Finance and Economics Discussion Series: Accessible versions of figures for 2017-033

Private and Public Liquidity Provision in Over-the-Counter Markets

Accessible version of figures


Figure 1: Feedback loop between primary and secondary market for corporate debt

The figure highlights the two-way interaction between the primary credit market and the secondary OTC market. The upper arrow highlights the liquidity premium channel, whereby lenders impose liquidity premia that depends on the market thickness of the OTC market. At the same time, the lower arrow highlights the liquidity provision channel, whereby bond issuance by firms affects secondary market liquidity by shaping the portfolio composition of investors.

Return to text.


Figure 2: Timeline.

The figure shows the model timeline. In the initial period, investors lend to the firm, which writes a long-term debt contract to fund a risky investment that pays out at the end of the second period. At time t=1 investors get hit with a liquidity shock that make a fraction impatient and the remainder patient. The two engage in trade in the over-the-counter market, with the impatient investor exchanging the illiquid asset for the liquid asset supplies by patient investors. Finally, in the last period, uncertainty is realized and the risky project pays out.

Return to text.


Figure 3: Aggregate Demand and Supply of Credit in the Primary Market.

The figure shows aggregate supply and demand of credit in the primary debt market. The expected hold-to-maturity return is on the y-axis and the quantity of credit is on the x-axis. The figure shows the aggregate supply of primary credit from investors is upward sloping while the aggregate demand for credit from firms is downward sloping. The upward sloping aggregate supply of credit sets or model apart from the standard costly state verification (CSV) literature. As the expected hold-to-maturity bond return increases, for investors to be indifferent between illiquid bonds and liquid storage, market thickness needs to drop so the return on storage increase and the expected loss from holding illiquid bonds decreases. Market thickness drops only if investors’ portfolios become more illiquid, for which investors bond holdings need to increase. In contrast, in the CSV literature it is typically assumed that aggregate credit supply is totally elastic at the rate (1+r)^2, shown by the dashed horizontal line.

Return to text.


Figure 4: Equilibrium in the Frictionless Benchmark

The figure is a graphical illustration of the equilibrium in the frictionless benchmark. The riskiness of the contract (omega) is on the y-axis and leverage is on the x-axis. The firm’s isoprofit lines are upward sloping and are increasing toward the southwest corner. The investors’ breakeven condition is also upward sloping, although at a different rate than the firm’s isoprofit lines. The equilibrium in the frictionless economy—indicated by a thick black dot—is the point at which the two are tangent to one another.

Return to text.


Figure 5: Comparative Statics on $$ \delta $$.

The figure presents comparative statics varying the size of the liquidity shock, delta. The riskiness of the contract (omega) is on the y-axis and leverage is on the x-axis. The firm’s isoprofit lines are upward sloping and are increasing toward the southwest corner. The slope of the investor’s breakeven condition increases in the size of the liquidity shock, so that the equilibrium with higher delta involves both lower risk and lower leverage.

Return to text.


Figure 6: Bond Premia Decomposition

The figure shows a decomposition of the firm’s total funding costs into a default premium and a liquidity premium as the liquidity shock (delta) gets larger. The size of the premium is on the y-axis and delta in on the x-axis. As delta gets larger, the decline in the default premium more than offsets the rise in the liquidity premium, resulting in an overall decline in the firm’s total funding cost.

Return to text.


Figure 7: Constrained Efficient Equilibrium

The Figure shows the planner’s solution and the private equilibrium for two cases: δ = 0 and δ = 0.1. In a frictionless environment (δ = 0), the planner’s solution coincides with the private equilibrium. However, when there is a positive demand for liquidity, δ > 0 and β < 1/(1 + r), and secondary market liquidity is not sufficiently high to guarantee f (θ) = 1, the planner chooses lower leverage and a less risky capital structure. The reason is because the planner internalizes the effect of the leverage decision on liquidity in the secondary market. This induces the planner to consider a steeper constraint compared to the breakeven condition considered by competitive firms (where market liquidity is taken as given). As a result, the planner understands how lower leverage and risk improves borrowing terms on the margin, when the total social costs are taken into account.

Return to text.


Figure 8: Effect of Quantitative Easing

The figure shows how the gains to the firm vary with ψ for different levels of the efficiency of the central bank monitoring technology. The thin lines show the case for μ = 0.3 assuming QE in conjunction with the optimal tax system (the thick solid line) and, alternatively, assuming QE alone with no supporting tax system (the thick dashed line). The thin solid and dashed lines correspond to the same information when the monitoring cost is higher, so that μ = 0.35. Finally, the thin blue line shows the gains to the firm from optimal tax policy alone in absence of QE. There are four things to take from the figure. First, QE is always more effective when combined with the optimal tax policy (the solid lines are always above the dashed line for the same monitoring cost assumption). Second, the effectiveness of QE is limited by the parameterization of ψ (the dashed lines are downward sloping, so that as the gains from trade that accrue to impatient investors declines, QE becomes less effective). Third, the effectiveness of QE depends importantly on the quality of the central bank’s monitoring technology (the thin lines are below the thick ones, so the worse the technology, the less effective is QE). Finally, there are parts of the parameter space in which QE is ineffective to the point at which a planner would strictly prefer optimal taxation to QE (the regions in which the thick and thin dashed lines lie below the solid blue line).

Return to text.