigorous short-term boom.6 These effects, however, are completely overturned in crisis times. When the nominal interest rate is at the ZLB, reforms are contractionary, as expectations of prolonged deflation increase the real interest rate and depress consumption. In our simulations, the short-run output losses associated with the ZLB constraint are increasing with the magnitude of the reforms and become particularly large when reforms are not fully credible (and are later undone).

We next consider two experiments in order to disentangle the short-run transmission of reforms at the ZLB. In the spirit of Eggertsson (2012), we first study the effects of temporarily granting firms and unions higher monopoly power. In spite of the absence of long-run changes to output (income effect), these temporary reforms are expansionary when implemented at the ZLB. The main intuition for this surprising result is that such a policy would create inflationary expectations, thus reducing the real interest rate beyond the direct stimulus provided by monetary policy and providing incentives to households to front-load their consumption.

In a second experiment, we follow the recent work by Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2012) and study the effects of announcements to credibly implement structural reforms at some future date. This policy delivers a sizeable income effect thanks to the permanent increase in the long-run level of output but avoids the short-term costs of prolonged deflation, as reforms are implemented when the ZLB stops binding. The net effect is a significant boost in output, even in the short term.

Our research contributes to a growing literature that studies the implications of the ZLB constraint for the short-run transmission of shocks and policies. Eggertsson (2012) argues that New Deal policies facilitated the recovery from the Great Depression by temporarily granting monopoly power to firms and unions. Our work differs from his in two important respects. First, we consider the transmission of (markup) shocks in an open economy environment which features tradable and non-tradable goods, thus involving significant cross-sector and cross-country spillovers. Second, we focus on shocks that are permanent, emphasizing the horse race between sizeable increases in long-run income and short-run deflationary effects. A number of studies have also studied the transmission of fiscal shocks at the ZLB (see, for example, Christiano et al., 2011; Eggertsson, 2011; Erceg and Linde, 2012), often concluding that fiscal multipliers change greatly when the central bank's nominal interest rate is at its lower bound. While we leave a full investigation of the interaction between structural reforms and fiscal policy for future research, our findings do suggest that the magnitude, and possibly the sign, of the structural reform "multiplier" may change as well at the ZLB.7

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines a simplified closed economy model to illustrate the two offsetting effects that are critical for our evaluation: The perverse effect of structural reforms due to deflationary expectations, and the positive effect due to a permanent increase in long-run income. Section 3 presents the full two-country model and its calibration. Section 4 discusses the effects of structural reforms in normal times. Section 5 introduces the crisis and re-evaluates the effects of structural reforms in that context. Section 6 studies two alternative policies that avoid the perverse short-run effects of structural reforms. Finally, Section 7 concludes.


2  An Illustrative Model

We begin our analysis by studying the effects of structural reforms in a linearized version of a standard closed economy model with monopolistic competition and sticky prices. The basic New Keynesian structure of this model is also at the heart of the open economy DSGE model that we use in our quantitative experiments. While we study the full non-linear dynamics of our multi-country model, the simple intuition that arises from the linearized closed economy provides insights about the main tradeoffs associated with structural reforms when monetary policy is constrained by the ZLB.

The linearized version of the prototype New-Keynesian model can be summarized by the following two equations

$\displaystyle \hat{Y}_{t}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \mathbb{E}_{t}\hat{Y}_{t+1}-\sigma ^{-1}(i_{t}-\mathbb{E} _{t}\pi _{t+1}-r_{t}^{e}),$ (1)
$\displaystyle \pi _{t}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \kappa \hat{Y}_{t}+\beta \mathbb{E}_{t}\pi _{t+1}+\kappa \psi \omega _{t},$ (2)

where $ \pi _{t}$ is inflation$ ,$ $ \hat{Y}_{t}$ is output in deviation from its first best level, $ r_{t}^{e}$ is an exogenous disturbance, $ \kappa $ is the slope of the Phillips curve (a convolution of structural parameters), $ \sigma $ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion, $ \psi \equiv 1/(\sigma +\nu )$ , where $ \nu $ is the inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply, and $ \mathbb{E}_{t}$ is the expectation operator conditional on all information available at time $ t$. The variable $ \omega _{t}$ denotes a wedge between output under flexible prices and the first best level of output. In the microfoundation of the model, this wedge could either be driven by the market power of firms (due to monopolistic competition in product markets) or markups in the labor markets. We interpret structural reforms as policies that aim at reducing this wedge by promoting competition in product and labor markets, for instance through lower entry barriers in industries, removal of restrictions on working hours, and privatization of government-owned enterprises with corresponding increase in the number of operating firms in protected sectors.

Consider a regime where $ \pi _{t}=0,$ that is, the central bank manages to target zero inflation at all times. Under this assumption, the model becomes static. In particular, we can think of the short and long-run equilibrium separately. Denote short-run variables by $ t=S$ and long-run variables by $ t=L.$ Then, equation (2) reduces to

$\displaystyle \hat{Y}_{S}=-\psi \omega _{S}$   and$\displaystyle \qquad \hat{Y}_{L}=-\psi \omega _{L}.$ (3)

Equations (3) reveals two important insights. First, structural reforms have an unambiguous impact on output, whose magnitude depends on $ \psi .$ In particular, a reduction in the wedge increases output. Second, under zero-inflation targeting, aggregate demand (equation 1) plays no role in determining short-run output. It is simply a pricing equation that pins down the level of the interest rate $ i_{t}$ consistent with zero inflation.

The dynamics significantly change when monetary policy is constrained by the ZLB. Consider the following shock, common in the literature on the zero bound due to its analytic simplicity: At time zero, the shock $ r_{t}^{e}$ takes value $ r_{S}^{e}<0$ but then, in each period, it reverts back to steady state with probability $ 1-\mu $. Once in steady state, the shock stays there forever. We can consider both long- and short-run structural reforms in this framework. In particular, consider reforms such that $ \omega =\omega _{S}$ when the $ r_{t}^{e}=r_{S}^{e}$ and $ \omega =\omega _{L}$ when the shock is back to steady state (i.e. $ r_{t}^{e}=r_{L}^{e}$). Under these assumptions, the model can still be conveniently split into long run and short run by exploiting the forward-looking nature of the equations. Moreover, as long as $ r_{S}^{e}<0$ and the policy $ (\omega _{S},\omega _{L})$ is sufficiently close to the point around which we approximate, the ZLB is binding only in the short run.

This shock dramatically changes the short-run equilibrium. When the nominal interest rate is at zero, the economy becomes completely demand-determined and equation (1) becomes relevant for the determination of output. Using our assumptions about the interest rate shock, and taking the solution once the shock is over as given (which we continue to denote by $ L$), we can rewrite equation (1) and equation (2) as

AD:$\displaystyle \qquad \qquad \hat{Y}_{S}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \hat{Y}_{L}+\frac{\sigma ^{-1}\mu }{ 1-\mu }\pi _{S}+\frac{\sigma ^{-1}}{1-\mu }r_{S}^{e},$ (4)
AS:$\displaystyle \qquad \qquad \pi _{S}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \frac{\kappa }{1-\mu \beta }\hat{Y}_{S}+ \frac{\kappa \psi }{1-\mu \beta }\omega _{S}.$ (5)

Figure 4: Short-Run Equilibrium of Aggregate Demand (AD) and Aggregate Supply (AS) at the ZLB

Figure 4 presents the short-run equilibrium of aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) at the ZLB. The horizontal axis represents output (Y) and the vertical axis inflation (pi). Note that in crisis times (at the ZLB), the AD curve is upward sloping and the equilibrium is represented by the intersection of the AD and AS in a point like A. Temporary structural reforms correspond to a shift of the AS curve and the new equilibrium is represented by a point like B, where both output and inflation are lower. Permanent structural reforms, however, also involve a shift in the AD curve and the equilibrium looks like the point C. The balance of the shifts in AS and AD curves determines if point C is associated with higher or lower output and inflation.

Short-run equilibrium at the ZLB under permanent structural reforms in the illustrative model.

Given the policy $ (\omega _{S},\omega _{L}),$ the short-run equilibrium is a pair $ (\pi _{S},\hat{Y}_{S})$ that satisfies these two equations. Graphically, the equilibrium corresponds to the intersection of the aggregate supply (AS) and the aggregate demand (AD) "curves," as shown by point A in Figure 4. Note that, when the ZLB binds, the aggregate demand curve becomes upward-sloping, as higher inflation stimulates demand through lower real interest rates.8

Figure 4 shows the impact of permanent structural reforms (i.e. a reduction in $ \omega _{S}$ and $ \omega _{L}$) on short-run output and inflation. A product or labor market liberalization generates two effects. First, it shifts the AS curve down, as firms can produce more output for any given level of inflation. Perhaps somewhat surprisingly, this effect turns out to be contractionary in the short run. At the ZLB, reforms amplify deflationary pressures, resulting in a higher real interest rate and contracting aggregate demand. Given that the interest rate is stuck at zero, the central bank cannot provide enough monetary stimulus to offset this effect and output declines.9

As shown in equation (4), however, reforms also have a second effect on short-run output $ \hat{Y}_{S}$ through $ \hat{Y}_{L}$, thus shifting the aggregate demand schedule outward (see again Figure 4). As structural reforms increase permanent income, output and inflation move up in the short term as well. Thus, depending on the relative strength of these two effects, reforms may be contractionary or expansionary in the short run. For instance, if structural reforms do not have much "credibility" (i.e. agents expect a policy reversal at some point in the future, such that $ \omega _{S}<0$ but $ \omega _{L}=0$), the AS curve shifts down whereas the AD curve does not change, and the reforms are clearly contractionary (point B in Figure 4). In contrast, ambitious reforms that are gradually implemented and become more credible over time are associated with large permanent income effects, shifting the AD curve more than the AS curve (point C in Figure 4).

The question of which effect dominates is ultimately quantitative. For this purpose, in the next section, we develop and calibrate a two-country model of a monetary union that we then use as a laboratory to evaluate the effects of different structural reforms experiments.

The open-economy dimension of the model is important to make our analysis concrete with respect to two key features that are relevant for the debate on the European crisis. First, the evidence in Figure 3 suggests that structural reforms are mostly needed in the periphery, to favor a catch-up in competitiveness with the core. Second, and related, structural reforms may prove helpful in closing the imbalances in external borrowing and relative prices that have received so much attention since the onset of the crisis. Our analysis sheds light on the short-run interaction between the role of structural reforms in correcting these imbalances and monetary policy when the nominal interest rate is constrained by the ZLB.


3  The Full Model

The world economy consists of two countries, the periphery ($ H$) and the core ($ F$), that belong to a currency union whose population size is normalized to one. The common central bank sets monetary policy for the union targeting zero inflation.

A continuum of households of measure $ n$ inhabits country $ H$. Each household derives utility from consumption of tradable and non-tradable goods and disutility from hours worked. Households supply sector-specific differentiated labor inputs. A representative labor agency combines these inputs in sector-specific aggregates, while households set the wage for each input on a staggered basis.

Firms in each country produce tradable and a non-tradable goods using labor, which is immobile across countries. Production takes place in two stages. In each sector (tradable and non-tradable), a representative retailer combines differentiated intermediate goods to produce the final consumption good. Monopolistic competitive wholesale producers set the price of each differentiated intermediate good on a staggered basis.

In each country, we assume the existence of a full set of transfers that completely insure against the idiosyncratic income risk arising from staggered price and wage setting. Across countries, the only asset traded is a one-period nominal bond denominated in the common currency. One-period changes in the net foreign asset position define the current account.

This section presents the details of the model from the perspective of the periphery (country $ H$). Variables for the core (country $ F$) are denoted by an asterisk.

3.1  Retailers

A representative wholesale producer in the tradable ($ k=H$) and non-tradable ($ k=N$) sector combines raw goods according to a technology with constant elasticity of substitution $ \theta _{k}>1$

$\displaystyle Y_{kt}=\left[ \left( \frac{1}{\gamma _{k}}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\theta _{k}} }\int_{0}^{\gamma _{k}}Y_{kt}(j)^{\frac{\theta _{k}-1}{\theta _{k}}}dj\right] ^{\frac{\theta _{k}}{\theta _{k}-1}},$ (6)

where $ j$ indexes an intermediate goods producer and $ \gamma _{k}=\{\gamma ,1-\gamma \}$ is the size of the tradable and non-tradable sector, respectively.

The representative retailer in sector $ k$ maximizes profits subject to its technological constraint (6)

$\displaystyle \max_{Y_{kt}(j)}P_{kt}Y_{kt}-\int_{0}^{\gamma _{k}}P_{kt}(j)Y_{kt}(j)dj.$ (7)

The first order condition for this problem yields the standard demand function

$\displaystyle Y_{kt}(j)=\frac{1}{\gamma _{k}}\left[ \frac{P_{kt}(j)}{P_{kt}}\right] ^{-\theta_k}Y_{kt},$ (8)

where $ P_{kt}(j)$ is the price of the $ j^{th}$ variety of the good produced in sector $ k$. The zero profit condition implies that the price index in sector $ k$ is

$\displaystyle P_{kt}=\left[ \frac{1}{\gamma _{k}}\int_{0}^{\gamma _{k}}P_{kt}(j)^{1-\theta_k}dj\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\theta_k}}.$ (9)

3.2  Labor Agencies

In each sector, a representative labor agency combines differentiated labor inputs provided by each household $ L_{kt}(i)$ into a sector-specific homogenous aggregate according to a technology with constant elasticity of substitution $ \phi _{k}>1$

$\displaystyle L_{kt}=\left[ \left( \frac{1}{\gamma _{k}n}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\phi _{k}} }\int_{0}^{\gamma _{k}n}L_{kt}(i)^{\frac{\phi _{k}-1}{\phi _{k}}}di\right] ^{ \frac{\phi _{k}}{\phi _{k}-1}}.$ (10)

The representative labor agency in sector $ k$ maximizes profits subject to its technological constraint (10)

$\displaystyle \max_{L_{kt}(i)}W_{kt}L_{kt}-\int_{0}^{\gamma _{k}n}W_{kt}(i)L_{kt}(i)di,$ (11)

where $ W_{kt}$ is the wage index in sector $ k$ and $ W_{kt}(i)$ is the wage specific to type-$ i$ labor input. The first order condition for this problem is

$\displaystyle L_{kt}(i)=\frac{1}{\gamma _{k}n}\left( \frac{W_{kt}(i)}{W_{kt}}\right) ^{-\phi_k}L_{kt}.$ (12)

The zero profit condition implies that the wage index is

$\displaystyle W_{kt}=\left[ \frac{1}{\gamma _{k}n}\int_{0}^{\gamma_k n}W_{kt}(i)^{1-\phi_k}di\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\phi_k}}.$ (13)

3.3  Intermediate Goods Producers

A continuum of measure $ \gamma_{k}$ of intermediate goods producers operate in each sector using the technology

$\displaystyle Y_{kt}(j)=Z_{kt}L_{kt}(j),$ (14)

where $ Z_{kt}$ is an exogenous productivity shock.

Intermediate goods producers are imperfectly competitive and choose the price for their variety $ P_{kt}(j)$, as well as the optimum amount of labor inputs $ L_{kt}(j)$, to maximize profits subject to their technological constraint (14) and the demand for their variety (8).

As customary, we can separate the intermediate goods producers problem in two steps. First, for a given price, these firms minimize labor costs subject to their technology constraint. The result of this step is that the marginal cost (the Lagrange multiplier on the constraint) equals the nominal wage scaled by the level of productivity

$\displaystyle MC_{kt}(j)=MC_{kt}=\frac{W_{kt}}{Z_{kt}}.$ (15)

This condition also shows that the marginal cost is independent of firm-specific characteristics. However, because of nominal price and wage rigidities, aggregate labor demand in each sector depends on price dispersion. We can use the demand function (8) and the production function (14) to write an aggregate production function as

$\displaystyle Y_{kt} \Delta_{kt} = Z_{kt} L_{kt},$ (16)

where equilibrium in the labor market implies

$\displaystyle L_{kt} = \int_0^{\gamma_k} L_{kt}(j) dj$

and $ \Delta_{kt}$ is an index of price dispersion defined as

$\displaystyle \Delta_{kt} \equiv \frac{1}{\gamma_k} \int_0^{\gamma_k} \left[\frac{P_{kt}(j) }{P_{kt}} \right]^{-\theta_k} dj.$

The second step of the intermediate goods producers' problem is the optimal price setting decision, given the expression for the marginal cost. We assume that firms change their price on a staggered basis. Following Calvo (1983), the probability of not being able to change the price in each period is $ \xi_p \in (0,1)$. The optimal price setting problem for a firm $ j$ that is able to reset its price at time $ t$ is

$\displaystyle \max_{\widetilde{P}_{kt}(j)}\mathbb{E}_{t} \left\{ \underset{s=0}{\overset{ \infty }{\sum }}\xi_p^s Q_{t,t+s}\left[ (1 - \tau^p_{kt+s}) \widetilde{P} _{kt}(j) - MC_{kt+s} \right] Y_{kt+s}(j) \right\},$ (17)

subject to the demand for their variety (8) conditional on no price change between $ t$ and $ t+s$. Households in each country own a diversified non-traded portfolio of domestic tradable and non-tradable intermediate goods producing firms. Therefore, firms discount future profits using $ Q_{t,t+s}$--the individual stochastic discount factor for a nominal asset between period $ t$ and period $ t+s$ (such that $ Q_{t,t}=1$). The time-varying tax $ \tau^p_{kt+s}$ is the policy instrument that the government can use to affect the degree of competitiveness in each sector. Ceteris paribus, a lower tax reduces the firms' effective markup and increases output. We discuss government policy in more details below.

In equilibrium, all firms that reset their price at time $ t$ choose the same strategy ( $ \widetilde{P}_{kt}(j)=\widetilde{P}_{kt}$). After some manipulations, we can write the optimality condition as

$\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{P}_{kt}}{P_{kt}}=\frac{\frac{\theta _{k}}{\theta _{k}-1} \mathbb{E}_{t}\left\{ \sum_{s=0}^{\infty }\xi _{p}^{s}Q_{t,t+s}MC_{kt+s}Y_{kt+s}\Pi _{kt+s}^{\theta _{k}}\right\} }{ \mathbb{E}_{t}\left\{ \sum_{s=0}^{\infty }\xi _{p}^{s}Q_{t,t+s}(1-\tau _{kt+s}^{p})P_{kt+s}Y_{kt+s}\Pi _{kt+s}^{\theta _{k}-1}\right\} },$ (18)

where $ \Pi _{kt}\equiv P_{kt}/P_{kt-1}$ is the inflation rate in sector $ k$. Firms that are not able to adjust, on average, keep their price fixed at the previous period's level. The price index (9) for sector $ k$ yields a non-linear relation between the optimal relative reset price and the inflation rate

$\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{P}_{kt}}{P_{kt}}=\left( \frac{1-\xi _{p}\Pi _{kt}^{\theta _{k}-1}}{1-\xi _{p}}\right) ^{\frac{1}{1-\theta _{k}}}.$ (19)

Moreover, from the price index (9) and the assumption of staggered price setting, we can also derive the law of motion for the index of price dispersion

$\displaystyle \Delta _{kt}=\xi _{p}\Delta _{kt-1}\Pi _{kt}^{\theta _{k}}+(1-\xi _{p})\left( \frac{1-\xi _{p}\Pi _{kt}^{\theta _{k}-1}}{1-\theta _{k}}\right) ^{\frac{\theta _{k}}{\theta _{k}-1}}.$ (20)

In steady state, there is no price dispersion ( $ \Delta _{k}=1$) and the price in sector $ k$ is a markup over the marginal cost

$\displaystyle P_{k}=\frac{1}{1-\tau _{k}^{p}}\frac{\theta _{k}}{\theta _{k}-1}MC_{k}.$ (21)

The government can choose a value of $ \tau _{k}^{p}$ that fully offsets firms' monopolistic power--or, more generally, set a desired markup level in the goods market.

3.4  Households

In country $ H$, a continuum of households of measure $ n$ derive utility from consumption and supply differentiated labor inputs while setting wages on a staggered basis (Calvo, 1983). Consumption is a composite of tradable and non-tradable goods with constant elasticity of substitution $ \varphi >0$

$\displaystyle C_{t}(i)=\left[ \gamma ^{\frac{1}{\varphi }}C_{Tt}(i)^{\frac{\varphi -1}{ \varphi }}+(1-\gamma )^{\frac{1}{\varphi }}C_{Nt}(i)^{\frac{\varphi -1}{ \varphi }}\right] ^{\frac{\varphi }{\varphi -1}},$ (22)

where $ \gamma \in (0,1)$ is the share of tradables in total consumption. The associated expenditure minimization problem is

$\displaystyle P_{t}C_{t}(i)\equiv \min_{C_{Tt}(i),C_{Nt}(i)}P_{Tt}C_{Tt}(i)+P_{Nt}C_{Nt}(i),$ (23)

subject to (22). The first order condition for this problem yields the demand for the tradable and non-tradable goods

$\displaystyle C_{Tt}(i)$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \gamma \left( \frac{P_{Tt}}{P_{t}}\right) ^{-\varphi }C_{t}(i),$ (24)
$\displaystyle C_{Nt}(i)$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle (1-\gamma )\left( \frac{P_{Nt}}{P_{t}}\right) ^{-\varphi }C_{t}(i).$ (25)

The associated price index is

$\displaystyle P_{t}=\left[ \gamma P_{Tt}^{1-\varphi }+(1-\gamma )P_{Nt}^{1-\varphi }\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\varphi }}.$ (26)

Consumption of tradables includes goods produced in the two countries combined according to a constant elasticity of substitution ( $ \epsilon >0$) aggregator

$\displaystyle C_{Tt}(i)=\left[ \omega ^{\frac{1}{\epsilon }}C_{Ht}(i)^{\frac{\epsilon -1}{ \epsilon }}+(1-\omega )^{\frac{1}{\epsilon }}C_{Ft}(i)^{\frac{\epsilon -1}{ \epsilon }}\right] ^{\frac{\epsilon }{\epsilon -1}},$ (27)

where $ \omega \in (n,1)$ is the share of tradable goods produced in country $ H$. We assume that the law of one price holds for internationally tradable goods

$\displaystyle P_{Ht}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle P_{Ht}^{\ast },$ (28)
$\displaystyle P_{Ft}^{\ast }$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle P_{Ft}.$ (29)

The expenditure minimization problem is

$\displaystyle P_{Tt}C_{Tt}(i)\equiv \min_{C_{Ht}(i),C_{Ft}(i)}P_{Ht}C_{Ht}(i)+P_{Ft}C_{Ft}(i),$ (30)

subject to (27). The first order conditions for this problem yield the standard demand functions for tradable goods

$\displaystyle C_{Ht}(i)$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \omega \left( \frac{P_{Ht}}{P_{Tt}}\right) ^{-\epsilon }C_{Tt}(i),$ (31)
$\displaystyle C_{Ft}(i)$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \left( 1-\omega \right) \left( \frac{P_{Ft}}{P_{Tt}}\right) ^{-\epsilon }C_{Tt}(i).$ (32)

The zero profit condition implies that the price index for tradable goods is

$\displaystyle P_{Tt}=\left[ \omega P_{Ht}^{1-\epsilon }+(1-\omega )P_{Ft}^{1-\epsilon } \right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\epsilon }}.$ (33)

While the the law of one price holds, home bias in tradable consumption ($ \omega >n$) implies that the price index for tradable goods differs across countries ( $ P_{Tt}\neq P_{Tt}^{\ast }$). Consumer price indexes (CPI) further differ across countries because of the presence of non-tradable goods. Therefore, purchasing power parity fails ( $ P_{t}\neq P_{t}^{\ast }$) and the real exchange rate ( $ RER_t \equiv P^*_t/P_t$) endogenously moves.

Conditional on the allocation between tradable and non-tradable goods and between tradable goods produced in country $ H$ and $ F$, the problem of a generic household $ i\in (0,n)$ in country $ H$ is

$\displaystyle \max_{C_{t+s}(i),B_{t+s}(i),W_{kt+s}(i)}\mathbb{E}_{t}\left\{ \sum_{s=0}^{\infty }\beta ^{s}\varsigma _{t+s}\left[ \frac{ C_{t+s}(i)^{1-\sigma }}{1-\sigma }-\frac{L_{kt+s}(i)^{1+\nu }}{1+\nu }\right] \right\} ,$ (34)

subject to the demand for labor input (12) and the budget constraint

$\displaystyle P_{t}C_{t}(i)+\frac{B_{t}(i)}{\psi _{Bt}}=(1+i_{t-1})B_{t-1}(i)+(1-\tau _{kt}^{w})W_{kt}(i)L_{kt}(i)+\mathcal{P}_{t}(i)+\mathcal{T}_{t}(i),$ (35)

where $ B_{t}$ represents nominal debt, $ \mathcal{P}_{t}$ indicates profits from intermediate goods producers and $ \mathcal{T}_{t}$ represents lump-sum tranfers. As for the goods market, the sector-specific and time-varying tax $ \tau _{kt}^{w}$ is the policy instrument that the government can use to affect the degree of competitiveness in the labor market of each sector. Ceteris paribus, a lower tax reduces workers' monopoly power and increases labor supply. The variable $ \varsigma _{t}$ is a preference shock that makes agents more or less impatient. For instance, positive preference shocks (an increase in the desire to save) may capture disruptions in financial markets that force the monetary authority to lower the nominal interest rate to zero. Finally, as in Erceg et al. (2006), the intermediation cost $ \psi _{Bt}$ ensures stationarity of the net foreign asset position

$\displaystyle \psi _{Bt}\equiv \exp \left[ -\psi _{B}\left( \frac{nB_{t}}{P_{t}Y_{t}} \right) \right] ,$ (36)

where $ \psi _{B}>0$ and $ P_{t}Y_{t}$ corresponds to nominal GDP

$\displaystyle P_{t}Y_{t}\equiv P_{Ht}Y_{Ht}+P_{Nt}Y_{Nt}.$ (37)

Only domestic households pay the transaction cost while foreign households collect the associated fees. Moreover, while we assume that the intermediation cost is a function of the net foreign asset position, domestic households do not internalize this dependency.10

The existence of a full set of transfers that completely insure against the idiosyncratic income risk arising from staggered price and wage setting and an appropriate normalization of initial wealth levels implies that all households make the same consumption and savings decisions ( $ C_{t}(a)=C_{t}(b)$, $ \forall \{a,b\}\in (0,n)$). Hence, from now on, we will suppress the index $ i$ from consumption variables. The consumption-saving optimality conditions yield

$\displaystyle 1=\beta \psi _{Bt}(1+i_{t})\mathbb{E}_{t}\left[ \frac{\varsigma _{t+1}}{ \varsigma _{t}}\left( \frac{C_{t+1}}{C_{t}}\right) ^{-\sigma }\frac{1}{\Pi _{t+1}}\right] .$ (38)

From expression (38), we can denote the stochastic discount factor for nominal assets ($ Q_{t,t+s}$) as

$\displaystyle Q_{t,t+s}=\beta ^{s}\frac{\varsigma _{t+s}}{\varsigma _{t}}\left( \frac{ C_{t+s}}{C_{t}}\right) ^{-\sigma }\frac{1}{\Pi _{t+s}}.$ (39)

Each household has a probability of being able to reset the wage at time $ t$ equal to $ \xi _{w}$. The optimal wage setting problem in case of adjustment for household $ i$ working in sector $ k$ is

$\displaystyle \max_{\widetilde{W}_{kt}(i)}\mathbb{E}_{t}\left\{ \underset{s=0}{\overset{ \infty }{\sum }}(\beta \xi _{w})^{s}\left[ (1-\tau _{kt+s}^{w})C_{t+s}^{-\sigma }\frac{\widetilde{W}_{kt}(i)}{P_{t+s}} L_{kt+s}(i)-\frac{L_{kt+s}(i)^{1+\nu }}{1+\nu }\right] \right\} ,$ (40)

subject to the demand for the specific labor variety (12) conditional on no wage change between $ t$ and $ t+s$.

In equilibrium, all households who reset their wage at time $ t$ choose the same strategy ( $ \widetilde{W}_{kt}(i)=\widetilde{W}_{kt}$). After some manipulations, we can rewrite the first order condition for optimal wage setting as

$\displaystyle \left( \frac{\widetilde{W}_{kt}}{W_{kt}}\right) ^{1+\phi _{k}\nu }=\frac{ \frac{\phi _{k}}{\phi _{k}-1}\mathbb{E}_{t}\left\{ \sum_{s=0}^{\infty }(\beta \xi _{w})^{s}\varsigma _{t+s}\left( L_{kt+s}/\gamma _{k}n\right) ^{1+\nu }(\Pi _{kt+s}^{w})^{\phi _{k}(1+\nu )}\right\} }{\mathbb{E} _{t}\left\{ \sum_{s=0}^{\infty }(\beta \xi _{w})^{s}\varsigma _{t+s}(1-\tau _{kt+s}^{w})C_{t+s}^{-\sigma }(W_{kt+s}/P_{t+s})(L_{kt+s}/\gamma _{k}n)(\Pi _{kt+s}^{w})^{\phi _{k}-1}\right\} },$ (41)

where $ \Pi _{kt}^{w}\equiv W_{kt}/W_{kt-1}$ is the wage inflation rate in sector $ k$. The remaining households, who are not able to adjust, on average keep their wages fixed at the previous period's level. The wage index (13) for sector $ k$ yields a non-linear relation between the optimal relative reset wage and the wage inflation rate

$\displaystyle \frac{\widetilde{W}_{kt}}{W_{kt}}=\left[ \frac{1-\xi _{w}(\Pi _{kt}^{w})^{\phi _{k}-1}}{1-\xi _{w}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\phi _{k}}}.$ (42)

In steady state, the real wage in sector $ k$ is a markup over the marginal rate of substitution between labor and consumption

$\displaystyle \frac{W_{k}}{P}=\frac{1}{1-\tau _{k}^{w}}\frac{\phi _{k}}{\phi _{k}-1}\frac{ \left( L_{k}/\gamma _{k}n\right) ^{\nu }}{C^{-\sigma }}.$

As in the case of prices, the government can choose a tax that fully offsets workers' monopolistic power--or, more generally, set a desired markup level in the labor market.

3.5  Fiscal and Monetary Policy

We assume that the government in each country rebates goods and labor market taxes via lump-sum transfers

$\displaystyle \mathcal{T}_{t}\equiv \int_0^n \mathcal{T}_{t}(i)di=\int_{0}^{1}\tau _{kt}^{p}P_{kt}Y_{kt}(j)dj+\int_{0}^{n}\tau _{kt}^{w}W_{kt}L_{kt}(i)di.$ (43)

Using (37) and its foreign counterpart, we construct a union-wide level of output as a population-weighted geometric average of the levels of output in the two countries

$\displaystyle Y_{t}^{MU}\equiv (Y_{t})^{n}(Y_{t}^{\ast })^{n}.$ (44)

In the same spirit, we define the union-wide price index $ P_{t}^{MU}$ as a population-weighted geometric average of the CPIs in the two countries11

$\displaystyle P_{t}^{MU}\equiv (P_{t})^{n}(P_{t}^{\ast })^{1-n}$ (45)

Consequently, the inflation rate in the currency union is

$\displaystyle \Pi _{t}^{MU}=(\Pi _{t})^{n}(\Pi _{t}^{\ast })^{1-n}.$ (46)

We assume that a single central bank sets the nominal interest rate in the entire union to implement a strict inflation target

$\displaystyle \Pi _{t}^{MU}=\bar{\Pi}.$

However, we take explicitly into account the possibility that the nominal interest rate cannot fall below some lower bound

$\displaystyle i_{t}\geq i^{zlb}.$

In the aftermath of shocks that take the economy to the lower bound, the central bank keeps the nominal interest rate at $ i^{zlb}$ until inflation reaches its target again. Our results would be unchanged if we were to specify an interest rate rule that responds to inflation, the output gap and/or the natural rate of interest.

3.6  Equilibrium

An imperfect competitive equilibrium for this economy is a sequence of quantities and prices such that the optimality conditions for households and firms in the two countries hold, the markets for final non-tradable goods and for labor inputs in each sector clear at the country level, and the markets for tradable goods and financial assets clear at the union level. Because of nominal rigidities, intermediate goods producers and workers who cannot adjust their contracts stand ready to supply goods and labor inputs at the price and wage prevailing in the previous period. An appendix available upon request contains the detailed list of equilibrium conditions. Here we note that goods market clearing in the tradable and non-tradable sectors satisfies

$\displaystyle \int_0^n C_{Ht}(i)di+\int_n^1 C_{Ht}^{\ast }(i)di =$ $\displaystyle nC_{Ht}+(1-n)C_{Ht}^{\ast }$ $\displaystyle = Y_{Ht},$ (47)
$\displaystyle \int_0^n C_{Ft}(i)di+\int_n^1 C_{Ft}^{\ast }(i)di =$ $\displaystyle nC_{Ft}+(1-n)C_{Ft}^{\ast }$ $\displaystyle =Y_{Ft}^{\ast },$ (48)

$\displaystyle \int_0^n C_{Nt}(i)di =$ $\displaystyle nC_{Nt}$ $\displaystyle = Y_{Nt},$ (49)
$\displaystyle \int_n^1 C^*_{Nt}(i)di =$ $\displaystyle (1-n)C_{Nt}^{\ast }$ $\displaystyle = Y_{Nt}^{\ast }.$ (50)

Integrating the budget constraint across households in country $ H$ and using the zero profit conditions for labor agencies and retailers, as well as the government budget constraint and the equilibrium conditions for tradable and non-tradable goods, implies that net foreign assets evolve according to

$\displaystyle \frac{nB_{t}}{\psi _{Bt}}=\left( 1+i_{t}\right) nB_{t-1}+P_{Ht}(1-n)C_{Ht}^{\ast}-P_{Ft}nC_{Ft}.$ (51)

Finally, asset market clearing requires

$\displaystyle nB_{t}+(1-n)B_{t}^{\ast }=0.$ (52)

3.7  Calibration and Solution Strategy

In our experiments, we model structural reforms as changes in the tax rates $ \tau _{t}^{w}$ and $ \tau _{t}^{p}$ that affect, permanently or temporarily, the markups in the labor and product markets (i.e. the degree of competition in the two markets). We run deterministic non-linear simulations that allow us to quantify the steady state effects and trace the dynamic evolution of the endogenous variables in response to the policy experiment.12

Table 1: Product market markup estimates by sector.

 Periphery ($ H$)Core ($ F$)
Total private firms1.361.25
Manufacturing (Tradable)1.171.14
Services (Nontradable)1.481.33

Note: Source: OECD (2005). Periphery: Italy and Spain. Core: France and Germany.

We set the initial levels of price markups in the periphery and the core following the estimates produced by the OECD (2005) for peripheral and core EMU, reported in Table 1. We consider the manufacturing sector as a proxy for the tradable sector in the model and the service sector as a proxy for the non-tradable sector. The OECD estimates for price markups show two interesting patterns. First, markups in the periphery are higher than in the core, consistent with the evidence provided in Figure 3. Second, this difference is largely accounted for by higher markups in the service sector of the periphery, whereas markups in the manufacturing sector are similar across regions. These data support the view that peripheral European countries could greatly benefit from the implementation of liberalization measures in the product market.

In order to calibrate the elasticity of substitution $ \theta $ in sector $ k$ of each region, we start from the expression of the total markup in the steady state

$\displaystyle \mu _{k}\equiv \frac{1}{1-\tau _{k}^{p}}\frac{\theta _{k}}{\theta _{k}-1}.$ (53)

For the manufacturing sector, we assume symmetry across countries and no policy-induced distortions (i.e. $ \tau _{H}^{p}=\tau _{F}^{p\ast }=0$). Targeting a steady state net markup of 15%, this strategy allows us to pin down the elasticity of substitution in the tradable sector ( $ \theta _{H}=\theta _{F}^{\ast }=7.7$). For the service sector, we assume no policy distortion in the core ( $ \tau _{N}^{p\ast }=0$). The estimate in Table 1 then implies $ \theta _{N}^{\ast }=4$. We assume that the elasticity is the same in the periphery ( $ \theta _{N}=\theta _{N}^{\ast }$) and attribute the difference in the OECD markup estimates to policy distortions ( $ \tau _{N}^{p}=0.1$).

Empirical studies point to similar patterns for wage markups across countries and sectors. Although direct estimates of wage markups are more difficult to obtain, data on wage premia (Jean and Nicoletti, 2002) and evidence on wage bargaining power in Europe (Everaert and Schule, 2006) indicate that wage markups are likely to be higher in peripheral countries than in core countries because of higher markups in the service sector. Furthermore, the point estimates of the implied wage markups so computed are not too different from the figures presented in Table 1. Thus, we set the wage elasticities and taxes across sectors and regions equal to the corresponding values for the product market.13

Table 2. Parameter Values

ParameterValue
Households: Country size$ n $= 0.5
Households: Individual discount factor$ \beta $ = 0.99
Households: Inverse Frisch elasticity$ \nu $ = 2
Households: Elasticity of intertemporal substitution$ \sigma^{-1} $ = 2
Households: Home bias$ \omega $ = 0.57
Households: Consumption share of tradable goods$ \gamma $ = 0.38
Households: Elasticity of substitution tradables-nontradables$ \epsilon $ = 0.5
Households: Elasticity of substitution H-F tradables$ \varphi $ = 1.5
Price and Wage Setting: Probability of not being able to adjust prices$ \xi _{p}$ = 0.66
Price and Wage Setting: Probability of not being able to adjust wages$ \xi _{w}$ = 0.66
Monetary Policy: Inflation target$ \bar{\Pi}$ = 1
Monetary Policy: Effective lower bound on nominal interest rate$ i^{zlb}$ = 0.0025

The remaining parameters used in our simulations are relatively standard (Table 2). In our benchmark experiment, the core and the periphery have the same size ($ n=0.5$). The individual discount factor $ \beta $ equals 0.99, implying an annualized real interest rate of about 4%. The coefficient of relative risk aversion $ \sigma $ is equal to 0.5, which is within the range of estimates provided in Hansen adn Singleton (1983) and slightly higher than Rotembert and Woodford (1997). The inverse Frisch elasticity $ \nu $ is equal to 2, a value commonly used in the New-Keynesian literature (see, for instance, Erceg and Linde, 2012). We calibrate the degree of home bias $ \omega =0.57$ and the size of the tradable sector $ \gamma =0.38$ to match (i) a steady state import share of 15% (corresponding to the average within-eurozone import share for France, Germany, Italy, and Spain) and (ii) a steady state output share of 38% in manufacturing (from the EU-KLEMS database). We set the elasticity of substitution between tradable and non-tradable goods $ \epsilon $ equal to 0.5, consistent with the estimates for industrialized countries in Mendoza (1991), and the elasticity of substitution between tradable goods produced in the core and in the periphery $ \varphi $ to 1.5, as in Backus et al. (1994). Finally, the probabilities of not being able to reset prices and wages in any given quarter ($ \xi _{p}$ and $ \xi _{w}$, respectively) equal 0.66, implying an average frequency of price and wages changes of 3 quarters. We assume that the ECB targets zero inflation ( $ \bar{\Pi}=1$) and consider an effective lower bound of the short term interest rate of 1%, annualized consistent with the evidence that the ECB has been resistant to lower nominal rates below that threshold throughout the crisis.14


4  The Effects of Structural Reforms in Normal Times

We begin our analysis by investigating the consequences of structural reforms in normal times. Specifically, we study the effects of a permanent reduction in the tax component of steady-state price and wage markups by one percentage point in the periphery non-tradable sector. Figure 5 presents the dynamics of the main economic variables following the implementation of these reforms.

Figure 5: Response of Output, Inflation, and Sectoral Output

Data for Figure 5 immediately follows

Response of output (top-left), inflation (top-right), sectoral output (middle-left), sectoral inflation (middle-right), interest rates (bottom-left) and international variables (bottom-right) to a permanent increase in labor and product market subsidies by one percentage point.

Data for Figure 5: Panel 1. Output

 UnionHome Foreign
10.000.000.00
22.131.992.27
31.131.131.14
40.670.750.59
50.460.600.31
60.350.530.17
70.300.510.10
80.280.500.06
90.270.500.04
100.260.500.03
110.260.500.02
120.260.500.02
130.260.500.02
140.260.500.02
150.260.500.02
160.260.500.02
170.260.500.02
180.260.500.02
190.260.500.02
200.260.490.02

Data for Figure 5: Panel 2. Inflation

 UnionHome Foreign
10.000.000.00
2-0.20-0.690.28
3-0.10-0.430.24
4-0.05-0.270.18
5-0.02-0.170.13
6-0.01-0.110.09
70.00-0.070.06
80.00-0.040.04
90.00-0.030.02
100.00-0.020.01
110.00-0.010.01
120.000.000.00
130.000.000.00
140.000.000.00
150.000.000.00
160.000.000.00
170.000.000.00
180.000.000.00
190.000.000.00
200.000.000.00

Data for Figure 5: Panel 3. Sectoral Output

 T_HNT_HT_FNT_F
10.000.000.000.00
22.061.952.092.36
31.081.171.031.19
40.630.850.520.61
50.430.720.260.31
60.330.680.140.16
70.290.680.070.08
80.260.680.040.04
90.250.680.020.01
100.240.690.010.00
110.240.690.00-0.01
120.240.690.00-0.01
130.230.690.00-0.01
140.230.690.00-0.01
150.230.690.00-0.01
160.230.690.00-0.01
170.230.690.00-0.01
180.220.69-0.010.00
190.220.69-0.010.00
200.220.69-0.010.00

Data for Figure 5: Panel 4. Sectoral Inflation

 T_HNT_HT_FNT_F
10.000.000.000.00
20.16-1.180.180.34
30.13-0.750.150.28
40.10-0.480.120.21
50.08-0.320.090.15
60.06-0.210.070.10
70.04-0.140.050.07
80.03-0.090.040.04
90.03-0.060.030.02
100.02-0.040.020.01
110.02-0.020.020.00
120.01-0.010.010.00
130.01-0.010.010.00
140.01-0.010.01-0.01
150.010.000.01-0.01
160.010.000.01-0.01
170.010.000.01-0.01
180.010.000.01-0.01
190.010.000.01-0.01
200.010.000.01-0.01

Data for Figure 5: Panel 5. Interest Rate

 NominalReal
14.044.04
21.982.07
33.073.12
43.583.61
53.833.84
63.943.94
73.993.99
84.024.02
94.034.03
104.034.03
114.044.04
124.044.04
134.044.04
144.044.04
154.044.04
164.044.04
174.044.04
184.044.04
194.044.04
204.044.04

Data for Figure 5: Panel 6. International Variables

 RERTOTCA
10.000.000.00
20.240.040.10
30.410.070.06
40.520.100.04
50.600.120.02
60.650.130.01
70.680.140.01
80.700.140.00
90.720.150.00
100.720.150.00
110.730.150.00
120.730.150.00
130.730.150.00
140.730.140.00
150.730.140.00
160.730.140.00
170.730.140.00
180.730.140.00
190.730.140.00
200.720.140.00

In response to lower markups in the non-tradable sector, peripheral output sharply expands on impact and subsequently decreases before converging to a higher long-run steady state (top-left panel). Trade linkages between the two regions of the monetary union propagate this expansion in the periphery through higher demand for goods produced in the core, thus stimulating a large short-run increase of output in the core. Overall, output in the monetary union expands almost 2.5% in the near term and the price level declines a touch, as deflation in the periphery outweighs the modest demand-driven increase of prices in the core (top-right panel). Crucially, the common central bank accommodates the effects of structural reforms by lowering policy rates (bottom-left panel).

As for developments across sectors, lower markups in the non-tradable sector generate a sizeable short-term increase of non-tradable and tradable output in the periphery as well as in the core country (middle-left panel). Lower markups also induce a decline of non-tradable prices but an increase in the price of tradable goods as well as of prices indices in the core country (middle-right panel). International relative prices in the periphery depreciate, but most of the movement in the real exchange rate ( $ RER_t \equiv P^*_t/P_t$) is accounted for by changes in the relative price of nontradables, whereas changes in the terms of trade ( $ TOT_t \equiv P_{Ft}/P_{Ht}=P^*_{Ft}/P^*_{Ht}$) are comparatively small (bottom-right panel). The same panel also shows that the current account ( $ CA_t \equiv b_t - b_{t-1}$, where $ b_t \equiv B_t/P_t$) responds little to structural reforms, as permanent changes in the income of the periphery reduce the incentive to smooth consumption through the trade balance.

In the long run, this one-percentage point reduction in price and wage markups implemented by the periphery increases domestic output by 0.56%. This gain mostly reflects the permanent expansion of production in the non-tradable sector. Notwithstanding the modest size of the reforms considered, measures of competitiveness typically observed by policymakers improve substantially, with the real exchange rate in the periphery depreciating by 0.85% in the long run. The relative price of nontradables drives the depreciation, whereas the terms of trade only accounts for about 20% of the total adjustment in the real exchange rate.

While the dynamics explicitly take into account the non-linearities of the model, the steady state effects are approximately log-linear. Therefore, the numbers just reported can be interpreted as elasticities. For example, permanent reduction in markups by 10 percentage points increases output in the domestic country by about 5.5% and depreciates its real exchange rate by about 8.5%. This finding, which is consistent with other studies in the literature (Bayoumi et al., 2004; Forni et al., 2010), supports the policy prescription that higher competition in product and labor markets can generate sizable permanent gains in peripheral countries'output, possibly boosting their near-term growth prospects as well through substantial wealth effects.


5  The Effects of Structural Reforms in a Crisis

We next investigate how the short-run transmission mechanism of structural reforms changes in the presence of the ZLB constraint. The motivation for this analysis is twofold. First, a legacy of the 2008-09 global financial crisis is that policy rates have been at the ZLB in many countries for several years. This development has prompted a large debate on the role of alternative policies at the ZLB, the impact of the ZLB on the recovery, and the ability of monetary policy to deal with unexpected adverse events (such as the European debt crisis). Second, a growing literature finds that the effects of shocks in the presence of the ZLB can be qualitatively and quantitatively very different than in normal circumstances. For instance, Erceg and Linde (2012) find that tax-based fiscal consolidations may entail lower output losses in the short run than expenditure-based fiscal consolidations, thus overturning findings previously established in the literature (see, for instance, ALesina and Ardagna, 2010). Closer to our work, Eggertsson (2012) argues that a temporary increase in the monopoly power of firms and unions helped the U.S. recovery during the Great Depression by relaxing the ZLB constraint on monetary policy. This result is in contrast with the conventional wisdom that these policies increased the persistence of the recession (see, for instance, Cole and Ohanian, 2004).

5.1  The Crisis and the ZLB

Figure 6: Crisis

Data for Figure 6 immediately follows

Response of output (top-left), inflation (top-right), nominal interest rates (bottom-left) and real interest rate (bottom-right) to the crisis.

Data for Figure 6

 GDP InflationNom Int RateReal Int Rate
10.000.004.044.04
2-4.00-0.931.001.86
3-3.10-0.861.001.75
4-2.35-0.751.001.64
5-1.74-0.631.001.53
6-1.27-0.531.001.45
7-0.92-0.451.001.38
8-0.69-0.381.001.34
9-0.56-0.331.001.30
10-0.51-0.301.001.28
11-0.55-0.281.211.48
12-0.55-0.261.391.64
13-0.54-0.251.541.77
14-0.53-0.241.671.89
15-0.50-0.221.792.01
16-0.48-0.211.912.11
17-0.46-0.202.012.21
18-0.44-0.192.122.30
19-0.42-0.182.212.39
20-0.40-0.172.302.47

In our crisis scenarios, we follow the recent literature (see, for example, Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003) and assume that an aggregate preference shock hits the monetary union, depressing output and generating deflation. The common central bank attempts to provide monetary stimulus, but the ZLB constraint prevents it from completely offsetting the recession.

Figure 6 displays the impact of the crisis. We calibrate the size of the shock so that we can reproduce the peak-to-trough decline of euro-area output of about 4% following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 (top-left panel). Interestingly, under our baseline calibration, prices drop nearly 1% (top-right panel), in line with the data. The central bank immediately cuts the nominal interest rate to its effective lower bound of 1% and keeps this accommodative stance for 10 quarters (bottom-left panel). The crisis' deflationary pressures, combined with the lower bound constraint, imply that the real interest rate remains relatively high (bottom-right panel).15

Having described the crisis environment, we next study the response of the economy to structural reforms considered in Section 4.

5.2  The Effects of Structural Reforms at the ZLB

Table 3: Impact effects of structural reforms at the ZLB

$ \tau _{N}^{p}=\tau _{N}^{w}$ (in p.p.) Output Inflation Real Rate
0 -4.00 -0.93 1.86
1 -4.13 -1.47 2.22
5 -4.56 -3.59 3.56
10 -5.07 -6.25 5.13

Note: Response (in %) to a permanent reduction in price and wage markups in the periphery non-tradable sector.

Table 3 summarizes the main findings of our analysis. As shown in the first column, we consider permanent structural reforms in the periphery's non-tradable sector ranging from no change in labor and product market markups (crisis scenario) to a 10 percentage point reduction in both markups (crisis scenario + ambitious reforms). The last three columns of the table present the impact response of union-wide output (second column), prices (third column), and the real interest rate (fourth column) to these policy experiments. Amid contracting output and falling prices due to the crisis, the implementation of reforms in a ZLB environment further reduces aggregate output between 13 basis points (in the case of a 1 percentage point markup reduction) and 1.07 percentage points (in the case of a markup reduction of 10 percentage points).

The fall in periphery output primarily explains the union-wide contraction. In the periphery, production collapses both in the tradable and non-tradable sector. As marginal costs decrease, firms in the non-tradable sector cut prices, thus worsening the deflationary pressures associated with the crisis and contributing to an increase in the real interest rate. This effect slows down demand even further, with consequences also for the tradable sectors of both countries. Conversely, core aggregate production is roughly unchanged. In that region, the slowdown in tradables is approximately compensated by an increase in the production of nontradables, driven by a favorable adjustment in relative prices.

The short-run perverse effects of reforms are quantitatively even more remarkable when compared to the standard effects of reforms in normal times. A markup reduction by one percentage point generates an increase in union output of about 2.5% in normal times (see Figure 5 above), but an output drop of 13 basis points in a crisis. This change in the sign of the output response suggests that the short-run transmission of structural reforms critically depends on the ability of monetary policy to provide stimulus. When the ZLB constrains monetary policy, the income and substitution effects of reforms may work in opposite directions. On the one hand, agents anticipate that income will be permanently higher, resulting in strong wealth effects and higher consumption. On the other hand, these policies stimulate production and competitiveness through lower domestic prices that result in higher real interest rates. While in normal times the central bank accommodates deflation by reducing the policy rate, higher real rates at the ZLB further depress consumption and output. Not surprisingly, more ambitious reform efforts are associated with a deeper output contraction as deflationary pressures become even more acute.

Figure 7: Effects of Reforms in Crisis

Data for Figure 7 immediately follows

Response of output (top-left), inflation (top-right), nominal interest rates (bottom-left) and real interest rate (bottom-right) to the crisis without reforms (continuous black line) and with a permanent increase in labor and product market subsidies by one percentage point (dashed blue line).

Data for Figure 7

 GDPInflationNom Int RateReal Int Rate
10.000.004.044.04
2-4.14-1.471.002.22
3-3.07-1.211.001.98
4-2.20-0.981.001.79
5-1.52-0.781.001.63
6-1.00-0.621.001.51
7-0.63-0.501.001.42
8-0.38-0.411.001.35
9-0.23-0.351.001.31
10-0.18-0.311.001.29
11-0.22-0.291.171.44
12-0.25-0.271.371.62
13-0.25-0.251.531.76
14-0.23-0.241.671.89
15-0.21-0.221.792.00
16-0.19-0.211.912.11
17-0.17-0.202.012.21
18-0.15-0.192.122.30
19-0.13-0.182.212.39
20-0.11-0.172.302.47

Granted, the long-run benefits of structural reforms remain unchanged, and union-wide output improves relative to the crisis after a few quarters (Figure 7). Yet, in the short run, structural reforms do not contribute to alleviate the consequences of a deep crisis. The main point of the paper, on which we elaborate in the next section, is not to deny the long-term gains associated with these reforms. In contrast, our analysis underscores that, absent the appropriate monetary stimulus, ambitious reforms may be detrimental for the near-term growth prospects of vulnerable euro-area countries, contrary to what is often advocated in policy and academic environments.

5.3  The Effects of Temporary Reforms at the ZLB

Under our baseline calibration (as well as in several robustness checks discussed in the next subsection), permanent reforms at the ZLB do not contribute to support economic activity in the immediate aftermath of a demand-driven crisis. In practice, other impediments--such as social unrest, political economy considerations, reallocation of factors across sectors, uncertainty about the implementation and gains of reforms--may actually exacerbate the short-term costs of reforms and limit their long-term benefits. The Greek and Spanish strikes over the recent austerity measures, as well as the pledge of some parties to undo the labor market reforms undertaken by the technocratic government during the 2013 elections in Italy, are clear examples of these issues.

We model these complex socio-political dynamics by considering an experiment in which the reforms are perceived as (and in fact turn out to be) temporary. Governments in the periphery implement labor and product market reforms as the crisis hits. However, the short-run costs in terms of deflation and the absence of output gains lead to social unrest and imply that the reforms are eventually undone. We make the simplifying assumptions that this outcome is perfectly anticipated at the time of implementation and the reforms are unwound when the ZLB stops binding.16

Figure 8: Effects of Temporary Reforms in Crisis

Data for Figure 8 immediately follows

Response of output (top-left), inflation (top-right), nominal interest rates (bottom-left) and real interest rate (bottom-right) to the crisis without reforms (continuous black line) and with a temporary increase in labor and product market subsidies by one percentage point (dashed blue line).

Data for Figure 8

 GDPInflationNom Int RateReal Int Rate
10.000.004.044.04
2-7.37-2.501.003.20
3-5.88-2.181.002.87
4-4.62-1.861.002.57
5-3.58-1.561.002.30
6-2.75-1.291.002.07
7-2.11-1.061.001.87
8-1.64-0.871.001.70
9-1.33-0.701.001.54
10-1.17-0.541.001.38
11-1.16-0.371.001.19
12-1.31-0.192.172.39
13-0.93-0.211.922.13
14-0.73-0.221.852.07
15-0.63-0.211.882.09
16-0.56-0.211.952.15
17-0.52-0.202.042.23
18-0.49-0.192.132.31
19-0.46-0.182.222.39
20-0.44-0.172.312.47

Figure 8 compares the response of output (top-left panel), inflation (top-right panel), the nominal interest rate (bottom-left panel) and the real interest rate (bottom-right panel) to the crisis without reforms (continuous black line) against the case of a temporary reduction in labor and product market markups by one percentage point (dashed blue line).

When monetary policy is constrained by the ZLB, temporary reforms entail large output losses in the short-run. At the union level, output drops by 7.4% on impact, almost doubling the output costs associated with the crisis. As in the case of permanent reforms, reducing markups increases the deflationary pressures generated by the crisis. However, the temporary nature of the reforms creates much more severe short-run deflationary pressures. This result reflects two mechanisms. First, as in the case of permanent reforms, lower prices increase the short-term real interest rate. However, temporary reforms are associated with much smaller wealth effects as long-run output is unchanged, thus providing stronger incentives for agents to postpone their consumption. Second, households understand that the eventual unwinding of reforms (i.e. higher markups) when the crisis has almost completely vanished will have inflationary consequences, triggering a sharp increase in the nominal and real interest rate. Anticipating the future tightening, aggregate demand contracts immediately, contributing to a deeper crisis. This effect adds to the initial deflationary pressures and creates a perverse feedback loop, as the real interest rate further increases. Moreover, the economy suffers a policy-induced double-dip recession when the ZLB stops binding. Under temporary reforms, the absence of long-run wealth effects together with higher short-run output losses imply that, differently from the case of permanent reforms, the periphery borrows from abroad and runs a current account deficit (not shown).

In sum, our experiments suggest that when monetary policy is at the ZLB, ambitious and credible structural reforms may have undesirable short-run effects. In addition, when political economy factors, such as electoral outcomes and social unrest, undermine the credibility of the reforms and cast doubts on their long-lasting impact, these perverse effects are likely to be magnified.

5.4  Robustness

In this section, we briefly discuss the sensitivity of the perverse effects of structural reforms at the ZLB to three factors, namely the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, the size of the economy implementing the reforms, and the nature of the shock generating the crisis.17

Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution. An important parameter governing the short-run response of consumption to changes in the real interest rate is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution ( $ \sigma ^{-1}$ ). As shown in Table 2, in our benchmark calibration we set $ \sigma =0.5$, implying that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is above one$ .$ Although several authors provide evidence in support of our calibration (Hansen and Singleton, 1983; Summers, 1984; Attanasio and Weber, 1989; Rotembert and Woodford, 1997; Gruber, 2006), other macroeconomists would consider such a value for $ \sigma $ as a low estimate for this parameter (Hall, 1988). Thus, given the disagreement on the appropriate value for the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in the literature, we repeat our simulations with $ \sigma =1$ and $ 2$.18 A smaller elasticity of intertemporal substitution implies a smaller negative output effect of permanent reforms in the short run. Moreover, and contrary to our benchmark results, larger reforms lead to smaller output losses. Yet, when $ \sigma =2$, a permanent reduction in labor and product markups by 10 percentage points (our most ambitious reforms considered in Table 3) still leads to output gains of only 0.6 percentage point relative to the crisis scenario. Given the size of the reforms, these gains are quite small, especially if compared to the 25% output increase experienced in normal times, pointing once again to the critical role played by (the lack of) monetary policy accommodation for the short-run transmission of reforms.

Country Size. The effects of reforms during crisis times are robust to changes in country size. Our calibration assumes that the currency union consists of two equal-sized regions, which represents a good approximation to the relative weight of core and peripheral countries in the EMU.19 Our experiments reflect the idea that all peripheral countries are currently being encouraged to implement ambitious reform programs. In practice, however, the implementation of reforms may occur at different times in each country. To check if the size of the country that implements the reforms matters for our results, we run simulations assuming that the periphery country accounts for only 10% of union-wide output.20

Perhaps not surprisingly, the main difference relative to the symmetric case is the smaller output decline experienced by the union as a whole. However, this difference simply reflects the smaller weight of the periphery in aggregate variables. The relevant real interest rate for the consumption decisions of the representative household in the periphery is a function of the nominal interest rate set by the common monetary authority, which is at the ZLB during the crisis, and the periphery's CPI inflation rate, which is approximately independent of the country size.21 Structural reforms that make the non-tradable sector in the periphery more competitive impact the domestic CPI almost identically, no matter whether the periphery is large or small. Therefore, the additional output contraction in the periphery due to the reforms compared to the crisis scenario remains essentially unaffected.

Asymmetric Shock. In our main experiment, we considered the crisis as a shock that hits symmetrically both countries in the currency union. However, the recovery from the global financial crisis in core and peripheral European countries reveals a great deal of asymmetry between the two regions, perhaps reflecting the "macroeconomic imbalances" accumulated in the early 2000s.

Motivated by this observation, we investigate the robustness of our main findings to a crisis shock that is not symmetric. We consider a scenario where the shock only hits the periphery. As in the previous exercise, we continue to calibrate the shock to match a 4% decline in union-wide output. This crisis is still associated with the nominal interest rate stuck at the ZLB for about three years. We then study the effects of structural reforms implemented in the periphery in the context of this crisis.

The main difference in case of an asymmetric shock is the large adjustment in international variables. The periphery runs a large current account surplus and the terms of trade significantly contributes to the depreciation of the real exchange rate. However, these movements primarily reflect the asymmetric nature of the crisis shock and occur also in the absence of structural reforms.

That said, structural reforms that permanently reduce product and labor market markups in the periphery continue to be contractionary in the short run, as more protracted deflation at the ZLB results in higher real interest rates. With an asymmetric crisis, the magnitudes of the additional output losses is smaller--twenty basis points in the case of a 10 percentage points reduction in markups. Yet, our main conclusion is qualitatively unchanged.


6  Disentangling the Effects of Reforms at the ZLB

So far, we have argued that the short-run transmission of reforms depends critically on the ability of the central bank to provide monetary policy accommodation. In normal times, the nominal interest rate falls, providing stimulus against deflationary pressures. However, in a severe crisis, whereby the central bank runs into the ZLB constraint, the deflationary pressures associated with structural reforms lead to higher real rates and further depress economic activity. In this section, we consider two experiments that shed light on the mechanism behind these findings.

In the first experiment, which we label "New Deal," we assume that the government sets $ \tau _{Nt}^{p}$ and $ \tau _{Nt}^{w}$ to temporarily increase the monopolistic power of firms and unions. This experiment is in the spirit of Eggertsson (2012), who claims that policies of this kind contributed to end the Great Depression, or can be interpreted as an application of unconventional fiscal policies that provide monetary stimulus at the ZLB as in Correia et al. (2013).22 In essence, this policy aims at generating expectations of price increases in the short run without any implication for the long-run level of output. Thus, we interpret this experiment as isolating the substitution effect associated with expectations of higher prices at the ZLB.

In our simulations, the government increases distortionary taxes on firms and workers as long as the "shadow" nominal interest rate (i.e. the nominal interest rate absent the ZLB constraint) stays in negative territory

$\displaystyle \tau _{t}^{p}=\tau _{t}^{w}=\tau _{t}^{nd}=-\min \left\{ 0,\phi _{\tau } \left[ (1+i)\left( \Pi _{t}^{MU}\right) ^{\varphi _{\pi }}-1\right] \right\} ,$    

where $ \phi _{\tau }>0$ is a parameter that controls how aggressively the government increases the taxes in response to the crisis.23

Our second experiment, which we label "Delay" , aims at retaining the long-run benefits of structural reforms without imposing the short-run costs in terms of deflation. Thus, we interpret this experiment as isolating the wealth effect associated with expectations of higher permanent income at the ZLB.

When the crisis hits, the government (credibly) announces that it will implement structural reforms when the ZLB stops binding

$\displaystyle \tau _{t}^{p}=\tau _{t}^{w}=\tau _{t}^{d}=-\max \left\{ 0,\tau \left[ (1+i)\left( \Pi _{t}^{MU}\right) ^{\varphi _{\pi }}-1\right] /i\right\} .$    

The Delay rule differs from the New Deal rule because the permanent change in the tax needs to be consistent with the final steady state. Therefore, the coefficient $ \phi _{\tau }$ is constrained to be equal to $ \tau /i$.

The idea that news about future supply increases may stimulate subdued aggregate demand in an economy facing a liquidity trap is not new. In their discussion about the Japanese ZLB experience of the late 1990s, Krugman (1998) argues that an expected drop in productivity due to population aging contributed to the persistence of the ZLB, while Rogoff (1998) suggests that future productivity gains ought to be the solution to the ZLB constraint. More recently, Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2012) formalize this argument in a two-period New-Keynesian model. Our Delay policy can be interpreted as a state-contingent application of these arguments.

Figure 9: Disentangling the Effects of Reforms in Crisis

Data for Figure 9 immediately follows

Response of output (top-left), inflation (top-right), nominal interest rate (middle-left), real interest rate (middle-right), real exchange rate (bottom-left) and current account (bottom-right) in the crisis without reforms (continuous black line), under the "new deal" rule (dashed blue line) and under the "delay" rule (dashed-dotted red line).

Data for Figure 9: Crisis

 GDPGDP %InflationNom Int RateReal Int RateRERCA
10.400.000.004.044.040.000.00
20.39-4.00-0.931.001.860.000.00
30.39-3.10-0.861.001.750.000.00
40.39-2.35-0.751.001.640.000.00
50.40-1.74-0.631.001.530.000.00
60.40-1.27-0.531.001.450.000.00
70.40-0.92-0.451.001.380.000.00
80.40-0.69-0.381.001.340.000.00
90.40-0.56-0.331.001.300.000.00
100.40-0.51-0.301.001.280.000.00
110.40-0.55-0.281.211.480.000.00
120.40-0.55-0.261.391.640.000.00
130.40-0.54-0.251.541.770.000.00
140.40-0.53-0.241.671.890.000.00
150.40-0.50-0.221.792.010.000.00
160.40-0.48-0.211.912.110.000.00
170.40-0.46-0.202.012.210.000.00
180.40-0.44-0.192.122.300.000.00
190.40-0.42-0.182.212.390.000.00
200.40-0.40-0.172.302.470.000.00

Data for Figure 9: New Deal

 GDPInflationNom Int RateReal Int RateRERCA
10.000.004.044.040.000.00
2-2.85-0.301.001.30-0.130.00
3-2.22-0.301.001.30-0.230.00
4-1.68-0.301.001.30-0.290.00
5-1.23-0.301.001.30-0.310.00
6-0.87-0.301.001.30-0.300.00
7-0.60-0.301.001.30-0.270.00
8-0.40-0.301.001.30-0.220.00
9-0.28-0.301.001.30-0.160.00
10-0.24-0.301.001.30-0.100.00
11-0.26-0.301.001.28-0.050.00
12-0.37-0.281.201.46-0.010.00
13-0.45-0.261.451.690.010.00
14-0.47-0.241.631.850.020.00
15-0.47-0.231.771.980.030.00
16-0.46-0.211.892.100.030.00
17-0.44-0.202.012.200.030.00
18-0.43-0.192.112.290.030.00
19-0.41-0.182.212.380.030.00
20-0.39-0.172.302.470.020.00

Data for Figure 9: Delay

 GDPInflationNom Int RateReal Int RateRERCA
10.000.004.044.040.000.00
2-2.26-0.431.001.390.600.02
3-1.59-0.391.001.341.170.02
4-1.03-0.341.001.301.710.02
5-0.59-0.301.011.312.210.01
6-0.23-0.291.071.362.700.01
70.07-0.291.151.433.150.01
80.33-0.281.241.513.580.01
90.55-0.271.341.603.970.01
100.74-0.261.441.694.340.01
110.91-0.251.541.784.670.01
121.05-0.241.641.874.970.01
131.18-0.231.741.965.250.01
141.29-0.221.852.055.500.01
151.39-0.211.942.145.730.01
161.48-0.202.042.235.940.01
171.56-0.192.132.316.120.01
181.64-0.182.222.396.290.01
191.71-0.172.312.476.450.01
201.77-0.162.392.556.580.01

Figure 9 presents the response of the main variables to the New Deal policy (dashed blue line) and to the Delay policy (dashed-dotted red line). Notwithstanding the absence of monetary accommodation due to the ZLB, both policies are closer to the short-run transmission mechanism of reforms operating in normal times: On impact, output in the currency union is well above the crisis scenario and, as a consequence, the permanent reform scenario discussed in Section 5.2. Under the New Deal policy, the initial drop in output is about 2.5%, much less than the 4% contraction experienced in the absence of announced reforms. Under the Delay policy, which is calibrated to a long-run reduction in markups of 10 percentage points, the output gains are somewhat larger (although still significantly less than in normal times). In particular, output recovers from the crisis and monetary policy exits the ZLB after only six quarters.

These experiments highlight the main tradeoffs associated with the implementation of reforms at the ZLB. The New Deal policy attempts to offset the deflationary effects of the crisis by creating expectations for positive inflation through higher, albeit temporary, monopoly power. Thus, this policy operates mainly through the substitution effect of lower real interest rates and has no effect on long-run income. In the case of the Delay policy, the expectation that reforms will be permanent, though implemented in the future, generates a large wealth effect that stimulates aggregate demand, thus limiting the short-run output drop due to the crisis and supporting domestic prices.

As for the open-economy variables, the permanent effects associated with the Delay policy result in a gradual depreciation of the real exchange rate and a current account surplus, similarly to what was observed in normal times. The New Deal policy, in contrast, has very little impact on international variables. The temporary nature of this policy does not bring about any realignment in international prices or permanent gain in competitiveness. In the short-run, the real exchange rate modestly appreciates and the current account turns slightly positive. These responses reflect higher output and prices in the periphery relative to the core, where no policy is implemented.

We close this section with an important caveat. The two policies discussed in this section present serious political economy challenges. Increasing markups in a crisis may combat deflationary pressures, but the same interest groups that oppose permanent reforms in a crisis could fight to make the temporary change indeed permanent. Similarly, crises are times when external forces may render unpleasant reforms acceptable. Announcing at the beginning of a crisis that the ambitious reforms will be implemented when the ZLB stops being binding poses obvious time-inconsistencies problems. For these reasons, we interpret the "New Deal" and "Delay" policies as illustrative of the key mechanisms at play in our model, rather than normative statements on the actual implementation of structural reforms.


7  Conclusions

Structural reforms can greatly reduce the competitiveness gap between the EMU core and periphery and boost income prospects in the region. However, the timing of such reforms is crucial. If undertaken during a crisis that takes monetary policy rates to the ZLB, structural reforms can deepen the recession by worsening deflation and increasing real rates. This effect becomes even stronger if the public expects policymakers to later unwind these reforms.

Our paper contributes to the recent literature on the implications of the ZLB for the transmission of shocks. We expand on the existing results by investigating the effects of permanent markup changes at the ZLB in an open economy environment, thus focusing on the domestic and international transmission of shocks.

In addressing the effects of reforms at the ZLB, we have abstracted from important considerations that are likely to shape the policy debate in Europe. First, our analysis features only inputs of production that cannot be accumulated over time. As argued by Fernandez-Villaverde (2013) in his discussion of this paper, the presence of physical capital may in principle preserve the standard transmission mechanism of reforms. However, in their simulations, Gavin et al. (2013) find that technology shocks at the ZLB continue to have perverse effects, at least in a closed economy environment. Moreover, if physical capital (or other assets, such as housing) can relax borrowing limits through their collateral value, perverse debt-deflation dynamics at the ZLB are likely to be amplified (see, for instance, Eggertsson and Krugman, 2012). Second, while our analysis has solely focused on the short-run transmission of reforms, the policy debate in Europe involves important political economy considerations (Blanchard adn Giavazzi, 2003). The social and political opposition faced by governments in peripheral Europe to adopt relatively small reform packages in times of financial turbulence reveals the difficulties of changing these policies in practice. Our findings emphasize a relevant macroeconomic tradeoff associated with the absence of sufficient monetary policy stimulus to support reform efforts. Future research efforts could embed the pure macroeconomic forces discussed in this paper in a political economy environment, with the objective of drawing serious welfare implications.


References

Adao, B., I. Correia, and P. Teles (2009). On the Relevance of Exchange Rate Regimes for Stabilization Policy. Journal of Economic Theory 144, 1468-188.

Alesina, A. and S. Ardagna (2010). Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus Spending. In J. Brown (Ed.), Tax Policy and the Economy, Chapter 3, pp. 35-68. University of Chicago Press.

Attanasio, O. and G. Weber (1989). Intertemporal Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Euler Equation for Consumption. Economic Journal 99, 59-73.

Backus, D., P. Kehoe, and F. Kydland (1994). The Dynamics of the Trade Balance and the Terms of Trade: The J-Curve? American Economic Review 84, 84-103.

Bayoumi, T., D. Laxton, and P. Pesenti (2004). Benefits and Spillovers of Greater Competition in Europe: A Macroeconomic Assessment. NBER Working Paper 10416.

Blanchard, O. and F. Giavazzi (2003). The Macroeconomic Effects of Regulation and Deregulation in Goods and Labor Markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 879-909.

Cacciatore, M. and G. Fiori (2012). The Macroeconomic Effects of Goods and Labor Markets Deregulation. Unpublished, HEC Montreal.

Cacciatore, M., G. Fiori, and F. Ghironi (2012). Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary Union. Unpublished, HEC Montreal.

Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383-398.

Chen, R., G. M. Milesi-Ferretti, and T. Tressel (2012). External Imbalances in the Euro Area. IMF Working Paper 12/36.

Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo (2011). When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large? Journal of Political Economy 119, 78-121.

Cole, H. and L. Ohanian (2004). New Deal Policies and the Persistence of the Great Depression: A General Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Political Economy 112, 779-816.

Correia, I., E. Farhi, J. P. Nicolini, and P. Teles (2013). Unconventional Fiscal Policy at the Zero Bound. American Economic Review Forthcoming.

Corsetti, G., P. Martin, and P. Pesenti (2013). Varieties and the Transfer Problem. Journal of International Economics 89, 1-12.

Corsetti, G. and H. Pesaran (2012). Beyond Fiscal Federalism: What Does It Take to Save the Euro? http://www.voxeu.org/article/beyond-fiscal-federalism-what-will-it-take-save-euro.

Eggertsson, G. (2011). What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? In D. Acemoglu and M. Woodford (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2010, Volume 25, Chapter 2, pp. 59-112. University of Chicago Press.

Eggertsson, G. (2012). Was the New Deal Contractionary? American Economic Review 102, 524-555.

Eggertsson, G. and P. Krugman (2012). Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127, 1469-1513.

Eggertsson, G. and M. Woodford (2003). The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 34, 139-235.

Eichengreen, B. (2010). Imbalances in the Euro Area. Unpublished, University of California at Berkeley.

Erceg, C., L. Guerrieri, and C. Gust (2006). SIGMA: A New Open Economy Model for Policy Analysis. International Journal of Central Banking 2, 1-50.

Erceg, C. and J. Linde (2012). Fiscal Consolidation in an Open Economy. American Economic Review 102, 186-191.

Everaert, L. and W. Schule (2006). Structural Reforms in the Euro Area: Economic Impact and Role of Synchronization Across Markets and Countries. IMF Working Paper 06/137.

Farhi, E., G. Gopinath, and O. Itskhoki (2012). Fiscal Devaluations. Unpublished, Harvard
University.

Fernandez-Villaverde, J. (2013). Discussion of "Can Structural Reforms Help Europe?". Unpublished, University of Pennsylvania.

Fernandez-Villaverde, J., P. Guerron-Quintana, and J. Rubio-Ramirez (2012). Supply-Side Policies and the Zero Lower Bound. Unpublished, University of Pennsylvania.

Forni, L., A. Gerali, and M. Pisani (2010). Macroeconomic Effects of Greater Competition in the Service Sector: The Case of Italy. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14, 677-708.

Gaulier, G. and V. Vicard (2012). The Signatures of Euro Area Imbalances. Unpublished, Banque de France.

Gavin, W., B. Keen, A. Richter, and N. Throckmorton (2013). Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2013-007A.

Gerali, A., A. Notarpietro, and M. Pisani (2013). Potential Outout and Structural Reforms after the Crisis: The Case of Italy. Unpublished, Bank of Italy.

Gruber, J. (2006). A Tax-Based Estimate of the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution. NBER Working Paper 11945.

Hall, R. (1988). Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption. Journal of Political Economy 96, 339-357.

Hansen, L.-P. and K. Singleton (1983). Stochastic Consumption, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Asset Returns. Journal of Political Economy 91, 249-265.

Jean, S. and G. Nicoletti (2002). Product Market Regulation and Wage Premia in Europe and North America: An Empirical Investigation. OECD Economics Department Working 318.

Krugman, P. (1998). It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 137-187.

Lipinska, A. and L. von Thadden (2012). On the (In)effectiveness of Fiscal Devaluations in a Monetary Union. FEDS Working Papers 2012-71.

Mendoza, E. (1991). Real Business Cycles in a Small Open Economy. American Economic Review 81, 797-818.

Rogoff, K. (1998). Discussion of: "It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap". Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 194-199.

Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford (1997). An Optimization-Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy. In B. Bernanke and J. Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12, Chapter 6, pp. 297-361. MIT Press.

Summers, L. (1984). The After-Tax Rate of Return Affects Private Savings. American Economic Revie 74, 249-253.

World Economic Forum (2012). Global Competitiveness Report.


Footnotes

1.   Prepared for the 2013 Carnegie-NYU-Rochester Conference on "Fiscal Policy in the Presence of Debt Crises." We thank our discussants Jesus Fernadez-Villaverde, T. Braun, Anna Lipinska, and Ricardo M. Félix for insightful comments, as well as seminar participants at the Carnegie-NYU-Rochester Conference, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the Federal Reserve Board, the University of Maryland, the Spring 2013 SCIEA Meetings, the 2013 Midwest Macroeconomic Meetings, the 2013 SED Meetings, the 2013 NBER Summer Institute, the Central Bank of Hungary/CEPR/Bank of Italy Conference on "Growth, Rebalancing, and Macroeconomic Adjustment after Large Shocks," and King's College London. M. Henry Linder provided excellent research assistance. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the view of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text

2.  Corsetti and Pesaran (2012) note how inflation differentials between EMU members and Germany--effectively the rate of change of the real exchange rate--are a much more reliable proxy for interest rate differentials than sovereign debt-to-GDP differentials. To the extent that current account deficits are correlated with real exchange rate appreciations, the external balance of periphery countries is also tightly related to sovereign yield spreads. In sum, according to this view, fiscal and external imbalances, as well as the relative competitive position, are different sides of the same underlying problem (Eichengreen, 2010). Return to text

3.   The product market efficiency index is an average of the scores in the categories related to market competition, such as "Extent of market dominance" and "Effectiveness of anti-monopoly policy." The labor market efficiency index is an average of the scores in the categories related to wage flexibility, such as "Flexibility in wage determination" and "Redundancy costs in weeks of salary." See World Economic Forum (2012) for more details. Return to text

4.   OECD estimates of business markups and regulations burden paint a similar picture. We make explicit use of these estimates in our quantitative exercises. Return to text

5.   These large long-run gains are consistent with the existing literature (Bayoumi et al., 2004; Forni et al., 2010), although the exact numbers may be sensitive to the introduction of entry and exit in the product market and search and matching frictions in the labor market (Cacciatore and Fiori, 2012; Corsetti et al., 2013).  Return to text

6.  Cacciatore et al. (2012) study optimal monetary policy in a monetary union under product and labor market deregulation in a model with endogenous entry and exit and search frictions. As in our "normal times" scenario, the Ramsey plan in that setup also calls for monetary policy accommodation during the transition period. Return to text

7.   In a small open economy calibrated to Italian data, Gerali et al. (2013) find that strong complementarities between structural reforms and fiscal consolidations can give rise to substantial output benefits. Like our experiments that temporarily increase markups or announce reforms at later stages, however, political economy considerations may hinder several aspects of such a coordinated plan and reduce the combined gains of these supply-side policies. Return to text

8.   When the ZLB does not bind, the AD curve is horizontal in a zero-inflation targeting regime. Return to text

9.   Eggertsson (2010) calls this effect the "paradox of toil." His analysis, however, is restricted to temporary reforms, whereas our focus here is on the effects of permanent reforms on the equilibrium. Return to text

10.   We use the intermediation cost only to ensure stationarity of the net foreign asset position. We set the parameter $ \psi _{B}$ small enough as to have no discernible effects on the transition dynamics. Return to text

11.   This definition is the model-equivalent of the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP), the measure of consumer prices published by Eurostat. Return to text

12.   We perform our simulations using Dynare, which relies on a Newton-Rapson algorithm to compute non-linear transitions between an initial point and the final steady state. Return to text

13.  Bayoumi et al. (2004) and Forni et al. (2010) follow a similar calibration strategy. Return to text

14.   The exact level of either the inflation target or the bound on the interest rate is not central for our results. What we need is that a lower bound for the policy rate exists, thus preventing the monetary authority from providing additional stimulus. To implement the zero-inflation targeting regime in the simulations, we assume the policy reaction function
$\displaystyle 1+i_{t}=\max \left\{ 1+i^{zlb},(1+i)(\Pi _{t}^{MU})^{\varphi _{\pi }}\right\} ,$
where $ \varphi _{\pi }>1$ is the feedback coefficient on inflation and $ i^{zlb}\geq 0$ is the effective lower bound for the interest rate. A high enough value for $ \varphi _{\pi }$ approximates a zero-inflation targeting regime well. We set $ \varphi _{\pi }=10$, although higher values would make no difference. Lower values can still approximate a zero-inflation targeting in the model if we were to assume that the ECB also responds to the output gap and/or the natural rate of interest. Return to text

15.   The real interest rate is high relative to a counterfactual world in which the nominal interest rate could go below its lower bound, and possibly into negative territory. Return to text

16.   These assumptions, while obviously extreme, make the analysis particularly stark. More realistically, the unwinding may occur with some probability at time of implementation, which would likely lead to a smaller output drop. At the same time, the unwinding may be decoupled from the duration of the crisis--in particular, the reforms could be reversed a few quarters after the ZLB stops being binding--which would entail more severe output losses. Return to text

17.   Tables and figures associated with these experiments are available upon request. Return to text

18.   In each experiment, we recalibrate the size of the preference shock to ensure that aggregate output contracts 4% in the crisis episode. Return to text

19.   In the data, Italy and Spain account for 17% and 12% of euro-area output, respectively, whereas Greece, Ireland, and Portugal each account for about 2% of total output. Thus, peripheral countries account for about 35% of euro-area output in total. Return to text

20.   In this experiment, we adjust the parameters governing home bias $ \omega $ and the share of tradable goods $ \gamma $ to match the same targets as in the benchmark simulation. Return to text

21.   Country size may have an indirect effect on the domestic CPI via the terms of trade. Return to text

22.   Given the severe fiscal constraints faced by peripheral countries and the lack of exchange rate flexibility, a recent academic literature (see Adao et al., 2009; Farhi et al., 2012) has focused on the scope for fiscal devaluations, that is, revenue-neutral changes in the composition of taxes that mimic an exchange rate devaluation. However, quantitatively, the potential gains associated with these policies for reasonable changes in tax rates appear to be limited (Lipinska and von Thadden, 2012). Return to text

23.   We calibrate the parameter $ \phi _{\tau }$ in the New Deal policy to minimize deflation on impact. Qualitatively, a constant increase in taxes would achieve the same objective as the state-contingent rule. However, if taxes remain high for too long, the nominal interest rate may endogenously spike up even if the crisis is not over yet. Return to text



This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text

Home | Economic research and data | Publications and education resources
Accessibility | Contact us
Last update: April 24, 2014