Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2016-101 Screen Reader version

The Effect of Banks' Financial Position on Credit Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries*

David E. Rappoport
Federal Reserve Board

September 19, 2016

Abstract:

This paper presents empirical evidence on the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth using a sample of 29 OECD countries. The failure of the exogeneity assumption of explanatory variables is addressed using dynamic panel type instruments. The empirical results show that among capital, profits and liquidity at the end of the previous year, capital is the most important predictor of credit growth in the current year. The relationship between capital and credit growth is non-linear. Point estimates from the preferred econometric specification imply that at the sample mean a one standard deviation increase (decrease) in capital is associated with an increase (decrease) of 0.8 (0.3) percentage points in credit growth upon impact and 1.6 (0.6) percentage points in the long-run.

Keywords: banking, credit supply, Bank lending, OECD, bank financial position

JEL Classification: G21, E44, G28

1 Introduction

Understanding the determinants of credit growth is an important issue, as credit is considered a key transmitter of financial shocks into real activity and it is at the heart of the lending channel of monetary policy. These issues have received renewed attention after the recent Great Recession following the collapse of the subprime housing market in the US.

This paper presents empirical evidence on the effect of banks' financial position (capital, profits and liquidity) on credit growth using a sample of 29 OECD countries. The empirical results show that among capital, profits and liquidity at the end of the previous year, capital is the most important predictor of credit growth in the current year. The relationship between capital and credit growth is non-linear. Point estimates from the preferred econometric specification imply that at the sample mean a one standard deviation increase (decrease) in capital is associated with an increase (decrease) of 0.8 (0.3) percentage points in credit growth upon impact and 1.6 (0.6) percentage points in the long-run. Capital is followed in importance by profits. Liquidity only seems to affect aggregate credit growth significantly in countries where smaller banks are important. These results are robust to the definition used to measure banks' financial positions and economic conditions, and are robust to considering the organization of the bank sector in each country. The failure of the exogeneity assumption of explanatory variables is addressed using the system GMM estimator from the dynamic panel literature. The use of this estimator for a "square" panel, instead of a "short" panel as originally devised, presents technical challenges that are discussed in the paper.

The paper is related to the literature on the determinants of banks' credit growth. This topic received considerable attention after the US recession of the early 90s, which coincided with a decline in banks' credit. Sharpe (1995) provides a very comprehensive survey of this work and discusses the extent to which the slowdown in credit growth was a result of weaknesses in banks' balance sheets, increased capital requirement or more stringent regulatory practices. The author concludes that the evidence shows a robust link between credit growth and both loan performance and bank profitability, although the causality of this relationship is not clear. The studies surveyed by Sharpe mostly analyze cross-sections of banks. In contrast, the results presented here use a panel of countries, adding to this literature in two dimensions. First, it investigates the generality of previous findings analyzing a single country. Second, the use of dynamic panel estimation techniques provides a nice alternative for the identification problem in this literature.

The use of a panel of countries to study bank-related questions is not new, but this is the first work to analyze the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth using this type of dataset. Ferreira (2009) used a panel of 26 EU countries, with quarterly observations between 1991 and 2006, to study the evolution of lending as a fraction of GDP and the lending channel of monetary policy. On the other hand, Levintal (2013) used a panel 28 OECD countries, with yearly observations for 1980-2003, to analyze the real effects of banking shocks. Levintal uses the same data source for bank information as this paper and identifies three types of bank shocks: profitability, capital, and reserves. He finds that profits, measured by ROA, is the bank shock with the most significant real effect. In contrast, the present paper ascribes the biggest explanatory power predicting credit growth to banks' equity capital. Thus, to the extent that the real effect of bank shocks operates through credit the result of the present study is at odds with the evidence presented by Levintal (2013). Furthermore, both studies cited above use "square" panels and so are subject to the methodological issues discussed in here.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 considers the specification of the economic model with a discussion about the variables that should be included in the model. Section 3 presents the data used in the econometric analysis. Section 4 discusses the econometric specification of the model with a discussion of how the system GMM estimator is used to address the dynamic panel bias and the failure of the exogeneity assumption of the variables included in the model. It presents the main results of the paper and analyzes in detail the estimated effects of banks' financial position on credit growth. Section 5 presents robustness checks to the main results, and section 6 concludes.


2 Model Specification

This section reviews the determinants of credit growth to inform the selection of the variables to be included in the model. The focus of the paper is on the effect of banks' financial position, which will be measured both from balance sheet and income statements. In particular, the effect of: (i) profits; (ii) equity capital; and (iii) liquidity, will be estimated. Additional variables are included to control for the time series structure of loan growth, economic conditions and the organization of the bank sector. The definition and rationale for all these variables is discussed below.

Time series structure: The dependent variable is the growth rate of outstanding loans, defined as the log change in outstanding loans, $$ {\Delta\ell}_t = \log L_t - \log L_{t-1}$$. Using loan growth is standard in the literature and has the advantages over using loans in level of being stationary. It is expected that loan growth depends on past values, as outstanding loans do not fully adjust in a year, which is the frequency of the dataset. Thus, $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ will depend on its own lags.

In order to specify the other variables that will be included in the model, it is helpful to start with the following simplified version of a bank balance sheet:

Assets Liabilities
$$ L_t + L^{\text{IB}}_t + \text{Sec}_t + M_t$$ $$ D_t + D^{\text{IB}}_t + E_t$$
where Lt stands for loans, superscript IB for inter-banks, Sec$$ _t$$ for securities, Mt for cash or money holdings, Dt for deposits and Et for equity. All variables measured at the end of period t. Moreover, let At be the size of the bank balance sheet or total assets or liabilities, and $$ \delta_t$$ denote the ratio of loans to asset, $$ \delta_t = \frac{L_t}{A_t}$$. Using these definitions we have that,1
$$\displaystyle {\Delta\ell}_t = \log\Biggl( \frac{ L_t }{ L_{t-1} } \Biggr) = \log\Biggl( \frac{ \delta_t A_t }{ \delta_{t-1} A_{t-1} } \Biggr) = \Delta \log \delta_t + \Delta a_t$$ (1)

This is, the growth rate of loans can be decomposed into changes in bank's portfolio and the growth rate of assets. In practice any given variable can affect theses two margins, but for expositional purposes it will be helpful to consider them separately. The growth rate of assets, ceteris paribus and assuming the bank business is profitable, will depend on the availability of funds, which typically come from equity and deposits. The portfolio decision, in turn, will depend on funding costs and expected returns, which will be given by economic conditions.

Banks financial position: Profits are one source of new equity. Let Yt be banks (after tax) profits in year t and assume that these profits are used to increase the banks equity capital keeping the same leverage. Let $$ \lambda_t$$ be banks' leverage at the end of year t, equal to the ratio of assets to equity, $$ \frac{A_t}{E_t}$$. Thus, the increase in assets from these profits, $$ \Delta A^*$$, is given by,2

$$\displaystyle \Delta A^* = (E^* - E_t) \frac{A^* - A_t}{E^* - E_t} = Y_t \lambda_t$$   or$$\displaystyle \qquad \Delta a^* = \frac{ Y_t }{ A_t } \lambda_t $$
This is the increase in log assets is the return on assets (ROA) times leverage, or simply the return on equity (ROE). However, when equity at year-end is negative, $$ E_t < 0$$, leverage is not defined and the previous expression does not hold. In this case the bank sector is insolvent and it will be assumed that profits are used to rebuild banks' equity. In other words, we can think of the bank as a net debtor, who will use new profits to pay these debts first and therefore we expect no effect on the size of the balance sheet. Banks' equity capital may play a key role on balance sheet expansion, as emphasized in the literature. In general, external funds for balance sheet expansion may come from the issuance of equity, debt or deposits. The literature emphasizes the role of banks's equity capital on funding costs by alleviating the moral hazard problem of bank managers (Holmstrong and Tirole, 1997). Thus, it is expected that banks with higher ratios of equity to assets will be able to raise new funds at lower costs. Moreover, minimum capital requirement limit banks' ability to expand their balance sheets. Therefore, we would expect a nonlinear effect of capital ratios due to regulation thresholds (cf. Peek and Rosengren 1995; and Thakor, 1996). Finally, liquidity will also play a key role in the growth of credit as selling securities is a cheaper source of funds given adverse selection problems. In fact, Stein (1998) shows that loan sales and uninsured liabilities involve higher funding costs due to adverse selection problems as the bank has private information about their loan portfolio. It follows that banks prefer to fund lending activities by selling securities or issuing insured deposits. Therefore, the growth rate of loans may depend on availability of liquid assets and the costs of insured deposits. Kashyap and Stein (2000) measure the former as balance sheet liquidity, $$ {\text{BSL}}_{it}$$, defined as the ratio of securities to assets. The evidence suggests that small banks are more sensitive to this adverse selection costs, therefore liquidity measures interacted with the fraction of small to total banks' assets at the country level, are also to be considered.3On the other hand, the cost of deposits will depend on economic conditions which are discussed below.

Economic conditions: will affect the costs of deposits, expected returns on different investments and the demand for credit. The cost of deposits could be proxied as the ratio of total interest expenses to total deposits.4Alternatively, the costs of deposits could be measured directly as the interest rate on deposits.

Expected returns on loans versus other type of assets will affect the portfolio decision. Bernanke and Blinder (1988) stress the dependence of this margin on interest rates, both on loans and on alternative investments (government bonds in the model). Another alternative is to invest in securities, which expected returns could be proxied by the return on domestic security markets. The expected return on loans depends on the interest rate and on the probability of borrower's default, the latter could be controlled for by the ratio of loans provisions to outstanding loans. This is the mechanism emphasized by the literature on the credit risk channel. Finally, Tobin (1982) highlights the dependence of the portfolio choice on the cost of banks' deposits, which were discussed above.

The business cycle will affect both the demand for credit and lending standards. Credit demand will be given by private and government consumption and investments decisions which are partially financed with credit. Finally, the bank literature also shows that banks change their lending standards over the business cycle.5

Organization of the bank sector: The banking literature identify other variables that may affect the growth of loans at the country level. First, the literature on bank efficiency identify a potential role for bank size and diversification. At the aggregate level bank size could be proxy by the ratio of banks' assets to GDP. On the other hand, we can use the fact that larger banks take more risk to use the ratio of large bank assets to total banks assets as a measure of both diversification and economies of scale in lending activities.This ratio of large banks assets to total banks assets may affect aggregate lending just by a composition effect as the evidence for the US have found that larger banks hold smaller fraction of loans to total assets.6

Finally, it is important to bear in mind that several variables affect loan growth through more than one channel something that needs to be considered when interpreting the results.


3 Data

This section describes the data used in the econometric analysis, consisting of an unbalanced panel of countries with yearly observations. The sample of countries is determined primarily by availability of banks' information, which is obtained from the OECD Bank Statistics database. This data set reports information for bank groups in each country. The most aggregated group is all banks, which includes: commercial banks, saving banks, cooperative banks, and other miscellaneous monetary institutions. When available information for large commercial banks and foreign commercial banks is reported separately. The subsequent analysis considers information at the country level, therefore the most comprehensive bank group is chosen for each country. Table 1 presents the list of countries present in the OECD Bank Statistics dataset and the bank group selected for the analysis.7Table 1 considers only availability of information on credit growth, when information on all bank variables is considered the total number of observation drops from 726 to 705. Additional information is lost when bank variables are merged with long-term and lending rates leaving a total of 530 country-year observations.8Including domestic stock market returns further reduce the number of observations to 500 and 6 more observations are lost when real variables (GDP, consumption and investment) are included. It should be noted that Turkey and Luxembourg are left out of the analysis because of the information requirements. Turkey does not have information on long-term interest rates, whereas the series on stock market returns and lending rates do not overlap in the case of Luxembourg. As mentioned above it will be assumed that the growth rate of credit depends on its own lagged realization, which will make additional observations to be discarded in the econometric analysis. As Table 2 shows, in the benchmark regression, the number of observations is 480. The Table also lists the sample period by country of the data used in the analysis.

The OECD Bank Statistics database contains data for income statements and balance sheets of bank groups in OECD countries. All figures are in local currency at the end of the period and are transformed to real values using individual countries consumer price indices (CPI).9 Information on outstanding nominal loans for country i at the end of year t, is included in the assets breakdown of the balance sheet as item 16. Using domestic CPI loan series are deflated to obtain real outstanding loans, Lit. Loan growth is defined as the log-difference of real loans, $$ {\Delta\ell}_{it} \equiv \log L_{it} - \log L_{i,t-1}$$ expressed in percents. Table 3 presents mean loan growth by country for the sample of 480 observation used in the econometric analysis. The sample mean of credit growth is 5.8% per year. Ireland presents the largest annual growth of real credit with almost 22% for the period 1997-2005, whereas Mexico exhibit the largest decline in real credit with an average decline of 2.2% per year in 1995-2007.

Profit measures are constructed based on income statements reported in the OECD dataset. Return on equity, (ROE) is defined as the ratio of item 11, after-tax profits, to item 19, capital and reserves, expressed in percents. Capital and reserves is the closest measure of banks' capital reported. Table 3 presents averages by country of $$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$ for the sample used in the estimations below. The sample mean is 8.5%. New Zealand presents the highest average ROE in the sample with almost 17%, whereas Japan presents the lowest with almost -2%. Banks' equity capital, CAP is defined as the ratio of item 19, capital and reserves, to item 25, end-year balance sheet total, expressed in percents. Balance sheet total equals the sum of assets or liabilities at year-end and henceforth it will be referred to as total assets. Table 3 presents means by country of $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$. Considering all country-year observations the mean is 6.1%, whereas taking individual countries it ranges from 3.1% in Belgium to 10.1% in Australia. Likewise, balance sheet liquidity, BSL is defined as item 17, securities in the asset side of the balance sheet at year-end, to total assets (item 25) and it is expressed in percents. Averages for this ratio for individual countries go from 7.1% in Australia to 33.4% in Greece. When all counties are considered the average $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$ is 18.9% (Table 3).

Measures on deposits costs and loan provisions are also calculated using information from the OECD Bank Statistics dataset. DEPOSIT COSTS is defined as the ratio of item 2, interest expenses, to item 22, non-bank deposits.10Non-bank deposits corresponds to deposits held by bank customers as opposed to interbank deposits hold by banks among themselves. Table 4 presents the sample mean for DEPOSIT COSTS considering the sample of 480 observations used in the estimations below: approximately 10%. Since information on loan provisions (item 8.a) is not available for all countries and years, total provisions (item 8) is used instead in the benchmark specification. PROVISIONS is defined as the ratio of total provisions to nominal outstanding loans (item 16). The sample average of this variable is 86 basis points, as reported in Table 4. Loan provisions will be used to check the robustness of the results in section 5.

Economic conditions also include variables collected from other sources. Real effective lending rates are calculated as the difference between nominal lending rates from the IFS, line 60P..ZF... and effective CPI inflation obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators, Prices: Consumer Prices. Real effective long-term interest rates are calculated as the difference between nominal 10 year government bonds or similar and effective CPI inflation. Nominal long term rates are obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators and the IFS.11Real domestic stock market returns are calculated as the log difference of real stock market price indices and expressed in percents. Nominal price indices are obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators and the IFS and deflated using domestic CPI to compute real stock market price indices. Changes in real aggregate demand are calculated as the log difference of real aggregate demand and expressed in percents. Real aggregate demand is defined as the sum of real private and government consumption and investment. All these series are obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators .12

Organization of the bank sector is measured as the ratio of banks' total assets to GDP. GDP figures corresponds to real GDP at 2000 prices published by the OECD. Real total assets at 2000 prices were computed from nominal total assets, deflated by domestic CPI.13Table 4 reports averages by country and for all observations of all these variables. Appendix A provides additional descriptive statistics for all the variables in Tables 3 and 4.


4 Estimation of the Effect of Banks' Financial Position on Credit Growth

This section discusses the econometric issues that arise when estimating the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth and specifies the benchmark econometric model for this analysis. Subsequently, it presents the main results on the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth. First, the effect of profits, capital and liquidity are estimated independently while controlling for economic conditions and the organization of the banking sector. Then, alternative measures for the three dimensions of banks' financial position are considered. Additional robustness checks are provided in section 5.

1 Econometric Specification

Credit growth is defined as the log-difference of real loans, $$ {\Delta\ell}_{it} \equiv \log L_{it} - \log L_{i,t-1}$$. The model to be estimated takes the form:

$$\displaystyle {\Delta\ell}_{it} = \alpha(L) {\Delta\ell}_{it} + \beta' X_{it} + \mu_t + \mu_i + v_{it} \qquad\qquad i = 1, \ldots, N \quad t = 1,\dots,T$$ (2)

where $$ \alpha(L)$$ is a lag polinomial with coeficients to be estimated, $$ \beta$$ is a vector of coeficients to be estimated, Xit is a vector of controls, $$ \mu_t$$ are time effects, $$ \mu_i$$ are country fixed effects and vit is an idiosyncratic shock. The variables to be included in the vector of controls, for country i in year t, follows from the discussion in section 2. It comprises two set of variables $$ X_{it} = \Bigl[ X^{pre}_{it} \ X^{endo}_{it} \Bigr]$$, with $$ X^{pre}_{it}$$ variables that are predetermined at the beginning of period t and $$ X^{endo}_{it}$$ variables that are endogenous to the idiosyncratic shock vit, given by,
$$\displaystyle X^{pre}_{it} = \left[ \begin{array}{l} {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1} \qquad\qquad {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} \qquad\qquad {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} \qquad\qquad {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1} \\ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1} \qquad\qquad {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1} \qquad\qquad {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1} \end{array} \right]$$    
$$\displaystyle X^{endo}_{it} = \left[ \begin{array}{l} {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it} \qquad\qquad {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it} \\ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it} \qquad\qquad {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{i,t} \end{array} \right]$$    

The first set of predetermined variables measure banks' financial position at the end of the previous year. Return on equity, $$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$ measures banks' profits. The ratio of equity capital to assets, $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ measures capital and the square of this variable is included to estimate potential nonlinear effects of banks' capital around regulatory thresholds. Finally, balance sheet liquidity, $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$ is measured as the ratio of securities to assets. Other variables control for economic conditions and the organization of the bank sector.

The identification strategy relies on two assumptions. First, it is assumed that predetermined variables and the lagged value of credit growth $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$ are weakly exogenous; whereas contemporaneous variables are endogenous. This is,

$$\displaystyle \mathbb{E}\bigl( v_{it} \big\vert {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}, X^{pre}_{it}, {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}, X_{i,t-1}, \ldots, {\Delta\ell}_{i1}, X_{i1}\bigr) = 0$$ (Assumption 1)

Second, it is assumed that the idiosyncratic shocks are serially uncorrelated:
$$\displaystyle \mathbb{E}[v_{it}v_{i,t-1}] = 0$$ (Assumption 2)

Note that Assumption 1 does not rule out that the idiosyncratic disturbance, vit could be correlated with future predetermined and contemporaneous endogenous variables. Nor does it rule out that banks can change their income or balance sheet statements, according to their expectation of future credit growth, as long as their expectations are not correlated with the error term. In other words, Assumption 1 says that when banks form their expectations about future credit growth, they do not know anything about future shocks. In model (2) the growth rate of loans depends on its own lagged value and the country considered causing a dynamic panel bias in the estimation. This renders OLS estimates biased. In fact, if we consider model (2) with a disturbance, $$ \varepsilon_{it} = \mu_i + v_{it}$$ then the coefficient on lagged credit growth will be positively biased, as the estimation will attribute predictive power to this variable that belongs to the country fixed effect in the error term. On the contrary, if we estimate the model using the within group (i.e. fixed effects) estimator, the bias will be negative due to the within group transformation. Although biased the fact that both estimates are biased in opposite directions provides a useful benchmark for theoretically superior estimators (Bond, 2002). Table 5 reports estimated coefficient for model (2) with 1 lag of the dependent variable, using OLS and FE. The coefficient on lagged credit growth is statistically significant in both specifications and these estimates imply an interval for its value between 0.19 and 0.32 (columns 1 and 2). Both ROE and BSL have positive signs and only the latter appears statistically significant in the specifications with country effects. The second order polynomial on equity capital, $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ is jointly statistically significant at the 5% level in the FE estimation, with only $$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$ significant at the 10% level. This suggest the presence of nonlinear effect for this variable on credit growth, as expected. Other coefficients have the expected signs. One exception is real LONG TERM RATE which displays a positive sign and it is statistically significant. Another exception is the estimated coefficient on ASSETS/GDP which turns negative when country effects are taken into account and the coefficient is statistically significant. Contemporaneous changes in aggregate demand are statistically significant, but this might be the result of the endogeneity of this variable. Perhaps more surprising is that contemporaneous stock returns and lending rates are not significant when country effects are considered. The dynamic panel bias is inversely proportional to the panel's length, T. This is, it is larger for shorter panels, i.e. when the temporal dimension, T is small. Table 2 shows that the average time length is 16.6 years with a maximum of 28 years, which is not in the "small" range for T. Thus, this bias is not the main econometric concern in the estimation of this model. Nonetheless, the techniques to address this bias will serve to address the endogeneity problem or more generally the failure of the strict exogeneity assumption of the variables included in Xit, which is the main econometric challenge here. In general, there are two approaches to address the dynamic panel bias. The methods proposed in the literature to solve the dynamic panel bias rely on constructing suitable sets of instrumental variables under assumptions 1 and 2, using past information of the existing variables for this. The first approach discussed below consists of transforming the model by taking first differences, yielding the difference GMM estimator. Next, the system GMM estimator is discussed which combines the former with using suitable instruments for the model in levels. The latter approach is best suited in cases where some variables are highly persistent as the case at hand.

Arellano-Bond (1991) propose a difference GMM estimator for dynamic panels. The idea is to take first differences of model (2) and then instrument for endogenous variables in the transformed model. Differencing the model gives,

$$\displaystyle \Delta^2 \ell_{it} = \alpha \Delta^2 \ell_{i,t-1} + \beta' \Delta X_{it} + \Delta \mu_t + \Delta v_{it}$$ (3)

where $$ \Delta^2 \ell_{it} = {\Delta\ell}_{it} - {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$. This transformation eliminates fixed effects, but makes $$ \Delta^2 \ell_{i,t-1}$$ endogenous, as $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$ is correlated with $$ v_{i,t-1}$$ in the new disturbance $$ \Delta v_{it}$$. Similarly, any predetermined variable become endogenous. In fact, for predetermined variable x, the term $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ in $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ will be correlated with $$ v_{i,t-1}$$. But $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ ( $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$) will be a suitable instrument for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ ( $$ \Delta^2 \ell_{i,t-1}$$) as it is correlated with it and independent of $$ v_{i,t-1}$$ by Assumption 1. Deeper lags of x ( $$ \Delta \ell$$) will also be candidate instruments, as $$ \Delta x_{i,t-1}$$ ( $$ \Delta^2 \ell_{i,t-2}$$) and deeper lags of it will be as well. The standard way of using $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ as an instrument is to consider the vector,

$$\displaystyle \left[ \begin{array}{c} \cdot \ x_{i,1} \ \vdots \ x_{i,T-1} \ \end{array} \right] $$
where "$$ \cdot$$" denote a missing value. This procedure is also referred as instrumenting in IV style. One of the shortcommings of this approach is that each additional instruments comes at the burden of reducing the sample size, as each additional lag forces to drop one time period. In contrast, in GMM framework it is possible to use $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ to build a set of instruments with one instrument for each time period and substituting zeros for missing observations, giving rise to meaningful instrument moment conditions. This approach generates a matrix of instruments of the form:

$$\displaystyle \left[ \begin{array}{cccc} 0 & 0 & \cdots & 0 \ x_{i,1} & 0 & \cdots & 0 \ 0 & x_{i,2} & \cdots & 0 \ \vdots & \vdots & \ddots & \vdots \ 0 & 0 & \cdots & x_{i,T-1} \ \end{array} \right] $$
Replacing missing with zeros there is no longer a trade-off between number of instruments and number of observations; thus, it is common practice in the literature of dynamic panels to include as many instruments as possible. The number of instruments equals the number of columns of the matrix of instruments. For the lagged dependent variable instrumenting in GMM-style using $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ will generate T-2 instruments.14Additional lags will generate $$ T-3,\ T-4, \ldots, 1$$ additional instruments. Therefore, using all available lags to construct the set of instrumental variables makes the number of instruments quadratic in T. The same is the case for any other variable that is to be instrumented. This will generate too many instruments in the case of "square" panels like the one studied here, which could be problematic. First, a large number of instruments can overfit endogenous variables (Roodman, 2006). In fact, in the extreme case where the number of instruments equal the number of observations the instrument set will span the space of the explanatory variables, causing the projection of the endogenous variable in the instrument space to equal itself, violating the instrumental variable assumption. Second, too many instruments cause numerical problems in the estimation affecting the accuracy of the estimates. Third, it weakens the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions leading to its non-rejection (Bowsher, 2002).

There are two ways around the problem of too many instruments which will be considered below. The first one is to restrict the number of lags to be used as instruments. The second consist of collapsing the set of instruments to get one instrument per instrumental variable. The latter combines elements of the IV and GMM style, as it builds a single instrumental variable using $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ but still replaces missing with zeros. This gives a single instrument using $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ as instrument:

$$\displaystyle \left[ \begin{array}{c} 0 \ x_{i,1} \ \vdots \ x_{i,T-1} \ \end{array} \right] $$

As discussed above, when xit is a predetermined variable lags one and up are suitable instruments for the differenced model (3). In contrast, when xit is an endogenous variable suitable instruments are the second and deeper lags of the variable. In fact, in this case the term $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ is correlated with $$ v_{i,t-1}$$ and therefore $$ x_{i,t-1}$$ will not be a suitable instrument for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$, but $$ x_{i,t-2}$$ is still independent of $$ v_{i,t-1}$$ and could be used as an instrument. Deeper lags of $$ x_{i,t-2}$$ and $$ \Delta x_{i,t-2}$$ and deeper lags of it will also be valid instruments.

Estimations using difference GMM are reported in Table 5 columns 3 to 6. Column 3 presents estimates that use 2 lags of explanatory variables as instruments in GMM style. The estimated coefficient is in the lower range of the interval [0.19, 0.32], but the number of instruments is almost equal to the number of observations. With 6 lags in GMM style, the number of instruments is greater than the number of observation, but the algorithm limits the number of instruments by the number of observations. Estimated coefficients are very similar to the FE estimates, as was to be expected by the use of as many instruments as observations. Collapsing the set of instruments, using 2 and 6 lags of each explanatory variable yields instrument sets with 52 and 100 elements, respectively (columns 5 and 6). This yields a more reasonable number of instruments, but the coefficient on lagged credit growth falls outside the desired interval and there are other problems that suggests the model is poorly specified. Indeed, the Sargan tests rejects the joint validity of the moment restrictions.15Moreover, the Arellano-Bond test for the independence of the idiosyncratic disturbances-Assumption 2-is rejected, suggesting serial correlation of the innovations of model (2). This assumption was key in the construction of the appropriate instrument sets. Arellano and Bond (1991) shows how to construct a test statistics under the null of serial independence, that converges to a normal distribution when the number of panels, N is large. The procedure consist of testing for second order serial correlation in the differenced residuals to test for first order serial correlation on the original disturbances. The p-values for this tests are reported in all the GMM regressions for first and second order serial correlation in the original disturbances, AR(2) and AR(3) for the differenced residuals, respectively. For example, using 6 collapsed lags as instruments this test indicate first order serial correlation at the 5% significance level, but cannot reject that there is no serial correlation of second order for the original disturbances. There are two ways to take this time series pattern into account. One is to construct the instrument set starting with lag t-2 and t-3, respectively for predetermined and endogenous variables. However, following this approach seems to weaken the instruments significantly.16Another is to enrich the time series specification of the variables in the model, so the innovations become serially uncorrelated, as we do below including an additional lag for credit growth to the model.

Table 6 reports the estimates using OLS, FE and difference GMM of model (2) including 2 lags of credit growth as explanatory variables. Now the Arellano-Bond tests cannot reject the null of serially uncorrelated innovations. With 2 lags of the dependent variable we expect the sum of the coefficients in the $$ \alpha(L)$$ polynomial to be upward and downward biased, respectively in the case of OLS and FE. Therefore, all models report the sum of the estimated coefficients on $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$ and $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ to facilitate comparison. As it was the case before OLS and FE estimates provide a useful benchmark to asses the performance of theoretically superior estimators, [0.36,0.48] in this case. Now the model seems better specified. The sum of these coefficients is in the desired range and the diagnostics tests do not reject the serial independence of the innovations or the joint validity of the moment restrictions. The coefficients of the FE estimator are similar as before and the joint test on the coefficients of CAP is rejected at the 5% confidence level. Figure 1 panel (a) plots the estimated effect of $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ on credit growth based on the FE estimates. Point estimates of the FE model imply that an increase of one standard deviation in the ratio of bank capital to assets at the sample mean of 6.1% will increase credit growth by 72 basis points upon impact and 1.13 percentage point in the long-run.

Despite the fact, that the difference GMM estimates pass the validations of the diagnostics checks indicated above, there are some signs of problems, as most coefficients are not significant. The problem with the difference GMM estimator in this case is originated by the use of persistent individual series. Bond (2002) recommends investigating the time series properties of all the series being used in the estimation and suggests using system GMM when they are found to be highly persistent. Appendix B analyze the time series properties of the individual series. BSL and ASSETS/GDP are found to be highly persistent with estimated coefficients for the autoregressive term between 0.81 and 0.93, and 0.98 and 1.04, respectively.

The system GMM estimator uses both the differenced and level equations, "doubling" the number of observations used in the estimation. The way right-hand side variables are instrumented for in the difference equations is the same as in difference GMM. For the level equations, right-hand side variables are instrumented by their differences, which are assumed independent of the individual effects. For example, for $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$ a valid instrument will be $$ \Delta^2 \ell_{i,t-1}$$, as it is assumed not correlated with the fixed effect and correlated with $$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$. Similarly, for a variable xit which is predetermined, $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ will be a valid instrument as it is assumed not correlated with the fixed effect and correlated with xit. Deeper lags of them will also be valid instruments. For endogenous variables $$ \Delta x_{i,t-1}$$ and deeper lags may be used as instruments.

Column 5, system GMM with 2 collapsed lags seems the best fit for the model. LENDING RATE and $$ {\Delta \text {AGG. DEMAND}}$$ are significant, and LONG TERM RATE and ASSETS/GDP have the desired signs. The sum of the coefficient on lagged credit growth is on the upper part of the desired range and the diagnostics tests do not reject neither joint validity of moment restriction nor the serial uncorrelation of the innovations. The estimated effects of banks' financial position yields CAP as the only significant variable. In fact the coefficient on the linear term is significant at the 10% level and the linear and quadratic terms are jointly significant at the 5% level. This nonlinear effect will depend on the initial level of the ratio of equity to assets (Figure 1 panel b). For instance, starting at the sample mean of 6.1% the effect of an increase (decrease) of one standard deviation in CAP is an increase (decrease) of 0.8 (0.3) percentage points in the growth rate of credit.17The presence of lagged credit growth in the model imply that the long-run effect will be the previous effect times $$ \frac{1}{1-\alpha(L)}$$, i.e. an associated increase (decrease) in credit growth in the long-run of 1.6 (0.6) percentage points. The coefficient on ROE displays the right sign, but it does not seem to have neither a statically or economically significant effect on credit growth. Balance sheet liquidity, BSL, have a negative sign in contrast to what was expected. Deposit costs at the end of the previous year and contemporaneous lending rates, stock returns and aggregate demand growth are all significant with the expected signs. The implied effects on credit growth of this point estimates from a one standard deviation increase are: DEPOSIT COSTS (ratio of interest expenses to deposits) -2.76 percentage points; LENDING RATE 4.72 percentage points; STOCK RETURNS 5.01 percentage points; and the growth rate of aggregate demand, $$ {\Delta \text {AGG. DEMAND}}$$ 1.01 percentage points.18

2 Effect of Banks' Financial Position

Having specified the benchmark specification it is now possible to study in more detail the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth. Three aspects will be considered. First, the individual effect of each variable that measures banks' financial positions will be considered. Then, it will be analyzed the effect of different measures of profits, liquidity and capital, respectively. Finally, the next section presents some robustness checks. Table 7 presents the results when banks' variables are included one at a time to investigate the significance of each one separately and potential non-linear effect of profits and liquidity. The first column presents the benchmark regression results to facilitate comparison. All models use two collapsed lags to construct the instrument set and the system GMM estimator. When only CAP is included in the model, estimates remain qualitatively the same. The joint significance of the linear and quadratic capital terms is affected but they are still significant at the 10% level (column 3). When only ROE is included the estimates are as before. More interesting is the estimation that considers both a linear and a quadratic profit term (column 5). Both of the ROE coefficients are significant at the 10% level, but they are not jointly significant in evidence the individual coefficients were only marginally significant.19When only balance sheet liquidity, BSL is included the coefficient turns bigger in absolute value, but it is still statistically insignificant. No significant effect is found when both a linear and a quadratic BSL term are included. This analysis reinforce the result that CAP is the only significant predictor of subsequent credit growth in this sample, with an effect that is nonlinear as was expected by the presence of capital regulations.

Table 8 reports estimations for different definitions of banks' profits. As detailed above ROE was set to zero when equity was negative. If ROE is defined as the ratio of after tax profits to equity, even when equity is negative results remain unchanged. This was expected as there is only one country-year observation with negative equity, corresponding to the US in 1983 (see Appendix A). Next, return on assets (ROA) at the end of the previous year is considered instead of ROE. Column 3 in Table 8 reports the results for this specification. The coefficient on ROA is positive, but statistically insignificant. When leverage is included as an additional control the estimated coefficient on ROA do not change significantly. But the coefficient associated with CAP do change, but the joint significance of the linear and quadratic terms is not compromised.

Table 9 presents the estimation results for different definitions of banks' liquidity. Once again, to facilitate comparison, the first column presents the benchmark regression results. The second column presents the results of replacing $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$ with the interaction of this variable and SMALL, the fraction of small banks' assets to total assets.20Not all countries reports information to compute this ratio so the regression include only 18 countries and 249 observations. The coefficient on liquidity turns statistically insignificant, in line with previous studies that suggests that liquid assets are a more important funding source for smaller banks. The second order polynomial on capital remains significant and now the linear term is significant by itself at the 1% level. More surprising is the fact, that the coefficient on ROE becomes significant and the coefficient on the lending rate becomes negative. The specification tests show that the joint validity of the moment conditions is rejected, whereas the independence of the original disturbances is not. Column 3 present the benchmark regression estimated with the restricted sample of 249 observations used in the previous regression. Again the joint validity of the moment restrictions is rejected, suggesting that the number of instruments is too large relative to the sample size of 249. Column 4 considers the sum of securities and reserves21to total assets at the end of the previous year as the measure of liquidity. Comparison with the benchmark regression shows that the coefficient on liquidity turns negative, the point estimates of other coefficients do not change significantly, and the results of the test of the significance of coefficients and diagnostics test are the same. The last column presents the estimation when liquidity is measured by the ratio of (non-bank) deposits to total assets at the end of the previous year. Again the coefficient of this measure of liquidity turns negative and the rest of the coefficient are in line with the baseline regression. An exception is ASSETS/GDPwhich changes sign.

Finally, Table 10 presents the results when alternative definitions of banks' capital are included in the model. To account for the non-linearity of the estimated effect of banks' capital, this variable is interacted with different dummy variables. The first one is whether $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ is larger or equal to the 25th percentile of the distribution of CAP in country i. The second one is whether $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ is larger or equal to 4% and the third one whether is larger or equal to 6%. As could be seen from the results reported in Table 10 (columns 2-4) none of this non-linear transformations capture the nonlinear effect of capital as none of the estimated coefficients is significant. The estimated effect of the other variables is in line with the baseline specifications.

This results correspond to countries and may not be compared in a straight forward way to the results from individual banks, as studying aggregate banks balance sheets it is not possible to identify movements between individual institutions. In fact, estimates pick up the multiplier effect of financial transactions. For example, a bank grants a loan to a client, who deposits part of the funds or spend them and the recipient deposits the proceeds in a domestic bank. Then the latter bank may grant a loan with the cycle continuing.


5 Robustness Tests

This section presents robustness tests to the benchmark regression reported above. First, real deposit rates are included instead of the ratio of interest expenses to deposits to control for the cost of deposits. Second, the ratio of large banks' assets to total assets, LARGE, is included to control for the structure of the bank sector. Third, LOAN PROVISIONS, defined as the ratio of provisions on loans to total loans is used instead of PROVISIONS to control for the riskiness of borrowers. Finally, alternative measures to control for real activity are considered. Table 11 presents the first set of robustness checks. Table 12 reports further robustness checks for the way real economic activity is controlled for in the model. Once again the table starts with the benchmark estimation results (column 1). Column 2 considers changes in real GDP, $$ \Delta$$GDP$$ _{it}$$ instead of changes in aggregate demand.

In sum, these robustness checks lend support to the main finding of the paper that banks' equity capital is a significant determinant of subsequent credit growth and that neither profits or liquidity display a significant role at the country level for OECD countries.


6 Conclusions

This paper presented estimates of the effect of banks' financial position on credit growth for a sample of 29 OECD countries. The identification relied on the assumption that country-year innovations to the growth rate of loans are independent of predetermined variables and past values of endogenous variables, and that these innovations are not serially correlated. The paper discussed how to adapt GMM estimators, designed for "short" panels, to the present context where the data is organized in a "square" panel. The main issue is on building suitable instrument sets without using too many instruments that will render the instruments invalid and generate other estimation problems. It was argued that the system GMM estimator was to be preferred due to the presence of highly persistent series and an instrument set using two lags of independent variables collapsed to economize on the number of instruments was chosen. The empirical results shows that among capital, profits and liquidity at the end of the previous year, capital is the most important predictor of credit growth in the current year. The relationship between capital and credit growth is non-linear. Point estimates from the preferred econometric specification imply that at the sample mean a one standard deviation increase (decrease) is associated with an increase (decrease) of 0.8 (0.3) percentage points in credit growth upon impact and 1.6 (0.6) percentage points in the long-run. These results were found robust to the definition of the variables included in the model as well as changes in the set of controls used in the estimation.



References

Arellano, M. & Bond, S. (1991), 'Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations', The Review of Economic Studies 58 (2), 277–297.

Asea, P. & Blomberg, B. (1998), 'Lending cycles', Journal of Econometrics 83 , 89–128.

Bernanke, B. & Blinder, A. (1988), 'Credit, money, and aggregate demand', American Econmic Review Papers and Proceedings 78 , 435–39.

Bond, S.R. (2002), 'Dynamic panel data models: a guide to micro data methods and practice', Portuguese Economic Journal 1 (2), 141–162.

Bowsher, C.G. (2002), 'On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models', Economics Letters 77 , 211–220.

Ferreira, C. (2009), European integration and the credit channel transmission of monetary policy. School of Economics and Management, Technical University Of Lisbon.

Holmstrom, B. & Tirole, J. (1997), 'Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector', Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 , 663–92. International Financial Statistics (IFS) (2016). Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund (accessed on 1 September 2016).

Kashyap, A.K. & Stein, J. (2000), 'What do a million observations on banks say about the transmission of monetary policy?', The American Economic Review 90 (3), 407–428.

Levintal, O. (2013), 'The real e ff ects of banking shocks: Evidence from {OECD} countries', Journal of International Money and Finance 32 , 556–578.

Loutskina, E. & Strahan, P. E. (2009), 'Securitization and the declining impact of bank finance on loan supply: Evidence from mortgage originations', The Journal of Finance 64 (2), 861–889.

Lown, C. & Morgan, D. (2001), The credit cycle and the business cycle: New findings using the survey of senior loan o ffi cers. Federal Reserve Bank of New York, working paper. OECD (2004), 'Bank profitability financial statements of banks: User guide'. http: // www.oecd.org / dataoecd / 63 / 57 / 39071919.pdf . OECD Bank Statistics [discontinued] (Edition 2010). DOI: http: // dx.doi.org / 10.1787 / e556bcae-en (ac- cessed on 1 September 2016). OECD Main Economic Indicators (2016), 'Main economic indicators - complete database'. DOI: http: // dx.doi.org / 10.1787 / data-00052-en (accessed on 1 September 2016).

Peek, J. & Rosengren, E. (1995), 'The capital crunch: Neither a borrower nor a lender be', Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27 (3), 625–638.

Roodman, D. (2006), How to do xtabond2: An introduction to “di ff erence” and “system” gmm in stata. Working Paper 103, Center for Global Development. 21

Schreft, S. & Owens, R. (1991), 'Survey evidence of tighter credit conditions: What does it mean?', Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 77 , 29–34.

Sharpe, S. A. (1995), Bank capitalization, regulation, and the credit crunch: a critical review of the research findings, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 95-20, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. URL: http: // ideas.repec.org / p / fip / fedgfe / 95-20.html

Stein, J.C. (1998), 'An adverse-selection model of bank asset and liability management with implications for the transmission of monetary policy', RAND Journal of Economics 29 (3), 466–486.

Thakor, A.V. (1996), 'Capital requirements, monetary policy, and aggregate bank lending: theory and em- pirical evidence', Journal of Finance 51 (1), 279–324.

Tobin, J. (1982), 'The commercial banking firm: A simple model', Scandinavian Journal of Economics 84 (4), 495–530.

Weinberg, J. (1995), 'Cycles in lending standards?', Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 81 , 1–18.

Appendix

1 Descriptive Statistics of Main Variables

The model to be estimated is given in equation (2). Recall $$ {\Delta\ell}_{it} = \alpha {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + \beta' X_{i,t} + \mu_t + \mu_i + v_{it}$$,. Here I present descriptive statistics for the variables Sample according to availability of information model (2).



Table A.1: Descriptive Statistics for Credit Growth by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics and OECD Main Economic Indicators.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 5.711 -20.933 32.421 11.584
Austria 5.990 5.329 6.650 0.934
Belgium 3.976 -5.812 14.950 4.482
Canada 3.628 -2.244 12.314 4.010
Chile 7.093 -2.092 14.543 5.215
Czech Republic 2.011 -8.000 13.552 8.701
Denmark 5.244 -11.747 20.829 8.182
Finland 2.369 -16.775 33.663 11.687
France 1.255 -9.579 6.575 4.168
Germany 4.572 -3.734 9.845 2.984
Greece 13.733 -2.059 43.961 12.271
Hungary 13.757 7.276 24.391 5.195
Iceland 13.134 0.091 36.726 11.987
Ireland 21.998 3.607 48.989 15.727
Italy 4.826 -3.094 12.803 4.605
Japan -1.056 -10.214 3.597 3.497
Korea 12.331 -23.941 42.042 13.408
Mexico -2.156 -15.492 14.075 9.874
Netherlands 6.768 -10.407 25.206 9.322
New Zealand 8.270 4.884 13.115 2.422
Norway 7.509 -8.376 22.119 7.550
Poland 6.805 0.690 20.959 7.604
Portugal 10.508 -5.987 23.041 9.589
Slovak Republic 4.234 -27.145 22.349 17.626
Spain 5.194 -9.749 11.833 5.292
Sweden 4.110 -23.421 21.980 10.602
Switzerland 3.289 -11.442 14.617 5.513
United Kingdom 9.240 -3.652 42.383 11.132
United States 2.575 -13.480 14.648 5.817
All 5.812 -27.145 48.989 9.092



Table A.2: Descriptive Statistics for ROE1 by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

1 ROE defined as zero when equity is negative.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 9.152 -0.913 35.149 8.414
Austria 8.003 7.603 8.402 0.565
Belgium 9.267 3.555 21.667 4.073
Canada 12.720 4.963 16.834 2.668
Chile 13.011 8.844 15.691 1.974
Czech Republic 9.744 0.755 14.147 5.212
Denmark 6.774 -21.384 25.622 9.676
Finland 0.014 -49.504 24.228 19.523
France 6.150 -1.291 10.283 3.808
Germany 6.114 3.696 8.894 1.084
Greece 14.109 7.045 21.901 3.939
Hungary 15.414 10.529 19.884 3.620
Iceland 8.737 -0.883 14.852 4.750
Ireland 13.356 10.452 15.937 1.526
Italy 7.307 1.208 12.842 3.306
Japan -1.992 -22.388 15.085 12.182
Korea -0.023 -79.028 18.174 24.044
Mexico 6.920 -5.008 20.079 7.252
Netherlands 10.864 -11.195 18.023 6.267
New Zealand 16.752 6.839 23.283 4.244
Norway 5.033 -113.774 17.897 25.325
Poland 10.240 4.742 16.572 4.742
Portugal 7.084 5.770 9.528 1.227
Slovak Republic 12.174 -29.391 26.495 18.135
Spain 8.600 1.356 11.697 2.072
Sweden 9.999 2.052 39.752 8.498
Switzerland 8.415 0.308 16.402 3.671
United Kingdom 13.102 1.117 21.013 5.898
United States 9.698 0.000 14.043 4.197
All 8.536 -113.774 39.752 10.692



Table A.3: Descriptive Statistics for Capital (ratio of Equity to Assets) by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

Note: p25 = 25th percentile.

Country mean min p25 max st. dev.
Australia 10.096 7.063 9.918 12.344 1.196
Austria 4.621 4.504 4.504 4.737 0.164
Belgium 3.071 2.384 2.545 3.957 0.514
Canada 5.279 4.185 5.099 5.877 0.411
Chile 8.517 7.276 8.316 9.199 0.459
Czech Republic 8.483 6.013 8.202 10.643 1.695
Denmark 7.628 5.512 6.542 9.930 1.352
Finland 6.820 5.044 6.126 10.823 1.622
France 4.260 3.124 3.996 5.064 0.539
Germany 3.793 3.271 3.557 4.242 0.310
Greece 5.732 2.443 4.552 9.886 2.343
Hungary 9.326 8.999 9.088 9.785 0.262
Iceland 7.321 6.410 6.734 7.980 0.600
Ireland 5.911 4.985 5.690 6.681 0.582
Italy 6.435 3.887 6.116 8.035 0.965
Japan 3.951 2.837 3.338 5.260 0.665
Korea 5.775 3.583 4.098 8.867 1.874
Mexico 7.349 5.298 6.389 9.713 1.256
Netherlands 3.878 2.668 3.605 4.601 0.524
New Zealand 5.700 3.676 4.805 7.686 1.218
Norway 5.457 2.904 4.544 7.295 1.245
Poland 9.492 8.348 9.151 10.204 0.694
Portugal 9.863 8.227 9.012 11.584 1.029
Slovak Republic 7.325 3.733 4.808 13.049 2.970
Spain 7.862 6.564 7.222 9.472 0.704
Sweden 5.762 4.268 5.342 7.163 0.796
Switzerland 5.904 4.531 5.622 6.807 0.661
United Kingdom 4.560 3.256 4.051 5.995 0.715
United States 6.730 -11.666 5.543 10.345 4.058
All 6.087 -11.666 4.481 13.049 2.234



Table A.4: Descriptive Statistics for Balance Sheet Liquidity (BSL, ratio of securities to assets) by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 7.096 3.457 10.048 1.823
Austria 16.025 15.956 16.094 0.098
Belgium 29.528 23.251 34.169 2.485
Canada 17.304 10.224 26.325 5.343
Chile 16.060 10.811 18.998 2.686
Czech Republic 23.766 20.422 26.887 2.389
Denmark 24.411 18.335 29.137 3.627
Finland 16.673 8.471 23.459 4.572
France 16.710 7.789 22.866 4.940
Germany 17.598 12.352 23.981 3.638
Greece 33.412 28.895 36.661 2.411
Hungary 16.430 14.107 18.731 1.692
Iceland 13.562 9.330 19.061 2.940
Ireland 23.902 19.189 29.521 3.961
Italy 14.829 9.132 22.755 4.208
Japan 19.669 14.343 27.225 4.925
Korea 17.291 12.491 24.983 3.265
Mexico 26.933 15.634 33.526 6.694
Netherlands 21.291 11.601 30.992 5.450
New Zealand 11.114 5.436 20.354 4.288
Norway 15.747 8.100 34.108 7.802
Poland 22.104 20.396 23.218 1.033
Portugal 21.373 15.000 27.348 3.973
Slovak Republic 25.821 14.275 36.199 6.663
Spain 18.756 12.621 24.787 3.224
Sweden 21.514 11.579 29.731 5.432
Switzerland 14.995 9.636 23.524 4.822
United Kingdom 14.950 6.944 20.924 5.029
United States 19.119 13.943 23.386 3.373
All 18.924 3.457 36.661 6.833



Table A.5: Descriptive Statistics for Deposit Cost (ratio of interest expenses to deposits) by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 8.758 5.860 16.371 3.434
Austria 8.607 8.531 8.683 0.107
Belgium 20.617 9.881 30.662 5.659
Canada 6.998 2.823 11.909 2.705
Chile 11.880 5.509 20.631 5.383
Czech Republic 4.129 2.597 6.514 1.567
Denmark 10.115 5.795 14.292 2.913
Finland 9.517 3.611 16.466 4.041
France 21.712 11.786 31.949 6.392
Germany 9.316 7.219 12.288 1.347
Greece 10.019 4.212 14.074 3.142
Hungary 8.298 6.783 10.822 1.305
Iceland 11.769 6.526 22.087 5.259
Ireland 9.511 7.908 11.460 1.239
Italy 11.190 5.527 17.236 3.199
Japan 2.907 0.339 8.207 2.615
Korea 6.984 3.954 11.871 2.139
Mexico 20.288 9.442 47.965 11.394
Netherlands 9.225 5.599 12.257 1.865
New Zealand 6.863 4.175 11.662 2.255
Norway 9.879 4.655 18.819 3.845
Poland 7.280 4.034 12.997 4.041
Portugal 11.265 8.505 14.163 1.675
Slovak Republic 5.707 2.947 12.361 3.216
Spain 9.180 3.973 12.763 2.462
Sweden 12.141 4.219 21.127 4.475
Switzerland 7.339 3.709 11.212 2.169
United Kingdom 6.881 4.053 11.084 1.883
United States 6.870 2.003 12.947 2.954
All 9.991 0.339 47.965 5.684



Table A.6: Descriptive Statistics for Real Lending Rates1 by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics and OECD Main Economic Indicators.

1 Real effective lending rates calculated as nominal rates minus effective inflation in the year.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 7.060 4.282 10.869 1.931
Austria 5.284 5.069 5.499 0.304
Belgium 6.924 3.922 10.572 1.727
Canada 4.889 1.929 9.283 2.070
Chile 7.133 3.369 15.059 3.492
Czech Republic 4.066 2.449 5.840 1.341
Denmark 7.663 4.627 11.458 1.901
Finland 5.106 2.565 9.217 1.986
France 5.796 4.465 7.589 1.055
Germany 8.101 6.757 9.192 0.658
Greece 9.644 -2.515 16.568 5.625
Hungary 4.165 1.127 6.081 1.515
Iceland 10.466 9.014 11.664 0.847
Ireland 0.997 -0.806 5.153 2.142
Italy 6.517 3.157 11.253 2.614
Japan 2.450 0.531 4.437 1.088
Korea 4.358 2.234 8.583 1.970
Mexico 5.880 1.514 24.433 6.183
Netherlands 2.511 0.671 5.490 1.660
New Zealand 7.904 6.161 9.578 1.122
Norway 6.335 0.543 11.922 2.821
Poland 7.118 4.178 12.952 3.652
Portugal 8.424 2.854 14.529 3.160
Slovak Republic 3.463 -0.095 7.123 2.199
Spain 4.886 0.560 11.114 3.161
Sweden 6.546 2.861 12.826 2.390
Switzerland 2.759 -0.930 4.710 1.239
United Kingdom 4.345 1.012 8.679 1.896
United States 5.194 1.663 8.730 1.864
All 5.725 -2.515 24.433 3.101



Table A.7: Descriptive Statistics for ratio of Total Provisions to Loans by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 0.704 0.141 2.052 0.680
Austria 0.733 0.722 0.744 0.016
Belgium 0.638 -0.079 1.307 0.368
Canada 0.549 0.158 1.331 0.288
Chile 1.111 0.519 2.045 0.438
Czech Republic -1.628 -2.923 0.574 1.408
Denmark 1.959 0.623 3.611 1.017
Finland 0.172 -0.105 0.813 0.278
France 0.870 0.367 1.780 0.466
Germany 0.618 0.200 0.946 0.195
Greece 1.186 0.651 1.866 0.441
Hungary 0.411 -0.084 0.662 0.227
Iceland 1.490 0.947 3.166 0.731
Ireland 0.196 0.076 0.298 0.062
Italy 1.197 0.260 1.823 0.429
Japan 0.564 0.046 1.602 0.500
Korea 1.524 0.585 3.018 0.795
Mexico 1.962 0.946 3.645 0.977
Netherlands 0.305 0.093 0.810 0.166
New Zealand 0.198 -0.141 1.042 0.317
Norway 0.924 -0.161 4.791 1.135
Poland 1.881 0.585 3.088 0.971
Portugal 2.476 1.070 4.867 1.355
Slovak Republic -0.395 -4.010 7.255 3.278
Spain 1.406 0.452 3.151 0.585
Sweden 0.076 -6.792 2.027 1.912
Switzerland 1.001 0.372 1.797 0.399
United Kingdom 0.912 0.307 2.655 0.739
United States 0.761 0.305 1.545 0.371
All 0.864 -6.792 7.255 1.047



Table A.8: Descriptive Statistics for Real Long Term Rates1 by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Main Economic Indicators, IFS, and National Sources.

1 Real effective long term rates calculated as nominal rates minus effective inflation in the year. Nominal long term rates corresponds to 10 year government bonds or similar. For Chile indexed bonds yields are used. Year averages.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 4.835 1.253 8.211 2.230
Austria 3.950 3.791 4.110 0.226
Belgium 4.449 0.566 7.331 1.838
Canada 4.466 1.233 8.405 1.967
Chile 4.571 2.550 7.330 1.720
Czech Republic 2.465 1.568 4.006 1.045
Denmark 5.749 2.412 10.264 2.109
Finland 5.466 2.440 9.053 2.118
France 4.361 1.964 6.701 1.448
Germany 4.326 2.131 6.288 1.113
Greece 3.662 -7.233 9.825 4.351
Hungary 1.432 -1.215 3.186 1.720
Iceland 5.591 2.763 8.000 1.550
Ireland 1.567 -0.079 4.839 1.632
Italy 4.371 1.332 7.997 2.166
Japan 2.098 0.088 3.673 1.066
Korea 4.711 0.862 8.871 2.694
Mexico 4.845 -1.568 16.744 4.321
Netherlands 2.704 0.796 4.976 1.071
New Zealand 4.535 2.122 7.387 1.468
Norway 4.179 -1.344 7.436 2.115
Poland 4.382 3.034 5.451 1.022
Portugal 3.970 2.033 7.289 1.647
Slovak Republic -0.349 -3.696 3.808 2.685
Spain 4.523 1.263 7.956 2.143
Sweden 4.684 1.248 7.788 1.942
Switzerland 1.853 -1.057 4.106 1.185
United Kingdom 4.206 0.977 6.707 1.433
United States 3.872 0.897 8.138 1.906
All 4.010 -7.233 16.744 2.303



Table A.9: Descriptive Statistics for Real Stock Returns by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Main Economic Indicators and IFS.

Note: Computed as the log changes of real stock market indices for domestic markets in each country. All indices deflated by domestic CPIs.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 3.236 -6.930 13.666 6.803
Austria 0.214 -10.571 10.999 15.252
Belgium 7.258 -21.659 35.240 15.062
Canada 3.965 -24.217 28.142 12.499
Chile 2.663 -32.983 27.590 16.487
Czech Republic 14.235 -33.835 40.992 30.287
Denmark 8.933 -21.735 49.235 18.504
Finland 8.229 -57.899 61.773 36.661
France 2.791 -26.417 29.879 18.528
Germany 4.919 -29.558 31.118 18.865
Greece 4.746 -43.945 67.555 30.773
Hungary 4.473 -33.609 43.942 26.845
Iceland 12.757 -38.385 46.953 23.057
Ireland 7.517 -24.900 31.969 18.579
Italy 1.165 -39.873 69.081 26.233
Japan -3.807 -35.093 24.585 18.928
Korea 1.083 -54.076 66.551 28.792
Mexico 9.665 -42.743 34.965 22.416
Netherlands 1.642 -36.478 38.252 23.711
New Zealand 1.412 -33.298 20.973 12.657
Norway 8.587 -25.134 42.439 21.201
Poland 11.236 -33.104 36.536 25.433
Portugal 3.381 -27.630 43.256 24.531
Slovak Republic 14.402 -12.408 69.236 26.099
Spain 6.883 -22.058 62.705 22.421
Sweden 10.666 -37.691 57.308 23.887
Switzerland 5.185 -28.461 33.663 16.974
United Kingdom 3.317 -21.184 20.634 12.746
United States 6.194 -15.271 26.400 11.281
All 5.427 -57.899 69.236 20.635



Table A.10: Descriptive Statistics for Real Aggregate Demand1 by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Main Economic Indicators.

Note: Computed as the log changes of the sum of real private consumption (household and non-profits), real government final consumption and real gross fixed capital formation.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 3.832 0.268 6.111 1.947
Austria 2.282 2.024 2.539 0.364
Belgium 2.014 -0.880 4.503 1.353
Canada 3.038 -1.303 5.315 1.680
Chile 4.576 -4.657 10.219 4.180
Czech Republic 3.234 1.792 4.536 1.130
Denmark 1.893 -3.230 7.291 2.492
Finland 1.692 -6.278 6.297 4.275
France 1.865 -0.560 3.818 1.236
Germany 1.722 -1.752 4.469 1.699
Greece 2.999 -1.141 5.869 2.129
Hungary 3.404 -0.915 9.159 3.437
Iceland 4.088 -2.549 12.425 4.364
Ireland 6.659 3.537 9.185 2.401
Italy 1.452 -4.536 4.557 2.096
Japan 0.923 -2.229 2.975 1.215
Korea 4.118 -15.019 10.001 5.758
Mexico 2.929 -13.258 8.283 5.671
Netherlands 2.213 -3.490 5.316 2.184
New Zealand 3.609 -1.107 7.261 2.296
Norway 2.689 -1.609 6.415 2.207
Poland 2.945 -0.387 6.857 2.584
Portugal 3.855 -0.548 6.553 2.117
Slovak Republic 4.507 -0.598 8.413 3.213
Spain 3.146 -2.748 7.471 2.728
Sweden 1.712 -4.057 4.488 2.074
Switzerland 1.602 -1.708 3.429 1.289
United Kingdom 2.844 -1.676 6.905 1.827
United States 3.214 -0.542 6.202 1.606
All 2.695 -15.019 12.425 2.774



Table A.11: Descriptive Statistics for Assets to GDP by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics and OECD Main Economic Indicators.

Country mean min max st. dev.
Australia 105.178 95.213 118.581 7.749
Austria 247.809 241.259 254.359 9.263
Belgium 291.774 219.571 365.779 35.033
Canada 140.348 110.685 180.169 21.132
Chile 100.584 82.520 136.346 15.642
Czech Republic 109.361 97.288 124.122 11.223
Denmark 114.330 77.119 148.415 20.222
Finland 122.673 97.217 146.150 15.154
France 236.109 224.426 254.429 8.765
Germany 168.793 116.938 268.464 49.278
Greece 69.855 50.866 104.403 20.704
Hungary 73.632 59.700 94.819 13.226
Iceland 88.277 54.556 147.149 35.562
Ireland 337.898 147.228 500.307 116.351
Italy 155.749 117.336 222.295 30.046
Japan 166.883 141.734 225.223 24.361
Korea 94.198 56.608 131.700 27.326
Mexico 46.236 33.261 61.285 8.326
Netherlands 384.141 213.657 597.025 129.745
New Zealand 137.906 103.211 186.810 26.750
Norway 80.465 52.668 159.743 24.827
Poland 57.889 56.830 59.240 1.058
Portugal 148.646 103.170 197.532 36.319
Slovak Republic 85.934 77.060 93.154 6.226
Spain 139.707 105.691 176.582 21.246
Sweden 97.837 69.222 144.522 22.638
Switzerland 409.050 258.519 660.909 119.501
United Kingdom 149.411 73.870 392.820 84.457
United States 93.180 79.512 113.440 12.628
All 160.274 33.261 660.909 108.564


2 Time Series Properties of Individual Variables

Here I present an analysis of the time series properties of the individual series used in the benchmark model. To facilitate comparison dependent variables are the explanatory variables used in the benchmark regressions with the same timing convention and restricting the sample to the sample of model (2).


Table B.1: Estimation of Time Series Process for Credit Growth ( $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$)

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.273***
(0.0811)
0.154*
(0.0832)
0.350***
(0.1000)
0.300***
(0.0970)
0.285***
(0.0976)
0.369***
(0.105)
0.324***
(0.0987)
0.312***
(0.100)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.230***
(0.0766)
0.132**
(0.0534)
0.327***
(0.0816)
0.277***
(0.0659)
0.259***
(0.0666)
0.324***
(0.0866)
0.277***
(0.0727)
0.266***
(0.0735)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.504 0.285 0.678 0.577 0.544 0.693 0.601 0.578
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.219            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.429 0.173 0.0699 0.292 0.188 0.110
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.201 0.345 0.435 0.235 0.409 0.465
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.212 0.262 0.285 0.229 0.276 0.287
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.315 0.247            
Number observations 464 464 448 448 448 464 464 464
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.2: Estimation of Time Series Process for ROE

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.518***
(0.145)
0.427***
(0.0738)
0.493***
(0.105)
0.519***
(0.0831)
0.533***
(0.0825)
0.476***
(0.109)
0.496***
(0.0908)
0.505***
(0.0916)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.0697            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.849 0.858 0.923 0.943 0.956 0.985
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.873 0.894 0.906 0.855 0.872 0.880
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.687 0.681 0.675 0.688 0.683 0.678
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.350 0.273            
Number observations 479 479 463 463 463 479 479 479
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.3: Estimation of Time Series Process for CAPITAL

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.828***
(0.0922)
0.535***
(0.120)
0.341
(0.240)
0.347
(0.242)
0.348
(0.243)
0.359*
(0.193)
0.373*
(0.197)
0.371*
(0.195)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.551            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.042 0.086 0.208 0.147 0.175 0.318
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.001 0.001 0.001 0.005 0.005 0.005
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.005 0.005 0.005 0.006 0.005 0.006
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.696 0.342            
Number observations 480 480 464 464 464 480 480 480
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.4: Estimation of Time Series Process for BSL

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.943***
(0.0159)
0.836***
(0.0342)
1.182***
(0.165)
1.054***
(0.133)
1.051***
(0.134)
1.144***
(0.0743)
1.052***
(0.0574)
1.057***
(0.0606)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.269            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.004 0.002 0.00322 0.0216 0.00312 0.00721
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.434 0.383 0.381 0.442 0.409 0.410
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.646 0.604 0.604 0.628 0.594 0.595
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.896 0.778            
Number observations 480 480 464 464 464 480 480 480
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.5: Estimation of Time Series Process for DEPOSIT COSTS

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.881***
(0.0457)
0.657***
(0.101)
1.139***
(0.201)
1.086***
(0.155)
0.992***
(0.136)
0.766***
(0.169)
0.760***
(0.148)
0.753***
(0.122)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.470            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.223 0.360 0.004 0.082 0.220 0.003
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.395 0.392 0.386 0.255 0.259 0.273
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.731 0.742 0.762 0.792 0.800 0.806
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.855 0.698            
Number observations 477 477 459 459 459 477 477 477
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.6: Estimation of Time Series Process for LENDING RATE

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.745***
(0.0903)
0.517***
(0.115)
0.559***
(0.0878)
0.557***
(0.0957)
0.535***
(0.0994)
0.587***
(0.125)
0.593***
(0.124)
0.585***
(0.125)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.315            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.567 0.915 0.571 0.105 0.338 0.364
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.721 0.719 0.722 0.743 0.744 0.745
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.254 0.236 0.232 0.255 0.247 0.247
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.669 0.509            
Number observations 476 476 473 473 473 476 476 476
Number countries 29 29 28 28 28 29 29 29



Table B.7: Estimation of Time Series Process for PROVISIONS

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.666***
(0.0948)
0.474***
(0.0655)
0.589***
(0.0702)
0.639***
(0.0564)
0.633***
(0.0574)
0.607***
(0.0664)
0.670***
(0.0571)
0.666***
(0.0578)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.405            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.923 0.072 0.194 0.981 0.123 0.282
    Hansen test     0.999 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.591 0.608 0.607 0.606 0.624 0.624
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.211 0.213 0.212 0.200 0.202 0.201
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.509 0.349            
Number observations 479 479 463 463 463 479 479 479
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.8: Estimation of Time Series Process for LONG TERM RATES

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.609***
(0.104)
0.453***
(0.142)
0.591
(0.573)
0.479
(0.375)
0.366
(0.301)
0.735***
(0.216)
0.685***
(0.182)
0.648***
(0.184)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.197            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.019 0.052 0.028 0.080 0.135 0.088
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.888 0.891 0.933 0.862 0.849 0.844
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.261 0.291 0.345 0.254 0.260 0.270
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.642 0.568            
Number observations 470 470 461 461 461 470 470 470
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.9: Estimation of Time Series Process for STOCK RETURNS

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.224***
(0.0742)
0.186***
(0.0439)
0.402*
(0.209)
0.350
(0.218)
0.351
(0.217)
0.477**
(0.212)
0.442**
(0.222)
0.435*
(0.224)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.0966            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.805 0.709 0.910 0.928 0.936 0.982
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.859 0.953 0.949 0.762 0.820 0.832
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.575 0.590 0.591 0.552 0.554 0.554
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.495 0.502            
Number observations 477 477 475 475 475 477 477 477
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.10: Estimation of Time Series Process for $$ {\Delta \text {AGG. DEMAND}}$$

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{i,t-2}$$
0.402***
(0.0949)
0.304***
(0.0703)
0.423**
(0.212)
0.379**
(0.175)
0.375**
(0.167)
0.344*
(0.204)
0.304
(0.187)
0.305
(0.190)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.128            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.284 0.453 0.726 0.335 0.324 0.541
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.987 0.903 0.891 0.822 0.726 0.730
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.655 0.604 0.604 0.584 0.530 0.528
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.323 0.273            
Number observations 479 479 478 478 478 479 479 479
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table B.11: Estimation of Time Series Process for ASSETS/GDP

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE correspond to the within R2. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
difference GMM
4 collapsed
(5) difference GMM 6 collapsed (6) system GMM
2 collapsed
(7)
system GMM
4 collapsed
(8)
system GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-2}$$
1.038***
(0.0115)
0.986***
(0.0182)
0.837***
(0.110)
0.835***
(0.111)
0.833***
(0.110)
1.106***
(0.0219)
1.106***
(0.0230)
1.104***
(0.0229)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ \sigma^2_{\mu_i} / \sigma^2_{v_{it}}$$   0.574            
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions                
    Sargan test     0.086 0.119 0.308 0.034 0.0401 0.081
    Hansen test     1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated                
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     0.229 0.229 0.227 0.252 0.252 0.252
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     0.167 0.166 0.169 0.146 0.146 0.148
Number of instruments     30 32 34 32 34 36
R2 0.985 0.941            
Number observations 479 479 462 462 462 479 479 479
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 29


3 Additional Regressions


Table C.1: System GMM Estimates of the Effect of Bank Financial Position on Credit Growth

residuals serially correlated (order 1) Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and Arellano-Bond regressions eliminate country effects by taking first differences. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ (1) 4 lags (2) 4 collapsed (3) 12 collapsed (4) all collapsed
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.318***
(0.054)
0.308**
(0.126)
0.222***
(0.072)
0.214***
(0.071)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.050
(0.066)
0.117
(0.101)
0.117**
(0.058)
0.054
(0.061)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.074
(0.151)
-1.072
(2.228)
1.722
(2.122)
0.384
(0.718)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.008
(0.016)
0.032
(0.127)
-0.143
(0.142)
-0.031
(0.056)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.076
(0.050)
-0.019
(0.177)
0.006
(0.144)
-0.009
(0.081)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.243**
(0.102)
-0.367*
(0.217)
-0.311*
(0.175)
-0.288**
(0.132)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.068
(0.315)
0.084
(1.263)
0.450
(0.678)
-0.212
(0.450)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
0.424**
(0.177)
0.213
(0.731)
0.324
(0.457)
0.666***
(0.243)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
0.491**
(0.237)
0.465
(0.737)
0.794**
(0.399)
0.396
(0.345)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.044**
(0.017)
0.112
(0.082)
0.074*
(0.040)
0.052***
(0.017)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
1.250***
(0.217)
0.372
(0.452)
0.780***
(0.248)
1.161***
(0.230)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.005
(0.004)
0.004
(0.015)
0.011
(0.010)
0.014*
(0.008)
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = 0$$        
     $$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [p-value] [0.852] [0.777] [0.509] [0.854]
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number observations 480 480 480 480
Number countries 29 29 29 29
Number of instruments 480 73 169 383
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions        
Sargan [p-value] [0.655] [0.363] [0.739] [0.137]
Hansen [p-value] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated        
Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [p-value] [0.003] [0.017] [0.004] [0.004]
Arellano-Bond for AR(3) [p-value] [0.028] [0.095] [0.037] [0.043]


Tables and Figures


Table 1: Bank Groups and sample with information for loan growth by Country

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics.

Notes: *Canada all banks chained with commercial banks for 1982-1987. Greece all banks chained with large commercial banks for 1979-1988. Mexico all banks chained with commercial banks for 1990-1999. US all banks chained with the sum of commercial, saving and cooperative banks for 1979.

        Number of
# Country Bank Group Sample observations
1 Australia All banks 1987-2003 17
2 Austria All banks 1988-2008 21
3 Belgium All banks 1982-2009 28
4 Canada* All banks 1983-2009 27
5 Chile All banks 1991-2009 19
6 Czech Republic All banks 1994-2005 12
7 Denmark All banks 1980-2008 29
8 Finland All banks 1980-2009 30
9 France All banks 1989-2008 20
10 Germany All banks 1980-2008 29
11 Greece* Commercial banks 1980-2009 30
12 Hungary Commercial banks 1995-2008 14
13 Iceland All banks 1980-2003 24
14 Ireland All banks 1996-2008 13
15 Italy All banks 1985-2009 25
16 Japan All banks 1990-2008 19
17 Korea All banks 1991-2008 18
18 Luxembourg All banks 1980-2008 29
19 Mexico* All banks 1991-2009 19
20 Netherlands All banks 1980-2009 30
21 New Zealand All banks 1991-2009 19
22 Norway All banks 1980-2009 30
23 Poland All banks 1994-2008 15
24 Portugal Commercial banks 1980-2008 29
25 Slovak Republic All banks 1997-2009 13
26 Spain All banks 1980-2008 29
27 Sweden All banks 1980-2008 29
28 Switzerland All banks 1980-2008 29
29 Turkey Commercial banks 1982-2009 28
30 United Kingdom Large commercial banks 1985-2008 24
31 United States* All banks 1980-2007 28
All All     726
Average         Average     23.42



Table 2: Number of Observations and Sample Period for Benchmark Regression by Country

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics, OECD Main Economic Indicators, IFS, and National Sources.
  Country Observations Sample Period
1 Australia 13 1991 - 2003
2 Austria 2 1998 - 1999
3 Belgium 25 1983 - 2007
4 Canada 25 1984 - 2008
5 Chile 14 1996 - 2009
6 Czech Republic 5 2001 - 2005
7 Denmark 22 1981 - 2002
8 Finland 16 1988 - 2004
9 France 15 1990 - 2004
10 Germany 22 1981 - 2002
11 Greece 13 1986 - 2003
12 Hungary 8 2001 - 2008
13 Iceland 10 1994 - 2003
14 Ireland 9 1997 - 2005
15 Italy 24 1986 - 2009
16 Japan 18 1991 - 2008
17 Korea 17 1992 - 2008
18 Mexico 12 1995 - 2007
19 Netherlands 16 1994 - 2009
20 New Zealand 17 1992 - 2008
21 Norway 27 1981 - 2008
22 Poland 6 2001 - 2006
23 Portugal 11 1989 - 1999
24 Slovak Republic 8 2000 - 2007
25 Spain 22 1981 - 2002
26 Sweden 25 1981 - 2005
27 Switzerland 28 1981 - 2008
28 United Kingdom 23 1986 - 2008
29 United States 27 1981 - 2007
All All 480 1981 - 2009
Average         Average 16.55 1989.72 - 2005.55
Min         Min 2 1981 - 1999
Max         Max 28 2001 - 2009



Table 3: Bank Variables Means by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics and OECD Main Economic Indicators.

Country $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ $$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$ $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$ $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
Australia 5.711 9.152 10.096 7.096
Austria 5.990 8.003 4.621 16.025
Belgium 3.976 9.267 3.071 29.528
Canada 3.628 12.720 5.279 17.304
Chile 7.093 13.011 8.517 16.060
Czech Republic 2.011 9.744 8.483 23.766
Denmark 5.244 6.774 7.628 24.411
Finland 2.369 0.014 6.820 16.673
France 1.255 6.150 4.260 16.710
Germany 4.572 6.114 3.793 17.598
Greece 13.733 14.109 5.732 33.412
Hungary 13.757 15.414 9.326 16.430
Iceland 13.134 8.737 7.321 13.562
Ireland 21.998 13.356 5.911 23.902
Italy 4.826 7.307 6.435 14.829
Japan -1.056 -1.992 3.951 19.669
Korea 12.331 -0.023 5.775 17.291
Mexico -2.156 6.920 7.349 26.933
Netherlands 6.768 10.864 3.878 21.291
New Zealand 8.270 16.752 5.700 11.114
Norway 7.509 5.033 5.457 15.747
Poland 6.805 10.240 9.492 22.104
Portugal 10.508 7.084 9.863 21.373
Slovak Republic 4.234 12.174 7.325 25.821
Spain 5.194 8.600 7.862 18.756
Sweden 4.110 9.999 5.762 21.514
Switzerland 3.289 8.415 5.904 14.995
United Kingdom 9.240 13.102 4.560 14.950
United States 2.575 9.698 6.730 19.119
All 5.812 8.536 6.087 18.924



Table 4: Economic Conditions Means by Country

(in percents)

Source: Own elaboration based on OECD Bank Statistics, OECD Main Economic Indicators, IFS, and National Sources.

  DEPOSIT PROVI- LENDING LONG-TERM STOCK $$ \Delta$$ AGG. ASSETS
Country COSTS$$ _{i,t-1}$$ SIONS$$ _{i,t-1}$$ RATE$$ _{it}$$ RATE$$ _{it}$$ RETURNS$$ _{it}$$ DEMAND$$ _{it}$$ TO GDP$$ _{it}$$
Australia 8.758 0.704 7.060 4.835 3.236 3.832 105.178
Austria 8.607 0.733 5.284 3.950 0.214 2.282 247.809
Belgium 20.617 0.638 6.924 4.449 7.258 2.014 291.774
Canada 6.998 0.549 4.889 4.466 3.965 3.038 140.348
Chile 11.880 1.111 7.133 4.571 2.663 4.576 100.584
Czech Republic 4.129 -1.628 4.066 2.465 14.235 3.234 109.361
Denmark 10.115 1.959 7.663 5.749 8.933 1.893 114.330
Finland 9.517 0.172 5.106 5.466 8.229 1.692 122.673
France 21.712 0.870 5.796 4.361 2.791 1.865 236.109
Germany 9.316 0.618 8.101 4.326 4.919 1.722 168.793
Greece 10.019 1.186 9.644 3.662 4.746 2.999 69.855
Hungary 8.298 0.411 4.165 1.432 4.473 3.404 73.632
Iceland 11.769 1.490 10.466 5.591 12.757 4.088 88.277
Ireland 9.511 0.196 0.997 1.567 7.517 6.659 337.898
Italy 11.190 1.197 6.517 4.371 1.165 1.452 155.749
Japan 2.907 0.564 2.450 2.098 -3.807 0.923 166.883
Korea 6.984 1.524 4.358 4.711 1.083 4.118 94.198
Mexico 20.288 1.962 5.880 4.845 9.665 2.929 46.236
Netherlands 9.225 0.305 2.511 2.704 1.642 2.213 384.141
New Zealand 6.863 0.198 7.904 4.535 1.412 3.609 137.906
Norway 9.879 0.924 6.335 4.179 8.587 2.689 80.465
Poland 7.280 1.881 7.118 4.382 11.236 2.945 57.889
Portugal 11.265 2.476 8.424 3.970 3.381 3.855 148.646
Slovak Republic 5.707 -0.395 3.463 -0.349 14.402 4.507 85.934
Spain 9.180 1.406 4.886 4.523 6.883 3.146 139.707
Sweden 12.141 0.076 6.546 4.684 10.666 1.712 97.837
Switzerland 7.339 1.001 2.759 1.853 5.185 1.602 409.050
United Kingdom 6.881 0.912 4.345 4.206 3.317 2.844 149.411
United States 6.870 0.761 5.194 3.872 6.194 3.214 93.180
All 9.991 0.864 5.725 4.010 5.427 2.695 160.274



Table 5: Estimations by OLS, Fixed Effects and Difference GMM

(1 lag of $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$)

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) and Difference GMM regressions eliminate country effects by taking differences. R2 for FE corresponds to the within R2. k lags means k lags are used to instrument each explanatory variable, i.e. $$ x_{i,t-1}, \ldots, x_{i,t-k}$$ are used as instruments for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ when xit is a predetermined variable and $$ x_{i,t-2}, \ldots, x_{i,t-1-k}$$ are used as instruments for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ when xit is an endogenous variable. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ (1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
2 lags
(4)
6 lags
(5)
2 collapsed
(6)
6 collapsed
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.318***
(0.0590)
0.188**
(0.0799)
0.182**
(0.0745)
0.182**
(0.0745)
0.106
(0.0799)
0.148*
(0.0802)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0505
(0.0746)
0.0446
(0.0623)
0.0446
(0.0582)
0.0451
(0.0580)
-0.00231
(0.0714)
-0.00934
(0.0566)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.0741
(0.156)
-0.178
(0.145)
-0.203
(0.126)
-0.198
(0.128)
-0.434
(0.541)
-0.508
(0.392)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.00751
(0.0191)
0.0384*
(0.0214)
0.0373*
(0.0206)
0.0382*
(0.0199)
0.0312
(0.0709)
0.0341
(0.0405)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0759
(0.0537)
0.177*
(0.0991)
0.191*
(0.0980)
0.194**
(0.0961)
0.0149
(0.398)
0.0564
(0.320)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.243***
(0.0695)
-0.0519
(0.152)
-0.0710
(0.147)
-0.0674
(0.148)
-0.222
(0.236)
-0.314
(0.289)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.0681
(0.488)
-0.428
(0.533)
-0.484
(0.499)
-0.479
(0.498)
-0.727
(1.154)
-0.632
(0.738)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
0.424**
(0.188)
0.106
(0.271)
0.0875
(0.263)
0.0939
(0.261)
1.500*
(0.856)
0.913
(0.731)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
0.491*
(0.254)
1.068**
(0.390)
1.150***
(0.393)
1.148***
(0.393)
-0.0499
(1.014)
0.573
(0.837)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.0436*
(0.0245)
0.0269
(0.0201)
0.0298
(0.0186)
0.0303
(0.0187)
0.205***
(0.0600)
0.150***
(0.0484)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
1.250***
(0.188)
1.079***
(0.211)
1.101***
(0.196)
1.097***
(0.194)
0.694
(0.489)
0.515
(0.345)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00548
(0.00389)
-0.0309***
(0.0111)
-0.0325***
(0.0113)
-0.0324***
(0.0110)
-0.103**
(0.0463)
-0.0761***
(0.0291)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.882] [0.021] [0.004] [0.004] [0.059] [0.018]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions            
    Sargan test     [0.134] [0.146] [0.053] [0.252]
    Hansen test     [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated            
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     [0.004] [0.004] [0.013] [0.014]
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     [0.054] [0.054] [0.235] [0.170]
Number of instruments     444 446 52 100
R2 0.462 0.435        
Number observations 480 480 446 446 446 446
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table 6: Estimations by OLS, Fixed Effects and GMM

(2 lags of $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$)

Notes: 1Fixed Effects (FE) regressions eliminate country effects by taking first differences. R2 for FE corresponds to the within R2. k lags means k lags are used to instrument each explanatory variable, i.e. $$ x_{i,t-1}, \ldots, x_{i,t-k}$$ are used as instruments for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ when xit is a predetermined variable and $$ x_{i,t-2}, \ldots, x_{i,t-1-k}$$ are used as instruments for $$ \Delta x_{it}$$ when xit is an endogenous variable. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$
(1)
OLS
(2)
FE
(3)
Difference GMM
2 collapsed
(4)
Difference GMM
6 collapsed
(5)
2 collapsed
(6)
System GMM
6 collapsed
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.215***
(0.0632)
0.151**
(0.0630)
0.153**
(0.0742)
0.170**
(0.0711)
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.232***
(0.0623)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.267***
(0.0629)
0.208***
(0.0515)
0.204***
(0.0634)
0.213***
(0.0565)
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.241***
(0.0506)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0519
(0.0614)
0.0465
(0.0578)
0.0296
(0.0815)
0.0181
(0.0564)
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0617
(0.0549)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.173
(0.156)
-0.223*
(0.124)
-0.747
(0.466)
-0.569**
(0.278)
-0.389*
(0.221)
-0.253
(0.225)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0127
(0.0191)
0.0389**
(0.0188)
0.00241
(0.0642)
0.0221
(0.0416)
0.0521
(0.0355)
0.0603**
(0.0294)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.107*
(0.0553)
0.211**
(0.0950)
0.0661
(0.421)
0.168
(0.274)
0.0886
(0.185)
0.0703
(0.153)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.297***
(0.0765)
-0.113
(0.142)
-0.367
(0.266)
-0.467
(0.301)
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.398***
(0.147)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.0787
(0.453)
-0.334
(0.495)
-0.0118
(1.025)
-0.00792
(0.672)
0.288
(0.678)
0.335
(0.463)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
0.410**
(0.187)
0.0466
(0.248)
1.744
(1.078)
0.580
(0.700)
1.521*
(0.840)
0.454
(0.535)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
0.548**
(0.269)
1.163***
(0.370)
-0.0436
(1.191)
0.755
(0.754)
-0.405
(0.895)
0.826
(0.614)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.0493**
(0.0230)
0.0347
(0.0208)
0.225***
(0.0677)
0.152***
(0.0460)
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.162***
(0.0416)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
1.193***
(0.164)
1.093***
(0.215)
0.560
(0.434)
0.462
(0.304)
0.723*
(0.380)
0.551**
(0.229)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00477
(0.00399)
-0.0291***
(0.0104)
-0.0702
(0.0549)
-0.0369
(0.0353)
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00749
(0.0118)
Year effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country effects1 No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.482 0.359 0.356 0.383 0.483 0.473
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.538] [0.028] [0.033] [0.048] [0.029] [0.067]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions            
    Sargan test     [0.717] [0.742] [0.771] [0.886]
    Hansen test     [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated            
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2)     [0.691] [0.754] [0.983] [0.985]
    Arellano-Bond for AR(3)     [0.611] [0.642] [0.701] [0.700]
Number of instruments     52 100 65 113
R2 0.510 0.467        
Number observations 464 464 430 430 464 464
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table 7: Estimates of the Effect of Bank Financial Position on Credit Growth

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$
(1)
(2)
ROE
(3)
CAP
(4)
BSL
(5)
$$ {\text{ROE}}^2$$
(6)
$$ {\text{BSL}}^2$$
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.233***
(0.0604)
0.266***
(0.0609)
0.247***
(0.0614)
0.227***
(0.0583)
0.235***
(0.0638)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.241***
(0.0581)
0.249***
(0.0607)
0.235***
(0.0661)
0.230***
(0.0607)
0.235***
(0.0590)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0554
(0.0649)
    0.165*
(0.0997)
0.0568
(0.0631)
$$ {\text{ROE}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
        0.00174*
(0.00103)
 
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
  -0.295
(0.264)
  -0.465**
(0.230)
-0.414*
(0.244)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
  0.0515
(0.0398)
  0.0558*
(0.0331)
0.0453
(0.0349)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
    0.0553
(0.211)
0.0957
(0.184)
0.116
(0.744)
$$ {\text{BSL}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
          -0.00152
(0.0183)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.562***
(0.178)
-0.479***
(0.184)
-0.568***
(0.184)
-0.486***
(0.150)
-0.529***
(0.153)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
0.416
(0.658)
-0.0590
(0.611)
0.0967
(0.638)
0.550
(0.608)
0.375
(0.638)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
1.713*
(0.890)
1.770**
(0.865)
1.661**
(0.846)
1.339
(0.857)
1.802**
(0.789)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
-0.737
(0.951)
-0.611
(0.879)
-0.921
(0.946)
-0.319
(0.867)
-0.652
(0.876)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.224***
(0.0716)
0.242***
(0.0686)
0.239***
(0.0646)
0.237***
(0.0582)
0.258***
(0.0587)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
0.833**
(0.407)
0.893**
(0.402)
0.858**
(0.404)
0.620
(0.384)
0.865**
(0.350)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00901
(0.0126)
0.0106
(0.0140)
0.00921
(0.0121)
0.00892
(0.0129)
0.0111
(0.0133)
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029]   [0.076]   [0.019] [0.023]
H0: $$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{ROE}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$         [0.189]  
H0: $$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{BSL}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$           [0.950]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions            
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.693] [0.638] [0.689] [0.869] [0.871]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated            
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.972] [0.922] [0.967] [0.859] [0.985]
Number of instruments 65 56 59 56 68 71
Number observations 464 464 464 464 464 464
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table 8: Estimates Using Alternative Measures of Banks' Profits

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$

(1)

(2)
ROE even
if E < 0
(3)

ROA
(4)
ROA and
LEVERAGE
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.223***
(0.0542)
0.233***
(0.0591)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.233***
(0.0599)
0.236***
(0.0602)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0594
(0.0652)
   
ROA$$ _{i,t-1}$$
    1.917
(1.451)
1.882
(1.845)
LEVERAGE$$ _{i,t-1}$$
      -1.570
(1.849)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
-0.399*
(0.223)
-0.433*
(0.245)
-15.40
(21.27)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
0.0528
(0.0357)
0.0505
(0.0307)
0.799
(1.142)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
0.0884
(0.185)
0.0655
(0.180)
0.0630
(0.148)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.506***
(0.149)
-0.415*
(0.217)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
0.285
(0.677)
0.561
(0.829)
0.0378
(1.095)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
1.522*
(0.840)
1.484*
(0.841)
1.475*
(0.864)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
-0.407
(0.895)
-0.313
(0.841)
-0.379
(0.826)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.236***
(0.0595)
0.264***
(0.0642)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
0.724*
(0.380)
0.603
(0.425)
0.730*
(0.415)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.0112
(0.0144)
0.00900
(0.0149)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.483 0.483 0.457 0.469
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029] [0.029] [0.025] [0.692]
H0: ROA$$ _{i,t-1} =$$   LEVERAGE$$ _{i,t-1} = 0$$       [0.490]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions        
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.771] [0.629] [0.810]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated        
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.983] [0.984] [0.947]
Number of instruments 65 65 65 68
Number observations 464 464 464 463
Number countries 29 29 29 29



Table 9: Estimates Using Alternative Measures of Banks' Liquidity

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$

(1)

(2)

BSL * SMALL
(3)
restricted
sample
(4)
SEC + RES
ASSETS
(5)
DEPOSITS
ASSETS
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.358***
(0.0713)
0.405***
(0.0925)
0.228***
(0.0628)
0.243***
(0.0599)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.0558
(0.0858)
0.227***
(0.0819)
0.232***
(0.0577)
0.265***
(0.0477)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.414**
(0.175)
-0.291***
(0.0987)
0.0681
(0.0650)
0.0874
(0.0661)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
-0.963***
(0.348)
-0.674*
(0.394)
-0.392*
(0.235)
-0.358
(0.250)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
0.0145
(0.0363)
0.0292
(0.0357)
0.0491
(0.0338)
0.0472
(0.0332)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
  0.191
(0.183)
   
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}*\text{SMALL}_{i,t-1}$$
  0.00874*
(0.00526)
     
(SEC+RES)/ASSETS$$ _{i,t-1}$$
      -0.0588
(0.131)
 
DEPOSITS/ASSETS$$ _{i,t-1}$$
        -0.174*
(0.0908)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.241
(0.251)
-0.644**
(0.313)
-0.489***
(0.152)
-0.563***
(0.171)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
-0.00191
(1.138)
-1.859*
(1.037)
0.289
(0.659)
0.593
(0.582)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
-0.531
(0.541)
0.0682
(0.531)
1.833**
(0.911)
1.824*
(0.952)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
0.556
(1.107)
1.279
(0.819)
-0.462
(0.893)
-0.405
(0.818)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
-0.0357
(0.0887)
0.122
(0.0814)
0.233***
(0.0606)
0.207***
(0.0682)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
-0.271
(0.785)
-0.771
(0.863)
0.868**
(0.379)
0.802**
(0.395)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
-0.0233**
(0.0116)
-0.0205
(0.0166)
0.0113
(0.0150)
-0.00333
(0.0143)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.483 0.414 0.632 0.460 0.508
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029] [0.00008] [0.046] [0.022] [0.068]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions          
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.002] [0.002] [0.779] [0.423]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated          
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.940] [0.171] [0.970] [0.992]
Number of instruments 65 65 65 65 65
Number observations 464 249 249 464 464
Number countries 29 18 18 29 29



Table 10: Estimates Using Alternative Measures of Banks' Capital

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ (1) (2) (3) (4)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.240***
(0.0586)
0.237***
(0.0635)
0.232***
(0.0625)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.240***
(0.0626)
0.244***
(0.0619)
0.236***
(0.0605)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0474
(0.0660)
0.0555
(0.0628)
0.0591
(0.0644)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
     
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
     
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}*({\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}\geq P25)$$
  0.0754
(0.807)
   
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}*({\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}\geq 4\%)$$
    0.292
(0.363)
 
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}*({\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}\geq 6\%)$$
      0.258
(0.218)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
0.105
(0.212)
0.0919
(0.185)
0.0753
(0.177)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.478***
(0.174)
-0.509***
(0.168)
-0.551***
(0.171)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
0.198
(0.671)
0.427
(0.708)
0.504
(0.715)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
1.404*
(0.798)
1.561*
(0.869)
1.707**
(0.861)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
-0.476
(0.889)
-0.464
(0.931)
-0.544
(0.933)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.210***
(0.0551)
0.233***
(0.0640)
0.241***
(0.0650)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
0.669*
(0.368)
0.740*
(0.400)
0.883**
(0.375)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00550
(0.0112)
0.00917
(0.0133)
0.0128
(0.0146)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.483 0.479 0.482 0.467
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029]      
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions        
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.542] [0.767] [0.700]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated        
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.985] [0.947] [0.998]
Number of instruments 65 62 62 62
Number observations 464 464 464 464
Number countries 29 29 29 29



Table 11: Robustness Checks I: Definition of Deposit Costs, Provisions and Organization of Bank Sector

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$

(1)

(2)
DEPOSIT
RATE
(3)

LARGE
(4)
restricted
sample
(5)
LOAN
PROVISIONS
(6)
restricted
sample
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.300***
(0.0708)
0.350***
(0.0709)
0.350***
(0.106)
0.247***
(0.0757)
0.225***
(0.0732)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.265***
(0.0477)
0.0783
(0.0841)
0.212**
(0.0825)
0.302***
(0.0533)
0.306***
(0.0551)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0607
(0.0633)
0.407**
(0.183)
-0.301***
(0.0730)
-0.0339
(0.0594)
0.0414
(0.0614)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
-0.110
(0.186)
-0.876***
(0.310)
-0.648*
(0.358)
-0.135
(0.234)
-0.256
(0.287)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
0.0790**
(0.0317)
0.0243
(0.0367)
0.0142
(0.0409)
0.107***
(0.0347)
0.102***
(0.0377)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
0.395**
(0.186)
0.163
(0.190)
0.204
(0.178)
0.538***
(0.179)
0.453**
(0.201)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
  -0.370
(0.228)
-0.297
(0.208)
-0.388***
(0.140)
-0.506***
(0.116)
DEPOSIT RATE$$ _{it}$$
  1.280
(0.823)
       
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
-0.0816
(0.859)
0.155
(1.105)
-1.972**
(0.854)
  0.324
(0.754)
LOAN PROVISIONS$$ _{i,t-1}$$
        -1.476*
(0.819)
 
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
0.471
(0.794)
-0.330
(0.470)
0.0128
(0.471)
1.366**
(0.652)
1.711**
(0.840)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
-0.284
(1.250)
0.634
(0.714)
1.184
(0.876)
-0.252
(0.676)
-0.0590
(0.773)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.225***
(0.0463)
-0.00534
(0.0797)
0.0745
(0.0960)
0.228***
(0.0686)
0.231***
(0.0695)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
0.928***
(0.356)
-0.178
(0.735)
-0.599
(0.797)
0.746***
(0.242)
0.721**
(0.315)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00618
(0.0134)
-0.0196**
(0.00992)
-0.0221*
(0.0132)
0.0151
(0.0104)
0.0189
(0.0145)
LARGE$$ _{i,t-1}$$
    -0.0645
(0.0585)
     
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.483 0.565 0.429 0.562 0.549 0.530
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029] [0.031] [0.000] [0.079] [0.00002] [0.000001]
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions            
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.648] [0.002] [0.0005] [0.317] [0.206]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated            
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.433] [0.894] [0.223] [0.669] [0.664]
Number of instruments 65 65 68 65 65 65
Number observations 464 443 254 254 354 354
Number countries 29 29 29 29 29 29



Table 12: Robustness Checks II: Controls for Real Activity

Notes: System GMM estimates using, 2 collapsed lags of explanatory variables as instruments. All models consider country and year effects. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses. P-values in brackets. ***, **, * denote significant at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Dependent Variable: $$ {\Delta \ell }_{it}$$ (1) (2) (3) (4)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1}$$
0.243***
(0.0603)
0.266***
(0.0629)
0.254***
(0.0636)
0.216***
(0.0605)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$
0.241***
(0.0618)
0.243***
(0.0635)
0.219***
(0.0724)
0.253***
(0.0614)
$$ {\text{ROE}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0598
(0.0651)
0.0804
(0.0658)
0.0333
(0.0710)
0.0694
(0.0684)
$$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.389*
(0.221)
-0.490**
(0.200)
-0.547*
(0.314)
-0.343
(0.217)
$$ {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1}$$
0.0521
(0.0355)
0.0608
(0.0388)
0.0354
(0.0338)
0.0598**
(0.0296)
$$ {\text{BSL}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.0886
(0.185)
0.140
(0.219)
0.256
(0.235)
0.299*
(0.182)
$$ {\text{DEPOSIT COSTS}}_{i,t-1}$$
-0.486***
(0.158)
-0.481***
(0.166)
-0.402
(0.248)
-0.266
(0.225)
$$ {\text{PROVISIONS}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.288
(0.678)
0.362
(0.702)
-0.0184
(0.624)
0.498
(0.666)
$$ {\text{LENDING RATE}}_{it}$$
1.521*
(0.840)
1.081
(0.861)
1.629*
(0.890)
1.317*
(0.766)
$$ {\text{LONG TERM RATE}}_{it}$$
-0.405
(0.895)
-0.187
(0.947)
-0.892
(0.916)
-0.626
(0.865)
$$ {\text{STOCK RETURNS}}_{it}$$
0.243***
(0.0602)
0.280***
(0.0733)
0.251***
(0.0702)
0.242***
(0.0482)
$$ {\text{ASSETS/GDP}}_{i,t-1}$$
0.00939
(0.0138)
0.00526
(0.0145)
0.00311
(0.0114)
0.00264
(0.0120)
$$ {\Delta \text{AGG. DEMAND}}_{it}$$
0.723*
(0.380)
    0.771*
(0.418)
$$ \Delta$$GDP$$ _{it}$$
  0.340
(0.600)
   
$$ \Delta$$CONSUMPTION$$ _{it}$$
    -0.0997
(1.062)
 
$$ \Delta$$INVESTMENT$$ _{it}$$
    0.236
(0.402)
 
$$ \Delta$$GOVERNMENT$$ _{it}$$
    1.395*
(0.785)
 
INFLATION$$ _{i,t-1}$$
      -0.404
(0.287)
UNEMPLOYMENT$$ _{it}$$
      -0.398
(0.344)
$$ {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-1} + {\Delta\ell}_{i,t-2}$$ 0.483 0.509 0.474 0.469
H0: $$ {\text{CAP}}_{i,t-1} = {\text{CAP}}^2_{i,t-1} = 0$$ [0.029] [0.003] [0.093] [0.011]
H0: $$ \Delta$$CONSUMPTION$$ _{it} = \Delta$$INVESTMENT$$ _{it} = \Delta$$GOVERNMENT$$ _{it} = 0$$     [0.028]  
H0: joint validity of moment restrictions        
    Sargan test [0.771] [0.889] [0.942] [0.676]
    Hansen test [1.000] [1.000] [1.000] [1.000]
H0: residuals are serially uncorrelated        
    Arellano-Bond for AR(2) [0.983] [0.986] [0.728] [0.898]
Number of instruments 65 65 71 71
Number observations 464 464 464 462
Number countries 29 29 29 29


Figure 1: Predicted Credit Growth by $$ {\text {CAP}}$$.

Figure 1. See link for accessible version.

Accessible version




Footnotes

* I thank Elias Albagli, Guillermo Ordoñez and Gary Gorton for helpful comments. I also benefited from comments from seminar participants at Yale. The opinions expressed do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. Return to Text
1. I use the convention that small caps letter denote the log of capital letters. Return to Text
2. In fact,

$$\displaystyle Y_t \lambda_t = \Delta A^* \equiv A^* - A_t = A_t \left( \frac{A^*}{A_t} - 1 \right) \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \Delta a^* \equiv \log\left( \frac{A^*}{A_t} \right) = \log\left( 1 + \frac{ Y_t }{ A_t } \lambda_t \right) \approx \frac{ Y_t }{ A_t } \lambda_t $$
Return to Text
3. See Kashyap and Stein (2000) and Ostergaard (2001). Return to Text
4. Loutskina and Strahan (2009) measure cost of deposits from Call Report for commercial banks in the US as the ratio of total interest expenses on deposits to total deposits. The data on banks used here only reports total interest expenses. Return to Text
5. Asea and Blomberg, 1998; Lown and Morgan, 2001; Schreft and Owens, 1991; Weinberg, 1995. Return to Text
6. See Berger, Demsetz, and Strahan (1999). Return to Text
7. For four countries (Canada, Greece, Mexico and US) information on the second most comprehensive bank group is used to extend the time series, see notes to Table 1. Return to Text
8. One reason why information on interest rates is not complete is because in 1999 the countries in the European Union changed the way statistics on lending rates are reported. This presents challenges in the construction of time series for lending (and deposits) rates as no lending rates with the old methodology are published anymore. Return to Text
9. Data in millions of National currency, except for Japan (100 millions) and Slovak Republic (thousands). Return to Text
10. According to the definitions in the OECD Bank dataset interest expenses "generally includes interest paid on liabilities and fee expenses related to borrowing operations, and it may include in some cases the difference between the issue price on debt instruments and their par value" (OECD, 2004). Return to Text
11. For Chile CPI-indexed bonds yields, obtained from the Central Bank of Chile, are used instead. Return to Text
12. Real private consumption corresponds to households and non-profit institutions serving households. Real government consumption is final consumption expenditure of general government. Real investment is gross fixed capital formation. Return to Text
13. Real GDP figures for Japan are in 100 millions and for Slovak Republic in thousands. Return to Text
14. The number of instruments could be T if information for lagged values of variables are available. This is the case for the data being analyzed here. Return to Text
15. This test is not consistent in the presence of non-spherical disturbances as in here; nonetheless, it is the best statistic for model diagnostics. The alternative Hansen test, which is consistent, has the disadvantage of being weakened by the use of a large number of instruments (Bowsher, 2002). In fact, this test does not reject the null of valid moment restrictions in all the GMM models reported in Table 5. Return to Text
16. Carrying out the estimation using system GMM and restricting the set of instruments in this way yields statistical insignificant coefficient for most variables suggesting that instruments are weakened significantly (Appendix C). Return to Text
17. The standard deviation of CAP for the whole sample is 2.2% as reported in Appendix A. Return to Text
18. Standard deviations are reported in Appendix A and equal: 5.684 for DEPOSIT COSTS; 3.101 for LENDING RATE; 20.635 for STOCK RETURNS; and 2.774 for $$ {\Delta \text {AGG. DEMAND}}$$. Return to Text
19. Considering the difference GMM estimator-not reported-individual coefficients loose their significance. Only when 6 collapsed lags are included using the system GMM estimator the coefficients on ROE are jointly significant. All this suggest that ROE might have a nonlinear effect, but it can not be ruled out that this is due to overfitting, as the result only becomes strong when many instruments are included. Return to Text
20. The ratio of small bank assets to total assets, SMALL is calculated as the ratio of assets of non-large commercial banks, savings banks and cooperative banks to total banks assets. Return to Text
21. Reserves corresponds to item 14 cash and balances with Central Bank of the OECD Bank Statistics dataset. For Japan reserves are included in interbank deposits, which are used instead. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text