The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2007-67 Screen Reader version

Nominal Mortgage Contracts and the Effects of Inflation on Portfolio Allocation

Joseph B. Nichols*
JEL Classification Codes: E21, G11, G21, R21, C61
March 2007

Keywords: Mortgages, inflation, portfolio allocation, life-cycle

Abstract:

Households who wish to extract home equity through refinancing their mortgage face a hidden transaction cost. The real value of the fixed nominal mortgage payment declines over time with inflation. The change in the real value of the mortgage payments from taking on a new mortgage is positive and an increasing function of inflation; higher inflation thus discourages households from re-balancing their portfolio as frequently as they would otherwise. The life cycle model developed in this paper demonstrates how the share of total wealth held in housing is sensitive to the rate of inflation, even when perfectly anticipated. Households hold larger positions in home equity earlier in the life cycle and smaller positions later in the life cycle as the rate of inflation increases.


1 Introduction

Housing wealth represents a significant share of most households total wealth. Flavin and Yamashita (2002) used the Panel Study of Income Dynamics to show that among homeowner households with a head between 18 and 30 years old, 67.8% of their portfolio is in their home. A common explanation for this concentration is that private homes are "lumpy" assets and households face significant transaction costs in extracting home equity through refinancing their mortgages. Generally, these transaction costs represent loan fees, realtor fees, and the time cost associated with the transaction. This paper explores a hidden, yet significant potential further source of transaction costs associated with mortgages with fixed nominal payments, and then shows how this cost is sensitive to inflation, even when that inflation is perfectly anticipated.

Those who examine the effects of inflation on the real macroeconomy commonly assume that prices are "sticky." Sticky prices are usually taken to be wages controlled by long-term contracts and prices of goods and services. These examples overlook perhaps one of the stickiest of prices: the recurring payments specified in many mortgage contracts, which are fixed in nominal terms for up to thirty years, regardless of changes in the level of inflation.

A key price held constant for so long has important effects on the investment behavior of homeowners over the life cycle. Given inflation, the real value of a fixed nominal mortgage payment declines over the life of a mortgage contract, while the payment on a new comparable mortgage payment increases in line with inflation. The gap between the old and new real mortgage payment does not depend on higher mortgage interest rates or larger real mortgage balances, but are a direct result of the declining real value of the fixed nominal mortgage payment from the original mortgage. This hidden transaction costs discourages households from more frequent re-balancing of their total portfolio by shifting assets from home equity into financial assets.

With about 70 percent of homeowners having a mortgage on their primary residence (Bucks, Kennickell, and Moore, 2006), housing wealth cannot be realistically modeled using a single state variable, as can holdings of a standard risky or risk-free financial asset. The model must also allow for the terms of the mortgage contract. The second section of this paper describes the household's choice where housing wealth is assumed to consist of three connected components: an asset, a liability, and a contract for a stream of recurring payments. In a standard fixed-rate self-amortizing mortgage, the recurring payments for the principal and interest are fixed at a nominal level for the life of the loan, even as the real value falls. I show that under certain specific, but not terribly binding, assumptions, a household who later refinances at the same mortgage interest rate, will face an increase in the real value of the recurring mortgage payment.

Starting in the third section of this paper, a detailed partial-equilibrium life cycle model with an explicit mortgage contract is developed. The model captures household saving and consumption decisions over the life cycle in an environment with several important features of the U.S. homeownership system. In particular, it allows for a transition in tenure from renter to owner, and for households to increase or decrease their consumption of housing by trading up to a larger home or trading down to a smaller home. Households also have access to a standard thirty-year fixed-rate self-amortizing mortgage to purchase their homes and have the opportunity to tap their home equity through refinancing their mortgages. This paper does not represent a serious attempt to formally calibrate a model of housing wealth or to estimate the maximum likelihood parameters of such a model. The goal is rather to see how closely the model can match certain stylized facts while using fairly standard and common parameter values used in the related literature.

The model's solution is used to demonstrate how an inflation rate that is perfectly anticipated and unchanging over the life cycle affects the household's portfolio allocation by increasing the transaction costs associated with shifting assets from housing to financial assets. The model is solved for different inflation rates and also for a case in which the mortgage contract is in real and not nominal terms. The results suggest that, the higher rate of inflation (that is, when the hidden cost to refinancing is higher), households hold larger positions in home equity earlier in the life cycle, and smaller positions later in the life cycle. The results also help explains why retired households hold such a significant portion of their wealth in housing.


2 Theoretical Model

This section lays out the theoretical justification behind the main conclusion of the paper: the nature of a standard fixed-rate mortgage contract implies that the cost of re-balancing a household's portfolio between housing and financial wealth is an increasing function of inflation, even when that inflation is perfectly anticipated. The assumptions underlying the theorems presented in this section are that the household invests  \alpha_0 of their total wealth at time 0,  W_0, in a financial asset  A_0, and uses the remainder,  1-\alpha_0, as a down payment on a house. Given a required down payment rate of  \mu, the value of the house,  P_0 is  \frac{(1-\alpha_0)W_0}{\mu}.

Theorem 2.1   As long as the total return on housing over the holding period is positive, the share of wealth held in the financial asset will decline over the holding period.
Proof. After  t years the value of the financial portfolio, the house, and the remaining mortgage balance are respectively,
  \displaystyle A_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle \alpha_0 W_0 (1+\eta_s)^t
  \displaystyle P_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{(1-\alpha_0)W_0}{\mu}(1+\eta_h)^t
  \displaystyle D_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{(1-\alpha_0)(1-\mu)W_0}{\mu}\right)\left( \frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right)

where  (1+\eta_s)^t and  (1+\eta_h)^t are the total rates of return on the financial asset and housing over the holding period,  \nu is the mortgage interest rate, and  \pi is the inflation rate. Note that the mortgage balance is in nominal terms, and must be adjusted using the rate of inflation.

The new value of the portfolio share of the financial asset is

  \displaystyle \alpha_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{A_t}{A_t+P_t-D_t}
    \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\alpha_0 W_0 (1+\eta_s)^t}{\alpha_0 W_0 (1+\eta_s)^t+\frac{(1-\alpha_0)W_0}{\mu}(1+\eta_h)^t-\left(\frac{(1-\alpha_0)(1-\mu)W_0}{\mu}\right) \left(\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right)}
    \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{(1+\eta_s)^t}{(1+\eta_s)^t + \frac{1-\alpha_0}{\alpha_0 \mu}\left((1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right)}
    \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{1}{1 + \frac{1-\alpha_0}{\alpha_0 \mu (1+\eta_s)^t}\left((1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right)}

The theorem holds if,

  \displaystyle \alpha_t \displaystyle < \displaystyle \alpha_0
  \displaystyle \frac{1}{1 + \frac{1-\alpha_0}{\alpha_0 \mu (1+\eta_s)^t}\left((1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right)} \displaystyle < \displaystyle \alpha_0
  \displaystyle \alpha_0 + \frac{1-\alpha_0}{\mu (1+\eta_s)^t}\left( (1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right) \displaystyle > \displaystyle 1
  \displaystyle \alpha_0 \mu (1+\eta_s)^t + (1-\alpha_0)\left((1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right) \displaystyle > \displaystyle \mu (1+\eta_s)^t
  \displaystyle (1-\alpha_0)\left( (1+\eta_h)^t - (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}\right) \displaystyle > \displaystyle (1 - \alpha_0)\mu (1+\eta_s)^t
  \displaystyle \mu (1+\eta_s)^t + (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t} \displaystyle < \displaystyle (1+\eta_h)^t

The balance on a self-amortizing mortgage begins at the starting value of the loan and slowly trends to zero over the life of the mortgage. Therefore,

    \displaystyle \frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}} = 1, \quad when \quad t=0 \notag

and is decreasing in  t.

Therefore,

    \displaystyle (1+\eta_h)^t > \mu (1+\eta_s)^t + (1-\mu)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t} \rightarrow \alpha_0 > \alpha_t \notag

 \qedsymbol

The first term on the right-hand side of the inequality above is the total return on the financial asset discounted by the fraction of the initial home value the household puts up as a down payment. The second term is bounded above by the initial loan-to-value ratio, and is decreasing over time. If the household forgoes mortgage financing, and pays the full home value up-front ( \mu = 1), the above condition holds only if the total return on housing is greater than the total return on financial assets. At the other extreme, if the household puts no-money down ( \mu = 0), the condition holds if the total return on housing does not fall below the rate of amortization. This conclusion is hardly counter-intuitive. Given that power of leveraging granted by the mortgage combined with the ongoing paying down of the mortgage balance, households will over time slowly decrease the share of their wealth in the financial asset and increase the share held in home equity over time.

The key contribution of this paper, as laid out in the following theorem, is that the costs associated with extracting accumulated home equity is an increasing function of inflation.

Theorem 2.2   A household that refinances its existing home in order to re-balance its portfolio between home equity and financial assets will face higher real mortgage payments as long as the total return on the financial asset does not exceed the leveraged total return on housing.
Proof. After  t years the household refinances its house, and puts  (1-\alpha_0)(A_t+P_t-D_t) back into home equity. The new mortgage balance is
  \displaystyle D_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle P_t-(1-\alpha_0)(A_t+P_t-D_t)
  \displaystyle D_{t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{(1-\alpha_0)W_0 (1+\eta_h)^t}{\mu}
    \displaystyle - \displaystyle (1-\alpha_0) W_0 \left(\alpha_0 (1+\eta_s)^t+\frac{1-\alpha_0}{\mu}\left((1+\eta_h)^t-\frac{(1-\mu)(1-(1+\nu)^{t-30})}{((1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t)}\right)\right)

The real value of the previous mortgage payment is

    \displaystyle M_t=\frac{\nu D_0}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^t}

and the real value of the new mortgage payment is

    \displaystyle M_{t+1}=\frac{\nu D_{t+1}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})}

The ratio of the new mortgage payment to the old can be written as

  \displaystyle \frac{M_{t+1}}{M_t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{D_{t+1}(1+\pi)^t}{D_0}
    \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\frac{(1-\alpha_0)W_0}{\mu}\left((1-\alpha_0)\frac{(1-\mu)(1-(1+\nu)^{t-30})}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1-\pi)^t} -\alpha_0\mu(1+\eta_s)^t+\alpha_0(1+\eta_h)^t\right)(1+\pi)^t}{\frac{(1-\alpha_0)(1-\mu)W_0}{\mu}}
    \displaystyle = \displaystyle \frac{\alpha_0(1+\pi)^t((1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t)}{(1-\mu)} +(1-\alpha_0) \frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}}

The theorem holds if,

  \displaystyle \frac{M_{t+1}}{M_t} \displaystyle > \displaystyle 1
  \displaystyle \frac{\alpha_0(1+\pi)^t((1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t)}{(1-\mu)} +(1-\alpha_0) \frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}} \displaystyle > \displaystyle 1
  \displaystyle \frac{\alpha_0(1+\pi)^t((1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t)}{(1-\mu)} > 1 - (1-\alpha_0)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}}    
  \displaystyle (1-\alpha_0)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}} < 1 \rightarrow 1 - (1-\alpha_0)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{t-30}}{1-(1+\nu)^{-30}} \displaystyle > 0
  \displaystyle \frac{\alpha_0(1+\pi)^t((1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t)}{(1-\mu)} \displaystyle > 0
  \displaystyle (1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t \displaystyle > 0
  \displaystyle \frac{(1+\eta_h)^t}{\mu} > (1+\eta_s)^t \displaystyle \rightarrow \displaystyle M_{t+1} > {M_t}

The term,  \frac{(1+\eta_h)^t}{\mu}, represents the leverage-adjusted total return on housing. These theorems do not hold when housing generates a return significantly below that of the risky asset or when the amount of leveraging is very small. If when extracting their home equity, the household puts less back into home equity, either because they are trading up to a larger home or they which to keep their LTV ratio,  \mu, constant, the gap between the real value of their new and old mortgage payments is even greater.

Corrolary 2.3   The size of the increase in the real mortgage payments upon equity extraction is an increasing function of inflation as long as the total return on the financial asset does not exceed the leveraged total return on housing.

When we differentiate the change in the mortgage payments by the inflation rate,  \pi, we find that,

    \displaystyle \frac{d}{d\pi}\left[\frac{M_{t+1}}{M_t}\right] = \frac{t(1+\pi)^{t-1} \alpha_0((1+\eta_h)^t-\mu (1+\eta_s)^t)}{1-\mu} \notag

Therefore,

    \displaystyle \frac{(1+\eta_h)^t}{\mu} > (1+\eta_s)^t \rightarrow \frac{d}{d\pi}\left[\frac{M_{t+1}}{M_t}\right] > 0 \notag

 \qedsymbol

The theorems laid out in this section support the argument that households face a significant transaction cost of extracting their home equity that is tied to the fixed nominal nature of the mortgage payment. In addition, this transaction cost is an increasing function of inflation. This result holds whether or not the inflation is expected or unexpected.


3 Simulation Model

The structure of the model was chosen to highlight the effects of mortgage contracts on the evolution of housing wealth, via its effects on the transaction costs for extracting home equity. The addition of an explicit mortgage contract to the standard model creates an additional layer of complexity in the model, which is embedded in the wealth transition rules. To accommodate this additional complexity and keep the model tractable, several important assumptions are required and are discussed in detail below. This section deals only with the aspects of the model and the underlying assumptions that differ from those of the standard model. Appendix A provides a more extensive discussion of the model, and Table B-2 in Appendix B lists the model parameters and their definitions.

One approach to modeling the role of housing wealth over a household's life cycle is to develop a simple model that captures only a few of the most important aspects of housing as an investment good. Papers such as Martin (2001) and Fernández-Villaverde and Krueger (2001) follow this approach. The advantage of such models is that many can be solved analytically or embedded in a general equilibrium framework and solved numerically. The primary disadvantage is that many have relatively narrow scopes. A second approach, as in Li and Yao (2004) and Hu (2002), is to sacrifice simplicity for a more complicated partial equilibrium model that can be solved numerically using stochastic dynamic programming. An advantage of this more complex type of model is that it presents a more realistic picture of the role of housing wealth over the life cycle. The disadvantage is an upper bound on the model's complexity, beyond which the solution times are no longer tractable, although parallel processing in a grid-cluster or super-computer environment can extend this upper bound. The complexity of the model requires that great care be exercised in presenting the results and currently precludes the option of embedding the model in a general equilibrium framework.

This paper pursues the latter approach, specifically using a dynamic stochastic optimizing framework for the household based on that in Rust and Phelan (1996). Rust and Phelan set up and solve a dynamic programming problem of labor supply with incomplete markets, Social Security, and Medicare. The dynamic programming problem in their paper is solved by making the continuous state spaces discrete and then using backward recursion to solve for the optimal value of the continuous choice variable at each point on the state-space grid. The detailed rules governing the determination of Social Security and Medicare benefits are embedded in the income-transition matrix. The model in this paper has a structure similar to those in Rust and Phelan and in Li and Yao, in that it embeds the detailed characteristics of the mortgage contract in the income-transition matrix; the significant innovation of the model is its inclusion of an explicit mortgage contract. In the main version of the model inflation is present but is constant and perfectly anticipated. The goal of the paper is to show that even under this strict assumption about inflation, optimal portfolio allocation differs under different levels of constant inflation.

The remainder of this section discusses the complications introduced by inclusion of the mortgage contract. The sections of the model that do not significantly differ from those in other papers are discussed in Appendix A.

As noted, households can store their wealth in a real asset by purchasing a house. In the model it is only through the purchase of a house, and the acquisition of a mortgage loan, that households can borrow against their future income. The model's use of durable goods as collateral is in the same spirit as in Fernández-Villaverde and Krueger (2001). The only mortgage contract available to the household in this model requires a 20 percent down payment, has a term of thirty years, and requires mortgage payments based on a fixed interest rate and the size of the original mortgage. The mortgage balance and the mortgage payment are both in nominal terms, while the rest of the model is in real terms. Households purchasing a home are also required to pay a transaction cost equal to 10 percent of the value of the home. This cost represents realtor's' fees, credit checks, and other expenses associated with the purchase.

To completely model the effects of a fixed-rate mortgage over the life cycle one must keep track of four additional continuous state variables: (1) the current value of the home, (2) the current balance of the mortgage, (3) the level of the fixed mortgage payment, and (4) the share of the fixed mortgage payment that is deducted from the outstanding mortgage balance in a given year. Because the value of home equity is the difference between the value of the home minus the remaining balance on the outstanding mortgage to measure equity, one must track both the value of the home and the mortgage balance. The nature of the mortgage contract complicates what would be a logical approach for tracking the mortgage balance, the addition of a continuous state variable. In particular, the principal paid on a self-amortizing mortgage is a function of the age of the mortgage. Initial payments are almost completely composed of interest, and the final payments on a thirty year mortgage, on the other hand, are almost completely principal. This process is modeled by including the mortgage age as a discrete state variable with thirty-one discrete values and imposing a strict structure on the evolution of the price of housing. The fact that the mortgage balance and mortgage payment are in nominal terms provides an additional motivation for including the age of the mortgage in the state space, as the real values of the mortgage balance and payment decline steadily over the life of the mortgage because of inflation.

Many factors in the model are conditional on current housing tenure, such as the cost of housing services which includes rent or mortgage payments and maintenance costs, the level of utility derived from housing, and the change in wealth associated with the appreciation in home values. To reduce the number of state spaces, households choosing to own are limited to buying either a small or a large home. The size of a large home is assumed to be twice that of a small home. The real price of housing has a positive trend over time. It is assumed that the price of rental and owner-occupied housing evolve at the same rate. Home prices are further governed by two assumptions: (1) the purchase prices of both small and large homes increase deterministically by the average increase in market price in each period and (2) the value of homes that have already been purchased changes according to a stochastic process, with the expected increase equal to the non-stochastic increase in market price. A significant result of these two assumptions is that a household that has had a series of periods of above-average rates of appreciation will own a home worth more than the market value of a comparable home, whereas a household that has had a series of periods with below-average appreciation will own a home worth less than the market value of a comparable home.

The primary motivation for the two assumptions is a need to control the number of state spaces. The mortgage payment paid by a household will vary according to the size of the house and its purchase price. By assuming that the price of new housing is deterministic and by including as state variables the age of the mortgage and size of the existing house, we are able to define both the level of the mortgage payment and the remaining mortgage balance as a function of these state variables. Another advantage of using this process to model the evolution of both market and household-level home prices is that there is significant cross-sectional variation in home appreciation. In effect, the model forces households always to buy the average-price home, regardless of their own realized price appreciation.

The effect of steadily increasing home prices provides another motivation for the inclusion of the age of the mortgage as a state variable. For example, because of the steady increase in home prices, the initial mortgage and the related mortgage payments on a given home today would be significantly greater than the mortgage on a similar home twenty years ago. As the model shows, this provides a disincentive for older households to move or refinance.

The model's design allows households to choose their current consumption, their savings, their savings allocated to risky assets as opposed to a risk-free asset, the type of housing they occupy, and whether to refinance their mortgages. Households face uncertainty in the returns on risky assets and housing, the probability of surviving, and income through a transitory shock. Income also has a deterministic component that is a function of age. The model includes moving, maintenance, and transaction costs. The model also includes the option to default on a mortgage and the costs of doing so.

The model is solved given the terms of a traditional thirty year fixed-rate mortgage contract. The values of nonstructural parameters, such as returns on different types of assets, the survival probability, mortgage terms, and the income process, are taken from historical data and are discussed in Appendix B.

3.1 Consumption of Housing

The housing choice in period  t, can take values associated with a rental unit,  i_r, a small home  i_s, and a large home  i_l. Households may increase their mortgage balances through the use of cash-out refinancing. The model does not currently include home equity lines of credit as an option for withdrawing equity. The number of housing units available to rent is continuous, whereas the number of housing units provided by small and large homes is fixed. The number of housing units associated with the housing choice  i_t is defined by the function  h(i_t).

Renters choose the number of housing units represented by the size of the rental unit so that the intra-period marginal utility of housing is equal to the marginal utility of nondurable consumption.

(A-1) \displaystyle \frac{\partial U(c_t,h(i_t))}{\partial c_t}=\frac{\partial U(c_t,h(i_t))}{\partial h(i_t)}

The optimal size of a rental unit that equalized the intra-period marginal utility of housing to the marginal utility of nondurable consumption may now be defined as a function of consumption:
(A-2) \displaystyle h(i_r)=(\phi/(1-\phi))c_t

The parameter  \phi is the measure of preference between a unit of housing and consumption, as defined in the utility function presented in Appendix A. As shown in the equation above, the model implies that  \phi will equal the share of total household expenditures associated with housing.

3.2 Price of Housing

The price per housing unit is the same across all types of housing. Large homes cost more than small homes because they provide more units of housing. Rent is proportional to the current market value of the home that renters choose. The value of owner-occupied units evolves stochastically, and the value of newly purchased and rental units are set equal to the current deterministic market price. The formulas for the market value of home type  i_t,  P_t({i_t}), and the housing wealth,  H_{t+1}, transition rule are as follows:

(A-3) \displaystyle P_t({i_t})=(1+\eta_h)^tP_0h(i_t)

(A-4) \displaystyle H_{t+1}= \begin{cases}H_t(1+\widetilde{r_h}), &i_{t+1} = {i_t}\\ P_t({i_t}), &i_{t+1} \ne {i_t} \and i_{t+1}\in{i_s,i_l}\\ 0, &i_{t+1} = i_r \end{cases}

(A-5) \displaystyle r_h\sim N(\eta_h,\sigma_h^2)

where  P_0 is the price of a single unit of housing in period 0;  P_t({i_t}) is the price in period  t of the number of housing units associated with housing choice  i_t;  \widetilde{r_h} is the realized rate of appreciation on housing in period  t;  \eta_h is the expected rate of appreciation on housing; and  \sigma_h^2 is the variance of house price growth. Note that the price of owner-occupied housing is allowed to evolve differently from the market price of housing overall in order to capture the idiosyncratic aspect of housing returns. Note also that home prices are in real terms, so the increase in the market price of housing is not due to general inflation but rather to a real increase in the value of the house over time.

3.3 The Mortgage

The interest rate and initial term to maturity are assumed to be constant over time and across households. The only variable determining the mortgage payment is the price of the home price when purchased. The homeowner's payment changes only when a new mortgage is entered into and that occurs only when the household refinances the mortgage or sells the house. A cash-out refinancing resets the number of years left on the mortgage. The formula for the real value of a mortgage payment at time  t after  \kappa_t years on a house of type  i_t is:

(A-6) \displaystyle M_t(i_t,\kappa_t)=\frac{\nu(1-\mu)P_{t-\kappa_t}}{(1-(1+\nu)^{-30})(1+\pi)^{\kappa_t}}

where  \nu is the nominal mortgage interest rate,  \pi is the inflation rate, and  \mu is the required down payment.

Also the cost of housing services reflects the maintenance costs paid by homeowners. As a result, the formula for the real cost of housing services is:

(A-7) \displaystyle X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)= \begin{cases}M_t(i_t,\kappa_t)+\delta H_t, &i_t\in{i_s,i_l}\\ 0.06P_t(i_r), &i_t = i_r \end{cases}

where  \delta H_t is maintenance costs, which are assumed to be a percentage of current home value. Rent is equal to 6 percent of the current market value of the unit being rented and renters pay none of the maintenance costs for the property.

The present value of the homeowner's home equity is the current value of the house minus the amount of the outstanding mortgage balance. The value of the house increases or decreases according to the stochastic return on housing, and the outstanding mortgage balance is a monotonically declining function of the age of the mortgage. The formula for the real value of the mortgage balance at time  t after  \kappa_t years on a house of type  i_t is:

(A-8) \displaystyle D_t(i_t,\kappa_t)= \begin{cases}M_t(i_t,\kappa_t)\frac{1-(1+\nu)^{\kappa_t-30}}{\nu}, & i_t\in{i_s,i_l} \quad\text{and} \quad \kappa_t\le 30\\ 0, & (i_t\in{i_s,i_l} \quad\text{and} \quad \kappa_t> 30)\quad\text{or}\quad(i_t = i_r) \end{cases}

The formula for the real mortgage payment is used to calculate the amount of mortgage interest paid for tax purposes. The real values must be adjusted back to nominal terms because the deduction is in nominal terms. The formula for the mortgage interest deduction is:

(A-9) \displaystyle I_t(i_t,\kappa_t)= M_t(i_t,\kappa_t)(1-(1+\nu)^{\kappa_t-30})(1+\pi)^{\kappa_t}

3.4 Net Change in Liquid Assets from Sale or Refinancing

The net change in liquid assets after paying transaction costs and down payments for a homeowner moving in the next period,  i_{t+1} \in {  i_r,i_s,i_l}, is given by

(A-10) \displaystyle G_t(i_t,i_{t+1},\kappa_t)= \begin{cases}H_t-D_t(i_t,\kappa_t)-\mu P_t(i_{t+1})-\tau H_t-\chi, &i_{t+1} \ne i_t \\ 0, &i_{t+1}=i_t \end{cases}

where  \tau H_t is the transaction cost,  \mu is the down payment rate, and  \chi is a fixed moving cost paid regardless of which type of housing is being purchased. When the household chooses not to move, (  i_{t+1}=i_t), it has a zero net gain.

The net gain in liquid assets after choosing to refinance a mortgage is defined as the sum of the difference between the mortgage balances after and before the refinancing and a fee for the transaction:

(A-11) \displaystyle Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1})= \begin{cases}(1-\zeta)D_t(i_t,\kappa_{t+1})-D_t(i_t,\kappa_t), &\kappa_{t+1}\ne\kappa_t+1\\ 0, &\kappa_{t+1}=\kappa_t+1 \end{cases}

where  \zeta represents the share of the new mortgage accounted for by the transaction costs associated with refinancing. Interest rates are constant in this model, so there is no possibility of refinancing at a lower interest rate. The only benefit of refinancing is to extract home equity and use the proceeds to invest in financial assets or to smooth consumption. When no refinancing occurs, the net gain is zero. When the household extracts cash by refinancing,  Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1})>0. Only households that choose not to move in a given period may choose to refinance.

3.5 Default Penalties

The model contains a default penalty. In any period, the household must be able to cover its housing expenses, which, in the case of rentals, consists only of the rent, and in the case of homeowners consists of the mortgage payment and maintenance costs. If a homeowning household fails to cover its housing expense, it must move in the next period into rental housing and forfeit all its home equity and all its financial equity above some small nominal amount. Defaulting renters on the other hand must simply move to a new rental unit. Households that can cover their expenses by selling their current house and extracting their home equity are allowed to do so. A household that can afford the associated transaction costs may also avoid default through a cash-out refinancing and therefore keep its housing equity.

Current consumption of households that default is constrained to equal the small nominal amount of equity left to them after default. The restriction that  A_{t+1} may not be negative, combined with the definitions of  X_t(i_t,\kappa_t),  Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1}),  G_t(i_t,i_{t+1},\kappa_t) and the budget constraint, creates an upper bound on possible levels of nondurable consumption and also rules out some possible choices of housing tenure. If the household cannot afford the down payment for a large home without incurring negative wealth, it is not allowed to move to such a home.


4 Baseline Simulation Model Results

The parameter values for the model calibration are chosen to be consistent with other models in the literature as cited above. The parameter values for the sizes of small and large homes are set so that they represent, respectively, 80 percent and 120 percent of the size of a median-priced home in 1990. The share of total household expenditures, including both renters and owners, allocated to housing expenditures, ( \phi) is set to 0.2, which is the value in the 2001 Consumer Expenditure Survey from the U.S. Department of Labor. Appendix B contains more information on the values of the market parameters and preference parameters chosen.

The model is used to generate 10,000 simulations. Households, represented by a single household head, begin as renters with no assets at age 20. Households retire at age 65 and have a maximum potential age of 80. The simulations track households accumulation of housing and financial wealth over their lifetimes.

Figure 4.1: Consumption and Income
Figure 4.1 (a). Wages and Consumption.  Two sets of data plotted together as separate curves with mean value (wages and consumption) in tens of thousands of dollars for survivors in cohort on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  One curve represents the average wages in tens of thousands of dollars by age cohort, and the other represents average consumption in tens of thousands of dollars by age cohort.  Average wages and consumption are relatively low for young households but increase steadily as households age.  Wages peak at approximately $30,000 at age 50, and then fall sharply when households retire at age 65.  After age 65, wages in retirement, representing penion income, remain flat at roughly $7,500.  Consumption for working households follows the same contour as wages, at a level roughly $10,000 lower.  In retirement consumption remains level, with a small uptick among the very old.
Figure 4.1 (b). Consumption as a Share of Total Wealth.  Data plotted as curve with average of the ration consumption over total wealth represented as decimals on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The curve shows that heads of households in their early twenties, where the graph begins, tend to consume only 2% of their total wealth.  This percentage increases fairly steeply through the mid to late twenties, peaking locally at consuming 15% of total wealth as households reach their thirties.  The portion of total wealth consumed decreases slowly, reaching 10% by the time households reach age 65.  The percentage then increases steeply, reaching 30% as household heads reach age 80.
Figure 4.1 (c). Ratio of Total Wealth to Income.  Data plotted as a curve with average of the ration of total wealth divided by income represented on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The ration of total wealth to income starts at 0 for households at age 20.  It then grows steadily until on average households hold 10 times their average income in total wealth prior to retirement at age 65.  In retirement, as income falls, the ratio of total wealth jumps to 43 times income before falling to 14 times income at age 80.

Income among surviving households drops sharply at retirement whereas the path of consumption over the life cycle is much smoother, (figure 4.1, panel A). Younger households who are aggressively saving for a down payment consume the smallest share of their wealth (panel B). Once households become homeowners, their consumption as a share of total wealth climbs, peaking near 16 percent around age 30. As households approach retirement, they start to accumulate more wealth, and consumption as a share of total wealth starts to fall, reaching a low of 9 percent at age 65 (panel C). In retirement, households draw down their savings, and consumption as a share of total wealth climbs again. At the outset of retirement the average household has roughly forty-five times its annual post-retirement income saved in both housing and financial wealth.

Figure 4.2: Wealth and Portfolio Choice
Figure 4.2 (a) Simulated Housing Wealth.  Data plotted as curve with mean value of housing wealth in tens of thousands of dollars for survivors in cohort on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  On average, housing wealth increases fairly steadily from zero at age 20 to about $60,000 at 65 years old.  Mean housing wealth peaks at the 65 year mark and then decreases during retirement, falling to below $40,000 by age 80. Figure 4.2 (b).  Simulated Financial Wealth. Data plotted as a curve with mean value of financial wealth in tens of thousands of dollars for survivors in cohort on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  On average, simulated financial wealth increases fairly linearly from the early 20s to about $120,000 at age 65.  Mean simulated financial wealth then decreases linearly at a steep rate as a households age, reaching $40,000 by age 80.
Figure 4.2 (c).  Simulated Share of Housing Assets.  Data plotted as a curve with mean share of total assets consisting of home equity, for the subset of households owning a home, on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The figure shows that on average, new homeowners start off with roughly 45% of their total assets held in home equity.  From their mid twenties to age 60, households's share of housing assets falls slightly an then remains around 40%, dropping slight again at age 65 and then increasing as households age, reaching 60% by age 80. Figure 4.2 (d).  Simulated Risky Share of Financial Assets.  Data plotted as a curve with mean share of financial wealth held in risky assets on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The figures shows that at age 22, households hold on average about 35% of their financial assets in risky assets.  This percentage drops under 30% as for households in their mid-20s, but then rises steeply until leveling off around age 40 and peaking at almost 100% at age 50.  The percentage drops to around 80% at age 65 and remains fairly level but falls slightly as households reach their late 70s.  The share of financial wealth held in risky assets ticks up slightly among the very old.

Housing wealth is hump-shaped, on average, over the life cycle of the household, reaching a peak at age 65 and declining after age 70 (figure 4.2 panel A). The brief plateau in the growth of housing wealth at age 50 is caused by many households either trading down to smaller homes or refinancing their existing mortgage to ensure that their nominal mortgage payments are fixed for the rest of their expected lives.1 Financial wealth over the life cycle is more sharply humped and peaks at age 65 (panel B).

Figure 4.3: Housing Tenure Choice
Figure 4.3 (a). Simulated Homeownership Rate.  Data plotted as curve with the share of survivors in cohort that are homeowners on y-axis and age in years on x-axis.  This figure shows that while an extremely small portion of household heads in their early twenties own their homes this percentage increases steeply, reaching almost 100% by age 40 where the rate remains constant until it begins to drop slightly after age 70. Figure 4.3 (b). Simulated Share of Homeownership in Large Homes.  Data plotted as curve with share of homeowners that own large homes on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  This panel shows that on average under 1% of homeowners in their twenties own large homes.  However this share increases fairly steeply until peaking at almost 19% of homeowners just over 50 owning large homes.  After the apex, the share drops dramatically and then levels off at around 16%.  The share of homeowners owning large homes starts to decreases with age once homeowners turn 70, reaching 11% by age 80.
Figure 4.3 (c).  Simulated Loan-to-Value Ratio.  Data plotted as curve with average ratio loan balance to home value for homeowners on y-axis and age in years on x-axis.  On average, the loan-to-value of a home for young homeowners starts off at its highest point at almost 80% and then decreases steadily until reaching 10% at age 65. The loan-to-value ratio then starts to increase, reaching 30% by age 80. Figure 4.3 (d) Simulated Refinancing Rate.  Data plotted as curve with fraction of homeowners refinancing on the y-axis and age on the x-axis.  On average, almost no households in their early to mid twenties refinance their home loans.  The fraction who refinance increases jaggedly to about .6% for households in their mid thirties and then decreases unevenly back to around 0% for household in their mid fifties and sixties.  At age 70 however, the fraction of households who refinance increases dramatically, peaking at just below 2.5% at age 75.  The percentage then drops steeply as households continue to age, reaching 1.2% at age 80.

Panel A reveals that households use accumulated home equity to finance their consumption of nondurables only late in retirement after their reserves of financial wealth have been largely depleted. These results are fairly consistent with some previous empirical work. Venti and Wise (2000) found that housing wealth was not in fact used to support non-housing consumption. They found that households resort to their home equity only when faced by a significant shock such as the death of a spouse or a serious illness. Similarly, Sheiner and Weil (1992) found that anticipation of illness or death significantly increases the probability that households will reduce their home equity. However, the present model does result in a more rapid decline late in life in housing wealth than previous empirical studies have shown. The model's omission and retiree labor supply might explain this failure. In particular households might view their home equity as an important source of savings to tap when faced with a serious health shock and be unwilling to extract that equity in the absence of such a shock. They could avoid consuming their housing wealth by continuing to work after retirement.

The simulated mean share of assets held in housing for surviving household heads between the ages of about 35 and 65 is consistently near 40 percent, (figure 4.2 panel C). The housing share is high among young households, who must invest a large portion of their savings in a down payment. As financial wealth grows faster than housing wealth, the housing share falls but somewhat climbs again. The jagged nature of the curve reflects a comparatively small number of simulations. The housing share climbs in retirement, as households draw down financial wealth before they extract home equity because of the transaction costs. This behavior can explain some of the "over investment" in housing seen in the empirical data, as reported by Flavin and Yamashita (2002). The implication is that some degree of over investment in housing can arise as a result of the mortgage contract rather than any suboptimal behavior by irrational consumers. Note, though, that the degree of over-investment implied by the model is below that seen in the data; Flavin and Yamashita find the mean share of total assets held in housing to be 67 percent.

Regarding the allocation of financial assets over the life cycle, young households - who are focused on saving for a down payment or already have a large share of their wealth in housing - invest less in risky financial assets and more in the risk-free asset (figure 4.2 panel D). Older households also have their allocation weighted to less risky financial assets, but in their case because they have drawn down their financial wealth relative to their housing wealth. The share of the financial portfolio invested in risky assets peaks around age 50, just when households start to actively shift their total portfolio away from home equity.

The model results also document other housing decisions over the life cycle. Homeownership increases rapidly for younger households and declines very slightly in retirement (figure 4.3 panel A). The share of homeowners living in larger homes has a similar contour with a considerable drop at age 50 (panel B), as households trade down in retirement to access housing wealth to finance consumption.

The sharpness of the decline at age 50 results largely from the combination of the thirty year term of the mortgage and the assumed maximum age of 80 and thus should not be taken too literally. In particular, at 50 years old, many households take advantage of the thirty year mortgage term to hold constant their nominal mortgage payments for the rest of their lives. These households will continue to receive a constant stream of utility from their home, the real value of the mortgage payments will fall because of inflation. In effect, in buying a home at age 50, households are purchasing an annuity from which the stream of real payments - the difference between the implicit rent and the real mortgage cost - will increase with time and be at its highest during retirement when income is at its lowest. This hypothesis is supported by results from simulations where the term of the mortgage is varied (figure 4.4). When the mortgage term is shortened to twenty years and the retirement age remains at 65, homeowners delay the shift to smaller homes to age 60. The results are not sensitive to the changing of the retirement age; in particular, when the retirement age is 75 and the mortgage term is thirty years, homeowners still shift to smaller homes at age 50. Thus proximity to retirement can be ruled out as a factor.

Figure 4.4: Why Trade Down at 50?
Figure 4.4  Simulated Share of Homeowners in Large Homes.  Three series plotted together as separate curves, each representing, under different sets of assumptions, the share of homeowners living in large homes on the y-axis age in years on the x-axis.  One curve reflects the baseline assumptions in the model as is identical to the one in Figure 4.3(b).  One curve represents an alternative scenario where households retire at age 75 instead of age 65.  Under this scenario the share of homeowners living in large homes is very similar to the share seen in the baseline scenario, except among the elderly where the share of homeowners living in large homes is significantly higher than was seen in the baseline scenario.  The third scenario assumes that households retire at age 65, but have 20-year instead of 30-year mortgages.  Under this scenario, the share of homeowners living in large homes is similar to the base scenario up until age 50.  Instead of dropping sharply at age 50, as it did in the other scenarios, the share of homeowners in large homes remains steady until age 60 when it drops sharply, and then steadily declines until it returns to the levels seen in the baseline scenario.

Panel C shows the path of the loan-to-value ration over the life-cycle. At the time they purchase their homes, households are required to have a loan-to-value ratio of 80 percent (panel C). They then pay down their mortgage through the regular amortization schedule and the average loan-to-value ratio falls. The average loan-to-value ratio seems to stabilize at 10% before climbing late in retirement in response to a surge in cash-out refinancing. This surge can be seen in Panel D. In addition, younger households and those that have just purchased their homes take advantage of refinancing to re-balance their portfolios and smooth their income.


5 The Effects of Inflation on Portfolio Allocation

This section shows how portfolio allocation across the life cycle changes with different levels of inflation. The model is re-solved for different levels and corresponding sets of simulations are generated. Setting the inflation parameter to a higher level simulates the effects of high inflation, and setting it to zero simulates the effect of mortgage contracts that are real rather than nominal. The levels of wealth accumulation, housing demand, refinancing activity, and portfolio allocation under each alternative assumption are then compared to the base case.

Figure 5.1: Rent and Mortgage Payments
Figure 5.1. Rent and Mortgage Payments.  Three series plotted together as separate curves with dollars on the y-axis and years on the x-axis.  The first curve is the nominal value of the mortgage payment and is flat from year 1 to year 30.  The second line represents the market rent for a rental unit and is a positively sloped line starting at $350 in the first year and increasing to over $475 by the end of the thirty years.  The third line represents the real value of the mortgage payment is negatively sloped, starting at just under the nominal mortgage in the first year but dropping to under $225 after thirty years.

The presence of nominal mortgage contracts effectively shifts the real costs of home ownership forward over the term of the mortgage (figure 5.1). The fact that the real value of the mortgage payment declines over the life of the mortgage is, of course, factored into the original mortgage rate.

Figure 5.2: Wealth and Portfolio Choice
Figure 5.2 (a). Simulated Housing Wealth.  Three series plotted together as separate curves with mean value of housing wealth in tens of thousands of dollars under three different scenarios on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  These curves show simulate housing wealth through a lifetime for three different scenarios: high inflation, no inflation, and the base case.  The baseline and no inflation curves more closely with each other with the baseline always slightly above the no inflation curve.  In the base case and with no inflation, heads of households in their early twenties have little or no housing wealth.  As they age their housing wealth increases.  There is a short period of leveling in the base case at just over $40,000 for fifty-year olds, but housing wealth then continues to climb and peaks with the no inflation curve at around $60,000 at age sixty five.  Both curves decrease from that point forward to about $35,000 by age 80. In the high inflation case, twenty-year old heads of household start with close to no housing wealth but accumulate housing wealth faster until they have on average around $45,000 worth of housing wealth around age 50.  The curve then drops sharply to around $30,000 and from there, it increases to over $50,000 at age 65 where it levels off. Figure 5.2 (b) Simulated Share of Housing Assets.  Three series plotted together as separate curves with mean share of total assets held in home equity for homeowners under three different scenarios on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis. These curves show simulated share of housing assets through a lifetime for three different scenarios: high inflation, no inflation, and the base case.  The three curves have the same basic shape.  Each starts at roughly zero around age twenty and increases very sharply to around 45%.  With fluctuation, the curves remain around 40% through age 60.  The high inflation curve experiences the most fluctuation over those forty years, peaking sharply at around 75% at age 35 with another peak at around 65% at age 50.  The three curves dip at age 65 to between 30 and 40% and then increase through the rest of the lifetime to around 60%.
Figure 5.3: Housing Tenure Choice
Figure 5.3 (a). Simulated Share of Homeowners in Large Homes.  Three series plotted together as separate curves with the fraction homeowner in large homes under three different scenarios on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The curves show simulated share of homeowners in large homes through a lifetime for three different scenarios: high inflation, no inflation, and the base case.  The baseline and no inflation curve have very similar shapes, starting at little to no homeowners in their twenties in large homes, increasing to about 15% of homeowners in their forties through sixties in large homes and then decreasing to about 10% of homeowners in their late seventies in large homes.  The two curves are visibly different only for homeowners ages 40 through just over 50 where the baseline curve is above the no inflation curve and reaches a peak at around 18% at age 50.  The high inflation curve is quite different from the other two.  While the high inflation curves starts with the other two at around 0% of homeowners in their twenties in large homes, the curve increases more slowly for homeowners in their thirties and forties, reaching less than 10% by age fifty.  At age fifty, however, the curve quickly shoots up to over 25% of homeowners in large homes and falls equally quickly to just over 5%.  This percentage increases slowly for homeowners in their mid fifties through seventies to just under 10% by age 75. Figure 5.3 (b). Simulated Loan-to-Value Ratio.  Three series plotted together as separate curves with average ratio the loan balance to the value of the home under three different scenarios of home on the y-axis and age in years on the x-axis.  The curves show simulated loan-to-value ratio through a lifetime for three different scenarios: high inflation, no inflation, and the base case.  In all three cases, the loan-to-value ratio increases sharply from 0% to over 75% during household heads' early twenties.  The high inflation curve then falls to just under 40% at age 50, jumps up to about 45% a couple years later, and then falls to just under 25% in household heads' late sixties where the percentage remains.  The baseline and no inflation curve are much smoother with the no inflation curve always slightly above the baseline.  Both curves decrease from the late twenties through early sixties, reaching a trough at around 10% in the late sixties.  The curves then begin to rise, reaching around 30% by age 80.

Figure 5.2 and  5.3 show how portfolio allocation and housing demand differ under different inflation rates. Under the zero-inflation scenario (the red-dotted lines) the transaction costs facing households in rebalancing their portfolios are significantly reduced. Households, especially younger households, hold less housing wealth. A common strategy in the presence of large transaction costs for durable goods is for a household to "over-buy," that is buy a larger house than they would otherwise, knowing that they would be unable to easily re-adjust their level of housing consumption later in the life-cycle when they might actually want a larger home. With zero inflation reducing the transaction costs, there is significantly less of this "over-buying." In addition, we do not observe the sudden shift towards smaller homes at age 50 seen in the base case, since the real value of the mortgage payment is no longer declining, and households gain less of a benefit of locking their mortgages prior to retirement.

The results from the high inflation scenario (the green lines) are a mirror image of those from the low inflation scenario. Now that the transaction costs associated with extracting home equity are higher, households rebalance their mortgage less frequently, resulting in an increase in housing wealth held by the young and very old and a decrease in housing wealth held by the middle-aged and early retirees.

The sudden shift towards smaller homes at age 50 is even more pronounced under the high inflation scenario, as the benefit of locking their mortgages prior to retirement is greater with higher inflation. Many households attempt to trade-up just prior at age 50, knowing that if they get several positive income shocks they would be able to afford the higher real mortgage payments, which would gradually decline over the life of the mortgage. When they do not receive positive income shocks, households in this model trade down because they fear they will not be able to make the mortgage payments once their income falls in retirement. During periods of high inflation, mortgage contracts with fixed nominal payments are especially attractive to households. During the prime of their earnings years (their 50s) the real mortgage payment is high. The real mortgage payment then falls rapidly during retirement, just when their income also falls. As discussed above, nominal mortgage payments allow older households to shift the expense of housing forward to earlier years to ensure their ability to consume housing later; the higher the rate of inflation, the greater the benefit to do so.


6 Conclusion

The model developed in this paper demonstrates the way in which perfectly anticipated inflation, even when reflected in the nominal interest rate on mortgages, can distort the household's portfolio allocation over the life cycle. A standard thirty-year fixed-rate nominal mortgage contract results in declining real mortgage payments. The longer a mortgage is held, the greater the difference between the household's mortgage payment and the payment for a mortgage refinanced in the current period. This widening gap discourages households from shifting assets from home equity to financial portfolios. When calibrated using commonly accepted parameters, the results can explain at least some of the "overinvestment in housing" documented in the earlier literature and also help explain why retired households hold such a significant portion of their wealth in housing.

Inflation distorts the household's portfolio allocation by introducing a hidden transaction cost through its effect on the real value of the fixed nominal mortgage payment. When inflation is high, the gap in the real value of a new mortgage and an existing mortgage is larger, and households rebalance their portfolio between home equity and financial assets less frequently. When inflation is low, household find extracting their home equity to be cheaper, and therefore more frequently rebalance their portfolio.


Appendix A - Detailed Partial Equilibrium Life Cycle Model

This appendix provides a detailed description of the partial equilibrium life-cycle model used in this paper. Aspects of the model that significantly differ from the basic model used in the literature are discussed in the main body of the paper.

The household's optimization problem is to maximize lifetime utility, defined as:

(A-1) \displaystyle E\sum_{t=20}^{80}\beta^t\rho_tU(c_t,h(i_t)) \displaystyle +\beta^t(1-\rho_t)(\theta_AU_B(A_t)+\theta_HU_B(H_t)-\theta_DU_B(D_t))
      \displaystyle s.t. \quad c_t > 0,\forall{t}=20,...,80

(A-2) \displaystyle U(c_t,h(i_t))=\frac{(c_t^{1-\phi}h(i_t)^{\phi})^{1-\lambda}}{1-\lambda}

(A-3) \displaystyle U_B(b)=\frac{b^{1-\lambda}}{1-\lambda}

where A household lives at most 60 years from age 20 to a maximum of age 80. The utility of bequests is treated as separable to capture the disutility associated with negative as well as positive bequests. It faces uncertainty about its survival, temporary income shocks, and the rate of return on both housing and risky assets. In addition to the stochastic elements for income and the rate of return on risky assets, the households may experience additional shocks. A small probability exists that the household will experience unemployment in one period, reducing income to zero. Also, a small independent probability exists of a stock market crash, in which case the household will lose 100 percent of its investment in the risky financial asset. The probability of a stock market crash is in addition to the regular standard deviation associated with the stochastic rate of return on risky assets. The inclusion of this additional shock is required in order to persuade households not to hold financial portfolios consisting entirely of risky assets. The price of the consumption good is set equal to unity and the rental price of housing is set equal to a constant ratio of the underlying price of the housing unit. The inflation rate is constant, positive, and known.

Households begin at age 20 as renters with no savings. Thus, they have no financial wealth and no housing wealth. In each period, a household receives a draw from an age-dependent income process. The model contains only transitory shocks. In retirement, pension income is set to 60 percent of the deterministic portion of income at age 65. Pension income is still subject to transitory shocks representing uncertainty regarding medical costs.

Households can store their wealth in two different classes of assets: financial and real. The household's financial assets are held in a portfolio of risk-free and risky assets. The household can costlessly rebalance its financial portfolio between risk-free and risky assets in every period. Households with zero wealth face a binding liquidity constraint for financial assets in that they cannot borrow against their future income. The only way to effectively borrow against future income is through a mortgage for which the household meets the down payment and income requirements. Households also cannot purchase leveraged portfolios, in which they borrow at the risk-free rate to invest more in risky assets. In addition to moving to one of the three types of housing, a rental unit ( i_r), a small house ( i_s), and a large house ( i_l), the household can also decide to stay in its current home,  \{i_{t+1}=i_t\}. Households may add to their mortgage balance through cash-out refinancing.

The transition rule for the level of financial wealth is defined as:

(A-4) \displaystyle A_{t+1} \displaystyle =(1+(1-\gamma)(\alpha_t\widetilde{r_{s_t}}+(1-\alpha_t)r))
      \displaystyle \times(A_t-c_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)+G_t(i_t,i_{t+1},\kappa_t)+Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1}))
      \displaystyle +(1-\gamma)\widetilde{e_{t+1}}+\gamma I_t(i_t,\kappa_t)
      \displaystyle s.t. \quad A_{t+1} \ge 0
      \displaystyle 0 \le \alpha_t \le 1

where The net gain from a home sale is tax free and the mortgage interest paid is deducted from taxable income. Both housing expenses and the amount of the mortgage interest deduction are functions of the current housing choice and the age of the mortgage. Refinancing is modeled as a choice to increase the remaining number of years on the mortgage, or inversely, to shorten the current age of the mortgage. The model allows only cash-out refinancing and does not allow prepayments. The age of a mortgage for a rental unit and of a mortgage that has been paid off is zero.

Households receive their wages at the same time they realize the returns on their investment from the previous period. As a result, the state variable  A_t represents all available cash on hand, consisting of previous financial wealth and current income. The income process is defined as a deterministic function of age plus a transitory shock:

(A-5) \displaystyle \log(e_t) \displaystyle =\psi_0+\psi_1t+\psi_2t^2+\varepsilon^{e}_t
      \displaystyle \varepsilon^{e}_t\sim N(0,\sigma_e)

The real rate of return on risky assets is a random variable with the distribution
(A-6) \displaystyle r_{s_t}\sim N(\eta_s,\sigma_s^2)

where  \eta_s is the expected real rate of return on the risky asset and  \sigma_s^2 is the variance. The household's optimization problem is to choose variables  c_t,\alpha_t,i_{t+1},\kappa_{t+1} given a series of state variables  t,\kappa_t,i_t,A_t,H_t to optimize equation (A-1) given equations (A-2) through (A-6). The household has only one choice of mortgage contract, with a fixed down payment rate. The choice variable  \kappa_{t+1} captures the ability of a household to cash-out home equity by refinancing and thereby reduce the effective age of the mortgage.

The value function of the household is the maximum utility, subject to the default constraints of the value functions for the households that choose next period's tenure type  i_{t+1} \in \{i_r,i_s,i_l,i_t\}:

(A-7)   \displaystyle A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)<0 \And
      \displaystyle A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)+\max_{i_{t+1},\kappa_{t+1}}(G_t(i_t,i_{t+1})+Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1}))>0\Rightarrow
      \displaystyle V_t(i_t,A_t,H_t,\kappa_t)=\max_{i_{t+1}\ne i_t \, or \, \kappa_{t+1}\ne \kappa_t+1,c_t,\alpha_t}{V_t^{i_{t+1}}(i_{t+1},A_t,H_t,\kappa_t)}

(A-8)   \displaystyle A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)<0 \And
      \displaystyle A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)+\max_{i_{t+1},\kappa_{t+1}}(G_t(i_t,i_{t+1})+Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1}))<0\Rightarrow
      \displaystyle V_t(i_t,A_t,H_t,\kappa_t)=U(\omega,h(i_t))+\beta\rho_tV_t(i_r,\omega,0,0)+\beta(1-\rho_t)\theta_AU_B(\omega)

(A-9)   \displaystyle A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)>0\Rightarrow
      \displaystyle V_t(i_t,A_t,H_t,\kappa_t)=\max_{i_{t+1} \in \{i_r,i_s,i_l\},c_t,\alpha_t,\kappa_{t+1}}{V_t^{i_{t+1}}(i_m,A_t,H_t,\kappa_t)}

where  \omega is the amount of consumption and wealth protected in default from creditors. Equation (A-7) is the value function when the household's recurring housing expenses,  X_t(i_t,\kappa_t), are greater than its available liquid assets,  A_t and its net equity after selling or refinancing its home is positive,  A_t-X_t(i_t,\kappa_t)+\max_{i_{t+1},\kappa_{t+1}}(G_t(i_t,i_{t+1})+Z_t(\kappa_t,\kappa_{t+1}))>0. Faced with this constraint, the household must either move,  i_{t+1}\ne i_t, or refinance,  \kappa_{t+1}\ne \kappa_t+1. Equation (A-8) is the value function when the household cannot cover its recurring housing expenses out of its liquid assets and its net equity after selling or refinancing the home is negative. This household must move to a rental unit,  i_{t+1}=i_r, and have both its consumption and remaining wealth limited to  \omega. Equation (A-9) is the value function when the household can cover its recurring housing expenses out of their liquid assets. The only limits to their choices are those embedded in the constraints in equation (A-4).

The value function conditional on next period's tenure choice  i_{t+1} is

(A-10)

such that equations (A-2) through (A-9) hold.

The code used to solve this problem was written in C. One solution of the problem initially took roughly two weeks on a dual processor Pentium Xeon 1.8GHz with 512K L2 cache and 1GB of RAM running Linux. In order to improve upon the run-time, the code was rewritten to take advantage of parallel processing, using the Message Passing Interface (MPI) standard. In this version of the code one processor is designated the master while a pool of other processors are designated slaves. As the model is solved recursively by year, the master distributes the current value function for all previous years to the slaves. Each slave then solves for the optimal value function for a subset of state spaces for the given year. The slaves then return the new value function values to the master. The master then combines the new values with the value function for the previous year, completing the recursion for one year. The problem was solved using 61 high-performance Digital Alpha 64-bit microprocessors running at 450MHz each on a scalable parallel Cray T3E at the Pittsburgh Supercomputing Center. One solution involved roughly 1.3 billion evaluations of the value function and took roughly eight and a half hours.

Appendix B - Baseline Model Parameter Values

The parameter values for the baseline model are chosen to be consistent with other models in the relevant literature. As was discussed in appendix A, the income process consists of a deterministic factor and a transitory factor. The income process is based on the results of regressions of Social Security earnings on age and age-squared. The dependent variable is the log of the wage income in constant 1990 dollars. The transitory factor of wage is reflected in the estimated standard error of the regression. The wage is converted from log to level terms in the model. At age 65 the level of the deterministic wage falls to a flat level equal to 60% of the last period's income before any transitory shocks, a condition representing a system of forced retirement and a defined benefit pension plan. The coefficients and standard deviation used in this version of the model are in Table B-1.


Table B-1: Log Income Regression Results
Constant  \psi_0 7.28626
Coefficient Age  \psi_1 0.10278
Coefficient of Age ^2  \psi_2 -0.00098
Std. Dev.  \sigma_w 0.80778
R ^2   15.5%
Probability of Unemployment  \upsilon 1%

The market price of a housing unit is the result of setting the deterministic home price at age 60 with the National Association of Realtors' 1990 median home price. It is assumed that a median home consists of 10 housing units. The home prices are converted to constant 1990 dollars and the deterministic home price series are calculated using the historical average return. The average and standard deviation of the return on housing are at taken from Li and Yao (2004) and are consistent with Campbell and Cocco (2003). The mortgage interest rate used is the average rate on loans with 80 percent loan-to-value ratios as reported by Freddie Mac from 1969 to 2001, adjusting for the inflation rate. The percent required for the down payment represents the minimum needed to avoid paying mortgage insurance. The transaction, maintenance, and moving costs are based on survey data provided by the National Association of Realtors. The values chosen for the current version of the model are in Table B-2. The risk and return on risky assets follows Yao and Zhang (2004).


Table B-2: Values of Market Parameters
Parameter Name and Definition Symbol Value
Real risk free rate of return r 2%
Price of 1 housing unit, at age 60  P_{60}(1) 1.003
Size of small homes  h(i_s) 8
Size of large homes  h(i_l) 12
Mean of real return on housing  \eta_h 1%
Standard deviation of housing return  \sigma_h 11.5%
Mean of real return on risky asset  \eta_s 6%
Standard deviation of risky asset return  \sigma_s 15.7%
Probability of 100% loss on risky asset  \varsigma 1%
Mortgage interest rate  \nu 5%
Percent required as down payment  \mu 20%
Percent of home price lost to transaction costs  \tau 10%
Maintenance costs  \delta 0.7%
Moving costs  \chi 0.3
Tax Rate  \gamma 30%
Refinancing Costs  \zeta 3%
Inflation  \pi 2%
            Note: Units not in percent are in $10,000s.

The values for the preference parameters shown in Table B-3 below were chosen to replicate certain stylized facts about the role of owner-occupied housing in portfolios, specifically the large share of total wealth held in home equity. An  \lambda value of 2 represents a relatively low, but realistic, level of risk aversion. An  \beta value of 0.96 is a commonly used discount rate. The  \phi value of 0.2 reflects the share of total household expenditures allocated to housing expenditures in the 2001 Consumer Expenditure Survey from the U.S. Department of Labor. The discount rate for bequests are 0.8 for  \theta_A, 0.8 for  \theta_H, and 0.8 for  \theta_M. They are chosen to imply that households would rather consume one additional dollar than leave an additional dollar as a bequest and that households place a premium on leaving their homes as bequests relative to other assets.


Table B-3: Values of Structural Parameters in Calibrated Model
 \lambda  \beta  \phi  \theta_A  \theta_H  \theta_M
2 0.96 0.2 0.8 0.8 0.8

Bucks, Brian K., Arthur B. Kennickell, and Kevin B. Moore.
"Recent Changes in U.S. Family Finances: Evidence from the, 2001 and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances." Federal Reserve Bulletin 92, 2006. pp. A1-A38.
Buist, Henry and Tyler T. Yang.
"Housing Finance in a Stochastic Economy: Contract Pricing and Choice." Real Estate Economics. Vol. 28. No. 1., 2000. pp. 117-139.
Caplin, Andrew and Sewin Chan, Charles Freeman and Joseph Tracy.
"Household Asset Portfolios and the Reform of the Housing Finance Market." TIAA-CREF Research Dialogues 59. February, 1999. pp. 1-12.
Cocco, João F.
"Hedging House Price Risk With Incomplete Markets." Society for Computational Economics. Computing in Economics and Finance., 2000. No. 317.
Engelhardt, Gary V.
"House Prices and Home Owner Saving Behavior." Regional Science and Urban Economics. Vol. 26. Issue 3-4., 1996. pp. 313-336.
Fernández-Villaverde, Jesús and Dirk Krueger.
"Consumption and Saving over the Life-cycle: How Important are Consumer Durables?" Working Paper., 2005.
Flavin, Marjorie and Takashi Yamashita.
"Owner-Occupied Housing and the Composition of the Household Portfolio." The American Economic Review. Vol. 92., 2002. pp. 345-362.
Fratantoni, Michael C.
"Homeownership, Committed Risk, and the Stockholding Puzzle." Oxford Economic Papers. Vol. 53. Issue 2., 2001. pp. 241-259.
Gourinchas, Pierre-Oliver, and Jonathan A. Parker.
"Consumption over the Life-cycle." Econometrica. Vol. 70. Issue 1. , 2002. pp. 47-89.
Green, Richard and Patric H. Hendershott.
"Age, Housing Demand, and Real House Prices." Regional Science and Urban Economics. Vol. 26. Issue 5., 1996. >pp. 465-480.
Guiso, Luigi, Tullio Jappelli, and Daniele Terlizzese.
"Income Risk, Borrowing Constraints, and Portfolio Choice." The American Economic Review. Vol. 86. Issue 1. pp. 158-172., 1996.
Grossman, Sanford and Guy Laroque.
"Asset Pricing and Optimal Portfolio Choice in the Presence of Illiquid Durable Consumption Goods." Econometrica. Vol. 58. No. 1., 1990. pp.25-51.
Henderson, J. Vernon and Yannis M. Ioannides.
"A Model of Housing Tenure Choice." The American Economic Review. Vol. 73. Issue 1., 1983. pp. 98-113.
Henderson, J. Vernon and Yannis M. Ioannides.
"Dynamic Aspects of Consumer Decision in Housing Markets." Journal of Urban Economics. Vol. 26. Issue 2., 1989. pp. 212-230.
Hu, Xiaoqing.
"Essays on Portfolio Choice for Homeowners." Dissertation. Northwestern University., 2002.
Hurst, Erik and Frank Stafford.
"Home is Where the Equity Is: Liquidity Constraints, Refinancing and Consumption." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. Vol. 36. Issue 6., 2004. pp. 985-1014.
LaFayette, William C., Donald R. Haurin, and Patric H. Hendershott.
"Endogenous Mortgage Choice, Borrowing Constraints and The Tenure Decision." NBER Working Paper No., 5074. 1995.
Li, Wenli and Rui Yao.
"The Life-Cycle Effects of House Price Changes." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, forthcoming.
Martin, Robert F.
"Consumption, Durable Goods, and Transaction Costs." Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. International Finance Discussion Papers: 756., 2003.
Ortalo-Magne, Francois and Sven Rady.
"Housing Market Fluctuations in a Life-Cycle Economy with Credit Constraints." Financial Markets Group. FMG Discussion Papers. , 1998.
Rust, John, and Christopher Phelan
. "How Social Security and Medicare Affect Retirement Behavior in a World of Incomplete Markets." Econometrica. Vol. 65. Issue 4., 1997. pp. 781-832.
Sheiner, Louise and David Weil.
"The Housing Wealth of the Aged." NBER Working Paper No., 4115. 1992.
Sinai, Todd and Nicholas S. Souleles.
"Owner-Occupied Housing as a Hedge Against Rent Risk." Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 120. Issue 2., 2005. pp. 763-789.
Venti, Steven F. and David A. Wise.
"Aging and Housing Equity." Innovations in Retirement Financing. Pension Research Council Publications. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press., 2002. pp. 254-81.
Yao, Rui and Harold H. Zhang.
"Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Risky Housing and Borrowing Constraints." The Review of Financial Studies. Vol. 8. Issue 1., 2005. pp. 197-239.



Footnotes

* Comments are welcome at: [email protected]. I would like to thank John Rust, John Shea, Anthony Yezer, Michael Pries, Shane Sherlund, Kathleen Johnson, Andreas Lehnert, Michael Highfield, Gregg Forte, Karen Dynan, Julie Holt-Baker, and Carolyn Aler for their comments. I would also like to thank seminar participants at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Econometric Society, Financial Management Association, and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Financial support from the University of Maryland Population Center Seed Grant, Economic Club of Washington Doctoral Research Fellowship, and Department of Housing and Urban Development Doctoral Dissertation Grant is gratefully acknowledged, as is computing resources from the Pittsburg Supercomputing Center. The analysis and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or other members of its staff. Return to Text
1. This behavior becomes more apparent under several alternative scenarios presented later in the paper. It is to a large degree a product of the specific model design, specifically the interaction of the thirty-year mortgage with the maximum age of the households set at 80. In the absence of these restrictions, households would still attempt to "lock-in" their nominal mortgage payments prior to retirement, but this activity would not be clumped together at age 50. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text