Abstract:
The United States government spends billions on public health insurance and has funded a number of programs to build health care facilities. However, the government runs these two types of programs separately: in different places, at different times, and for different populations. We explore whether access to both health insurance and hospitals can improve health outcomes and access to health care. We analyze a coal mining union health insurance program in 1950s Appalachia with and without a complementary hospital construction program. Our results show that the union insurance alone increased hospital births and reduced infant mortality. Once the union hospitals opened, however, the insurance and the hospitals together substantially increased the net amount of hospital beds and health care employees, with limited crowd-out of existing private hospitals. Our results suggest that hospitals can complement health insurance in underserved areas.
JEL Codes: I18, I13, H51
The United States government plays a large role in the health care sector through public health insurance and subsidized hospitals. In practice, the government has carried out these public health care programs separately: in different places, at different times, and for different populations. Therefore, there is limited empirical evidence on the potential for health insurance and hospitals to complement each other. Specifically, public insurance may lower the cost of health care, but people may still have trouble accessing care if they live in an area without many hospitals to treat them. As a result, building new hospitals may make subsidized health insurance more effective in underserved areas. However, subsidizing hospitals may displace, or crowd out, existing private hospitals, which would reduce the potential for the hospitals to complement the insurance.
Our paper explores the effects of subsidized insurance programs with and without a complementary hospital construction program in an underserved area. To study this question, we analyze two health care interventions in 1950s Appalachian coal country using data on health care utilization (hospital birth rates and hospital admissions), hospital outcomes (beds and employees), and health outcomes (infant and overall mortality rates). In 1950, the United Mine Workers of America (UMWA), a major coal mining union, began providing hospital care insurance to its members and their families. For pregnant women in coal mining families, the union insurance covered comprehensive pregnancy-related hospital care for the first time.1 In 1956, the union opened ten new hospitals in the area, primarily to serve those with the union hospital care insurance. Because the insurance pre-dated the hospitals, we can analyze the impact of the insurance before and after the hospitals opened. In recent times, 36 states, including seven Appalachian states, have expanded public insurance through Medicaid .2Therefore, whether subsidized health care is less effective in areas with fewer hospitals to treat new patients continues to be an important issue in health care policy.
Before the union health care interventions, Appalachia had limited access to health care compared with the rest of the United States. Appalachians had access to 1.5 hospital beds per thousand, well below a federal designation for underserved areas of 4.5 per thousand . At the time, only 65 percent of infants in Appalachia were born in hospitals, compared to nearly 85 percent in the rest of the United States.3 To this day, the differences between Appalachia and the rest of the United States persist, as disparities in infant mortality rates have widened in Appalachia despite government programs designed to incentivize doctors to live in rural areas with doctor shortages .
By studying the complementary effects of subsidized hospital care insurance and hospitals, we contribute to our understanding of public health insurance programs in three ways. First, we provide causal evidence on a subsidized health insurance program with and without a complementary supply-side expansion of new hospitals. There is already a large literature on U.S. public health insurance programs.4 However, only limited evidence exists on whether building health care facilities improves the effectiveness of health insurance programs in underserved areas (Bailey and Goodman-Bacon (2015) is one exception). Second, we present the first causal analysis of these subsidized union health care programs. Our work complements existing studies that conduct descriptive and qualitative analysis of the programs.5 Third, we improve upon studies of the introduction of public health insurance programs in theUnited States by using a county-level proxy for health insurance eligibility instead of state or Census sub-region.6 As a result, our approach reduces the measurement error in the analysis.
We use a difference-in-differences approach across counties and over time to separately identify (i) the initial effects of the hospital insurance and (ii) the complementary effect of new hospitals in areas with high concentrations of people eligible for the union hospital insurance.7 Because the insurance pre-dated the hospitals, we can measure the impacts of the insurance separately with and without the hospitals.8We use county-year level data in the 399 counties in Appalachia, including measures of health care utilization, hospitals, and health outcomes from the U.S. Vital Statistics and the American Hospital Association.9 In particular, since the insurance provided comprehensive coverage for hospital pregnancy care, the Vital Statistics allow us to measure its effects on pregnancy-related outcomes such as hospital birth rates and infant mortality, with and without the union hospitals. We identify the effects of the two interventions using two different measures of exposure at the county level. For the hospital insurance intervention, we use differences across counties in the rates of mining employment as a share of the population 14 years and older in the first year of the program (1950).10 The higher the share of mining employment, the more people have the mining union hospital care insurance. For the complementary hospital intervention, we use a county-level indicator for the presence of a union hospital.11
Without the subsidized hospitals, we find that the insurance increased health care utilization and improved health outcomes. Hospital birth rates increased by 3 percent for the average Appalachian county with 3 percent of its adult population employed in mining. Among counties with mining employment in the 95th percentile or above, the union insurance increased hospital birth rates by an average of 23 percent. Infant mortality rates fell by 2 percent for the average county. This reduction is around 25 percent of the overall gap in infant mortality rates between Appalachia and the rest of the United States. We find no statistically significant evidence of a private market supply-side response to the insurance, such as an increase in hospital beds in private hospitals.
With the insurance in place, the new hospitals had a large and lasting impact on health care infrastructure, suggesting that existing private hospitals were not enough to meet demand. In counties with new hospitals, beds increased 83 percent, on net, and these effects persist nearly ten years later. Full-time equivalent hospital employees more than doubled, from two per 1,000 to over five per 1,000. Moreover, the associated crowd out rate for hospitals is much lower than a separate federal subsidized hospital program in the same time period (the Hill-Burton program) that did not complement any existing insurance programs.12 We cannot reject the null of no further improvements in hospital births, admissions, or infant mortality.13
Our analysis is robust to a variety of alternative specifications and explanations. First, we analyze pre-trends with event study specifications of our difference-in-differences regressions. Our results are robust to accounting for other contemporaneous government programs such as county-level funding from the Hill-Burton hospital construction program and counties receiving funding from the Tennessee Valley Authority. In addition, to ensure that the creation of Medicare and Medicaid did not confound our results, we intentionally end our sample in 1965, one year before these programs began providing benefits. Finally, we provide evidence that the Second Great Migration of African-Americans out of the South likely does not bias our results, nor did mining wages rise more rapidly than overall wages during our sample period.
Compared to the most similar study, Bailey and Goodman-Bacon (2015), our results extend our knowledge and complement their findings in several ways. First, we can examine the impact of reducing the cost of health care through subsidized insurance with and without building more health care facilities. Bailey and Goodman-Bacon (2015) examine the War on Poverty's Community Health Centers (CHCs). CHCs provided both additional health facilities and reduced cost primary care at the same time. Therefore, the two effects cannot be separated. Second, our study examines hospital care programs, rather than primary care programs. Third, we can test whether the subsidized hospitals crowded out existing private hospitals.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. First, we provide details on the health conditions in Appalachia before the union health care programs and information on the programs themselves. We then describe the two main data sources followed by the difference-in-differences identification strategy. Next, we present results on the impacts of both programs followed by the conclusion.
Before the United Mine Workers of America (UMWA) health care programs, coal miners in Appalachia and their families had limited access to quality health care. 14 They received primary care through company doctors and local hospitals, some of which had minimal pre-payment hospitalization plans. Company doctors were typically poorly trained and primarily concerned with minimizing worker compensation claims for the coal companies . The pre-payment hospitalization plans acted like a very limited insurance plan. However, miners had difficulty determining whether certain treatments were covered and how much they had to pay out of pocket 1.F15The plans did not cover the treatment of contagious diseases or injuries related to car crashes . Moreover, neither the company doctor nor the hospitalization plans covered obstetric care or pre- and postnatal care . Even if the hospitalization plans were clear as to what was covered, most hospitals in the Appalachian region lacked basic facilities, such as surgical rooms, delivery rooms, clinical laboratories, or X-ray facilities .16
At the time, the government played only a limited role in health care. Medicare and Medicaid had not yet been established (these programs began providing benefits in 1966), and state and local governments primarily provided medical care through public health clinics and workers' compensation. Public health clinics largely provided care for tuberculosis and venereal diseases . State workers' compensation benefits were limited and only provided care after a waiting period .
The only major federal health care program was the Federal Hospital Survey and Construction Act of 1946, better known as the Hill-Burton Act. The Hill-Burton Act was passed to improve access to health facilities in areas with high levels of need, particularly in the South. Under the Hill-Burton Act, the federal government provided matching grants for up to one-third of the total cost to build or expand hospital facilities in areas that lacked a sufficient number of beds - defined as fewer than 4.5 beds per 1,000 .
The Hill-Burton program did little to alleviate the conditions in Central Appalachia, where the UMWA's programs were most heavily concentrated. By 1960, Central Appalachia had received only limited funding and additional beds as a result of the Hill-Burton Act, shown in panels (b) of Figures A.2 and A.3 .17 The average county in Central Appalachia had received approximately 0.7 Hill-Burton funded beds per 1,000 by 1960. Nationally, by 1960, the average county had received approximately 1.6 beds per 1,000 funded by the Hill-Burton program. Compared with the rest of the country, Central Appalachia appears as a "hole" for Hill-Burton funding, even by 1960 (Figures A.4(b) and A.5(b)).
Our health and health care outcome measures are considerably worse before the UMWA health care interventions. Table 1 presents summary statistics for our full sample (1946 to1965), and Table 2 presents the same statistics for 1948, pre-UMWA interventions.18 On the utilization side, the share of births in a hospital for the average Appalachian county for our full sample is relatively high compared to the pre-period - 82 percent on average (Table 1). Finally, we look at summary statistics to show that health and health care measures before the union programs were worse overall than during the full sample. Before the UMWA programs, in the average county in Appalachia only around 60 percent of births were delivered in a hospital (Table 2) compared to over 80 percent in the full sample (Table 1). Hospital admissions are around 85 per thousand people in the full sample, but only around 53 per thousand before the UMWA programs were established. On the facilities supply side, the average Appalachian county had around 1.4 hospitals with 2 hospital beds per 1,000 in the full sample. In the pre-program period, these figures are only 1.2 hospitals and 1.5 beds per 1,000. The federal Hill-Burton hospital infrastructure program set a goal target of 4.5 beds per 1,000 at the time, considerably higher than the average county in Appalachia.
The infant mortality rate in mid-century Appalachia was slightly higher than in the rest of the United States. Before the interventions, in 1948, the average Appalachian county had an infant mortality rate of 36 per 1,000 births (Table 2). The U.S. national infant mortality rate in 1948 was 34 per 1,000 births.19 By contrast, by 2015, the U.S. national rate had fallen to 5.9 per 1,000.
To improve health care in the coal fields, the UMWA launched two massive health programs in the 1950s. These programs were very much targeted to Appalachia, as the region had the highest concentration of coal employment in the country (Figure A.1). First, following the coal miners' strike of 1946, the UMWA secured the establishment of a fund to provide non-wage benefits to all miners, financed by a per-ton royalty fee on coal production as part of a collective bargaining agreement facilitated by the U.S. government .20 These benefits included retirement, disability, and a free health insurance program for miners and their dependents. Second, in the mid-1950s, the UMWA, dissatisfied with the quality of hospitals and doctors in Appalachia, used its funds to build ten state-of-the-art hospitals in the area. To support its hospitals, the UMWA attracted top medical talent to the area to staff the hospitals.
The UMWA started its hospital care insurance program in June 1950, covering all union miners, working and retired, plus their dependents. The insurance required no out-of-pocket costs - beneficiaries paid no copayments, deductibles, or premiums. Compared with the hospital pre-payment plans miners were used to, the insurance was cheaper and provided more comprehensive coverage . Importantly, the UMWA insurance program fully covered obstetric care for pregnant women, typically not covered under the previous plans. The full coverage of obstetrics care was a particularly salient innovation at the time. As late as the mid-1970s, health insurance provided only limited coverage of childbirth .
Before 1950, in the first nine months of 1949, the UMWA rolled out an initial insurance plan that was short-lived and chaotic, suffering from overcharging and abuses . This initial version of the insurance that paid providers directly on a fee-for-service basis was quickly ended. . In an event-study specification of our analysis, we show that this "false start" initial program had little to no impact on outcomes. It was only in 1950, when the insurance program began again with more robust controls for quality of care, that we see sustained increases in hospital care and declines in infant mortality.
Soon after the hospital insurance plan was established, the UMWA realized it had made a poor assumption about the supply-side response to its insurance program. To the UWMA's surprise, the draw of a large set of patients with a well-functioning, centrally managed insurance program was not enough to attract an additional supply of quality hospitals and doctors to an isolated, rural area like Appalachia.
As a result, the UMWA developed a supply-side plan that we refer to as the "hospital program" - building a network of ten state-of-the-art hospitals and attracting top medical talent to the area . The union hospitals directly accepted the union hospital insurance. These hospitals opened between December 1955 and May 1956 (Figure 2) in various population centers in Central Appalachia, costing around $34 million in 1955, equivalent to around $350 million in today's dollars. The union paid physicians a steady salary instead of the typical fee-for-service. The hospitals were open to all, and, as a result, represented an increase in available hospital services for all residents .
A key feature of these hospitals was their location: the UMWA built them in places where larger shares of people had recently become eligible for the UMWA's insurance. As we describe in the next section, we use this feature of the UMWA's program to expand our understanding of complementary effects of placing hospitals in areas where people can afford to use them. We also describe how we support the identifying assumption necessary to estimate the impact of the hospitals (parallel trends in our outcomes in the absence of the hospitals). As Figure 2 shows, all counties where UMWA hospitals opened had high shares of mining employment. In counties without UMWA hospitals, most counties had little to no mining employment, but there still exist some counties without UMWA hospitals where the amount of mining employment was similar to counties with UMWA hospitals.
To examine the effect of the two UMWA health care interventions on health and health care outcomes, we use data from two main sources: county-year level U.S. Vital Statistics administrative data and county-year level American Hospitals Association (AHA) survey data from 1946 through 1965 for all 399 counties in Appalachia.21For our outcome variables, our health care utilization measures include the fraction of births in a hospital, or hospital birth rate (Vital Statistics, 1946 to 1965, Bailey, Clay, Fishback et al ), and overall hospital admissions (AHA, 1948 to 1965). To measure effects on hospital capacity, we use data on the number of hospital beds per 1,000 (AHA, 1948 to 1965) and full-time equivalent hospital employees per 1,000 (AHA, 1951 to 1965). Finally, we examine the effects on health outcomes with Vital Statistics data on infant mortality under the age of one per 1,000 births (1946 to 1965) and overall mortality rates per 1,000 (1946 to 1965).
We choose the time frame of our analysis to increase the representativeness of the sample and to avoid confounding effects of the War on Poverty. As in other work, we choose 1946 as the starting year for our series of analyses . In doing so, we begin our sample in 1946 to mark the beginning of the post-war period, when prime-age men returned to the labor force and children were born to a more representative group of families. For the end year, we choose 1965, the first year of the War on Poverty programs, to avoid any confounding effects of other future programs (most notably Medicare and Medicaid). Including years through 1965 also allows us to examine a time when the UMWA scaled back benefits.22 Because we have two interventions (insurance and hospitals), we divide the years 1946 to 1965 into three separate periods according to when the UMWA rolled out each intervention. The next section describes this in more detail.
We use two county-level variables to measure each Appalachian county's exposure to the insurance and the hospitals. For the hospital insurance, we use the fraction of workers employed in mining as a share of the population age 14 and older at the county level in 1950 from the U.S. County and City Data Book . For the union hospitals, we use a binary indicator for whether a particular county contained one of the ten UMWA hospitals using information from Krajcinovic (1997). At this time, the average Appalachian county had 3 percent of the population employed in mining (Table 1). Some counties had zero mining employment, while in others miners made up 20 percent of the population 14 and older. The fraction of workers employed in mining was particularly concentrated in Central Appalachia (Figure 1).23
First, we describe the specifications we use to estimate the effects of introducing hospital insurance coverage and union hospitals to Appalachia. Second, we explain the interpretation of the coefficients of interest and the identification assumptions. Finally, we discuss a theoretical framework to explain the results we expect to see for the impact of the two union programs.
We use a difference-in-differences approach to estimate the impact of the two UMWA programs on health care and health outcomes in Appalachia. Our setup is different from many difference-in-differences designs. A common setup is a "staggered rollout" design, where observations get the same intervention at different times.24 In our case, we have two different interventions at two different times, but observations receive each intervention at roughly the same time. Moreover, there are overlapping pre- and post- periods for the two interventions.
There are the three distinct time periods for our difference-in-difference approach (Figure 3). Our sample begins in 1946 and the hospital insurance program started in 1950. Therefore, the pre-period for the hospital insurance program is 1946 to 1949. We end the post period for the insurance program in 1955, because starting in 1956, the hospitals opened in the areas with the highest shares of people eligible for UMWA insurance to complement the insurance. For the hospitals, the pre-period is 1951 to 1955, and the post- period is 1956 to 1965.
To account for the timing of the interventions, we estimate two separate regressions over different time periods, one for the insurance intervention and one for the hospital intervention. We estimate the following two equations:
$$\displaystyle y_{{ct}} = \alpha_{c} + \alpha_{t} + \beta_{1}{post}_{1t}*{ME}_{c}{\ + \ \Gamma X_{{ct}} + e}_{{tc}},\ 1946 \leq t \leq 1955$$ | (1) |
$$\displaystyle y_{{ct}} = \alpha_{c} + \alpha_{t} + {\beta_{2}{post}_{2t}*H_{c} + \theta X_{{ct}} + u}_{{tc}},\ 1951 \leq t \leq 1965$$ | (2) |
where $$y_{{ct}}$$ is the outcome variable for county $$c$$ in year $$t$$. We also run event-study specifications of (1) and (2) in which we interact each of the intervention variables with indicators for each year.25
Our outcomes $$y_{{ct}}$$ include a number of health and health care outcomes. We measure effects on hospital birth rates, hospital admissions per 1,000, infant mortality per 1,000 births, overall mortality per 1,000, hospital beds per 1,000, and full-time equivalent (FTE) hospital employees per 1,000).
For the insurance intervention (equation 1), we interact two variables to estimate the causal effect of the insurance program ($$\beta_{1}$$). First, $${post}_{1t}$$ is an indicator for the post-intervention period for the insurance program and is set equal to one for all years 1950 and later.26 Second, $${ME}_{c}$$ is the 1950 county-level mining employment as a share of the total population age 14 and older. This measure is a proxy for the share of the population (miners and dependents) eligible for insurance. The more mining employment a county has, the more people are eligible for UMWA hospital insurance. This measure improves upon existing literature on the initial effects of public insurance because it has a finer level of geographic variation (the county).27
One potential issue is that the union insurance was only available to union coal miners, and we do not observe union membership. At the time, less than 10 percent of coal miners in Appalachia were non-union .28 Our measure counts some miners as insured who are not actually insured. If this measurement error is uncorrelated with our outcome measures, then it should bias our results toward zero. Instead, union membership may be correlated with the mining employment to population share. The most likely scenario is that union membership is positively correlated with mining employment: counties with high levels of mining employment also have high rates of union membership. In this case, mining employment share is a good proxy for union employment share and, therefore, insurance eligibility share, and our estimates are measuring the impact of the insurance. We view the opposite scenario as unlikely, that union membership is negatively correlated with true eligibility.
For the hospitals (equation 2), we interact two different variables to estimate the causal effect. First, $${post}_{2t}$$ is an indicator equal to one for all years 1956 and later.29 Second, $$H_{c}$$ is a county-level indicator for a union hospital. The level of treatment for the hospital program is the county. Though the primary intended beneficiaries of the UMWA hospitals were miners who already had UMWA insurance, the UMWA hospitals also accepted non-miner beneficiary patients.30 As a result, all residents of the county gained access to additional hospital facilities once the UMWA hospitals were opened.
In theory, the two natural experiments would allow us to estimate three separate effects: (i) the effect of union insurance without the union hospitals, (ii) the effect of union hospitals without union insurance, and (iii) the complementary effect of building hospitals in areas where people have health insurance. In equation (1), $$\beta_{1}$$ does in practice estimate (i). 31 In equation (2), we could in theory estimate (ii) and (iii) with a triple difference specification: $$\widetilde{\beta_{2}}{post}_{2t}*H_{c}$$ to estimate (ii) and $$\widetilde{\gamma_{2}}{post}_{2t}*H_{c}*{ME}_{c}$$ to estimate (iii). Because the UMWA built ten hospitals, we cannot separately identify (ii) from (iii) because there is not enough power.
We instead estimate two separate effects. In equation (1), we estimate the effects of the hospital insurance with $$\beta_{1}$$. In equation (2), we estimate $$\beta_{2}$$, the complementary effect of building hospitals in areas where people have health insurance. Going back to the triple difference specification, we can think of $$\beta_{2}$$ as the sum of $$\widetilde{\beta_{2}} + \widetilde{\gamma_{2}}$$ for a specific set of counties where a large share of the residents already had insurance.32
In both (1) and (2), we include a number of control variables to account for variation in our outcomes that is not due to the union health care interventions. First, we include county fixed effects, $$\alpha_{c}$$, to control for baseline pre-UMWA program county characteristics such as the number of hospitals, the number of physicians, or household income. Second, we include year fixed effects $$,\ \alpha_{t}$$, to control for region-wide shocks within year. Third, we control for observable time-varying characteristics of the counties in $$X_{{ct}}$$. Specifically, we include controls for county population, fertility rates (births to female population), the number of hospital beds added by the Hill-Burton program in each county-year during this time period, and an indicator for when a Hill-Burton project was approved in a given county-year.33 Finally, in (1), we also include a variable interacting $${post}_{1t}*{total\_ births}_{{ct}}$$. In other work, we find that when women get access to UMWA insurance, they have fewer children, likely because more children are expected to survive into adulthood ("quality-quantity" tradeoff) . We include this interaction term to control for these differential fertility effects.
To correct for differences in the county-year error term and improve precision, we estimate (1) and (2) using Weighted Least Squares (WLS), following guidance in Solon, Haider, and Wooldridge (2015). We weight by county-level population in regressions with the following outcome variables: hospital admissions per 1,000, overall mortality per 1,000, hospital admissions per 1,000, and hospital FTEs per 1,000. We weight by county-level births in regressions estimating effects on hospital birth rates and infant mortality. We cluster our standard errors at the county level.34
To identify $$\beta_{1}$$ and $$\beta_{2}$$, we rely on two key identification assumptions, one for each parameter. For $$\beta_{1}$$, the assumption is parallel trends in our outcome variables in low mining and high mining employment counties in the counterfactual world with no union insurance. For $$\beta_{2}$$, the assumption is parallel trends in our outcome variables in hospital counties and non-hospital counties in the counterfactual world with no union hospitals. Union hospital counties had higher levels of insured people compared to the average county in our sample, but as long as the trends in these counties would have been parallel in the absence of the hospitals, $$\beta_{2}$$ is identified. To support the plausibility of parallel trends, we examine whether there are differential pre-trends in each regression in their respective pre-periods. To do so, we run event-study specifications of (1) and (2) in which we interact each of the treatment variables with indicators for each year.
However, due to the timing and location of the hospitals, for parallel trends to hold for the hospitals, we must do an additional check. The post period for the insurance is the pre-period for the hospitals (Figure 3). Counties that eventually got hospitals were in fact differentially affected by the insurance compared to counties that did not. These differential effects could violate parallel trends for identifying $$\beta_{2}$$. However, violating parallel trends is not a given. Instead, it depends on the nature of the impact of the insurance over time. In particular, it depends on the slope of the insurance effect over time. If the impact of the insurance is a level shift, meaning the effect of the insurance does not grow or shrink over time, then parallel trends are likely to hold. Because we have annual data, we can examine the shape of the insurance effect over time. When we run (1), the insurance program regression, as an event study, we can measure the year-by-year differential effects between high insurance (high mining employment) and low insurance (low mining employment) counties using the coefficients in the event study regression. If these coefficients grow over time, then parallel trends are likely violated for identifying the casual effect of the hospitals.
As an example, we describe the impacts of hospital birth rates. If we run (1), we expect $$\beta_{1} > 0$$ for 1951 to 1955 (an increase in hospital birth rates post-insurance). With an event-study version of (1), we can identify year-by-year effects of the insurance in the post-period of 1951 to 1955, which is the pre-period for identifying $$\beta_{2}$$. The event-study specification measures differences in hospital birth rates between high and low insurance counties over time. Parallel trends for identifying $$\beta_{2}$$ are likely to hold if the slope of these event-study coefficients is flat rather than growing or shrinking over time. In other words, if hospital birth rates jump up to a higher but constant level in high insurance counties in the post-insurance but pre-hospitals period, then parallel trends for $$\beta_{2}$$ are likely to hold. If, instead, hospital birth rates jump to a higher level and then continue to rise in high mining counties relative to low mining counties, parallel trends are unlikely to hold.
We discuss the expected results of our empirical analysis using the theoretical framework of a market for hospital care. For the impact of the insurance intervention ($$\beta_{1}$$), we test whether the program caused an increase in the equilibrium quantity of hospital care in affected Appalachian counties. Giving people subsidized insurance lowers the price of health care. We expect that providing union coal miners and their dependents with free hospital insurance will increase demand for hospital care, or a shift to the right in the demand curve for hospital care services. This increased demand would result in an increase in both the equilibrium quantity of hospital care demanded and supplied in the market. As a result, we expect to see an increase in hospital birth rates and admissions and a corresponding increase in full time equivalent employees and hospital beds ( $$\beta_{1} > 0$$).
If increased hospital care is improving people's health, we also expect to see an improvement in health outcomes. At the time of the interventions, hospitals had just recently gained the technology to deliver life-saving antibiotics to reduce infant mortality .35 We are less likely to find a decline in overall mortality given the state of medical technology and the overwhelming amount of deaths due to heart disease.36 The additional care provided to adult miners is unlikely to have been able to prevent deaths from heart disease. However, because miners had access to hospital services such as rehabilitation after mining injuries, the UMWA insurance may have improved health outcomes for adults in ways we cannot measure with mortality data.
For the hospital intervention ($$\beta_{2}$$), we test whether building new hospitals in high insurance places further increased the equilibrium quantity of health care in these areas. It could be that the union hospitals simply crowded out existing private hospitals and doctors. If the supply side of the market had responded adequately to meet the new demand from the insurance by increasing hospital capacity, we would expect $$\beta_{2} \approx 0$$, or full crowd-out of existing hospitals. However, if the union hospitals responded to a true need for more hospital capacity, then we would expect $$\beta_{2} > 0$$ for hospital beds and FTEs. If $$\beta_{2} > 0$$, then the hospital intervention shifted the hospital care supply curve to the right. As a result, we expect to see an additional increase in the quantity of hospital care supplied and demanded.
Therefore, if $$\beta_{2}$$ is greater than zero and significant for measures of hospital capacity, we might also expect $$\beta_{2} > 0$$ for our health care utilization outcomes (increase in quantity demanded as a result of the shift to the right in the hospital supply). Finally, if the new hospitals and health care employees were in fact better at preventing deaths, we would expect further declines in infant and overall mortality rates, or $$\beta_{2} < 0$$.
We find the strongest effects of the insurance program on measures of hospital utilization and infant mortality. For the hospital program, we find the strongest effects on hospital capacity beds and FTEs. We discuss our results separately by intervention: first union hospital insurance, then union hospitals.
We first discuss results from the first union health care intervention: hospital insurance for union coal miners, working and retired, and their dependents. The first row of Table 3 shows estimates for $$\beta_{1}$$, our difference-in-differences estimator for the impact of the insurance program (the coefficient on Post Ins x Mining EPop share 1950), from equation (1). These estimates measure the average impact of a county going from zero employment in mining and no insurance coverage to all workers employed in mining and eligible for insurance (minus non-union miners). We also show that, for a version of the hospital birth rate regression, with certain assumptions, $$\beta_{1}$$ can be interpreted as a household-level treatment effect.
In the left-hand side graphs of Figure 4, 5, and 6, we examine whether counties with high population shares of mining employment trended differently than those with low shares before 1950, when the hospital insurance program began. We normalize the year 1948 to zero. 37
In theory, once people enroll in subsidized health insurance, we expect increased hospital utilization. Consistent with this theory, we find large utilization effects of the insurance for pregnant women, who received free hospital obstetric care for the first time. Table 3, row (1), column (1) shows that the union insurance increased the fraction of births in a hospital. The coefficient can be interpreted as the effect of UMWA insurance on our outcomes when our treatment variable increases from zero to one. In other words, the treatment effect for a county in our sample going from zero mining employment (and no one eligible for insurance) to all individuals in the county age 14 and older working in mining (and all individuals eligible for insurance). The estimated coefficient of 0.660 suggests that for the average county with 3 percent of its population age 14 and older employed in mining, hospital birth rates increase by around 0.02, or a percent increase of 3 percent.38 For counties with very high shares of mining employment (in 95th percentile and above), hospital birth rates increase by 15 percent or more (10 percentage points).
In Figure 4, panel (a), the left graph shows little evidence of pre-trends. However, there is a small spike in 1949, indicating that slightly more women in high insurance counties delivered their babies in a hospital during the UMWA's short-lived initial program. This difference goes away the following year before jumping and staying at a relatively stable but elevated level from 1952 to 1955. The slope of the coefficients is relatively constant starting in 1952, which supports the assumption of parallel trends for estimating causal effects of the hospitals.
We run an alternate specification of (1) to calculate a back-of-the envelope measure of a household-level impact of the insurance. In other words, a measure of the probability a woman in an insured household gives birth in a hospital. We rely on a number of assumptions to calculate this household-level effect (we provide additional detail in Appendix A). The key assumption comes from the fact that we do not observe the number of mining households in a given county that also had a birth in 1950. Instead, we rely on a proxy. Birth rates among mining households were 2.7 percentage points higher than non-mining households in 1950, according to data from the 1950 decennial census 1 percent sample . We take the average share of households with a birth in 1950 in the Vital Statistics data, and we scale it up by 2.7 percentage point to account for the higher birth rate in mining households.
In this alternate specification, we find that the insurance increases the probability of delivering in a hospital by 3 percentage points for the average mining household. Column (6) of Table 3 shows the results of this alternative specification. The point estimate of three percentage points is a percent increase of 5 percent, going from a probability of 0.61 before the UMWA insurance to a probability of 0.64.
We find more suggestive evidence that the insurance increased overall hospital admissions, which could reflect some combination of increased admissions of pregnant women and other types of patients. Table 3, row (1), column (2) presents the results of running (1) with hospital admissions per 1,000 people on the left hand side. The coefficient of 65.56 from column (2) indicates that for the average Appalachian county, the insurance induces an increase of around 2 additional admissions per thousand people (significant at the ten percent level).39 This represents a percentage increase of around 4 percent from a pre-intervention average of around 53 admissions per thousand. Figure 4, panel (b), left graph shows results of a version of the regression in Table 3, row (1) column (1) with indicators for each year multiplied by the mining employment to population age 14 and over share. There is no evidence of pre-trends in Figure 4. However, the data on hospital admissions begin in 1948, reducing the number of pre-intervention years to one in fixed effects specifications.
The average treatment effects on hospital admissions are smaller than those associated with the introduction of Medicare, a much larger subsidized insurance program that covered people 65 and older . Finkelstein (2007) finds that Medicare increased hospital admissions by 46 percent, on average, much higher than our point estimate of four percent. However, Medicare was a larger intervention covering nearly an additional 7.5 percent of Americans.40 Therefore, it is unsurprising that our average treatment effects on hospital admissions are smaller than those associated with the introduction of Medicare.
We find that the insurance reduces infant mortality. Table 3, row (1), column (3) shows for the average Appalachia county, going from zero people working in mining to 100 percent of people working in mining, UMWA insurance reduces infant mortality by around 21 per thousand. For the average Appalachian county with three percent of the population age 14 and older employed in mining, the insurance reduces the infant mortality rate by around 0.66 per thousand, or a percentage decline of around two percent.. Figure 5, panel (a), left graph shows that the yearly estimates of the effect on infant mortality are noisier, and that in 1947 there is some evidence of pre-trends. However, there is a clear decline in 1950 for counties with higher population shares of mining employment. These counties have increasingly lower rates of infant mortality as time goes on, which means that the parallel trends assumption for the complementary impact of the hospitals in high insurance counties on infant mortality may be violated.
In comparison to the literature, our results are in line with previous studies of the Medicaid program . However, unlike the UMWA insurance, Medicaid also provided coverage for primary care in addition to hospital care. Currie and Gruber (1996) find that, for a state with the average increase in Medicaid eligibility of 0.30, Medicaid reduced infant mortality by around 1 deaths per 1,000 births, from a base of around 10 deaths per 1,000 births. Bacon-Goodman (2018) finds similar results for Medicaid's initial rollout, though the declines were larger in percentage terms.
Finally, we do not find evidence of reductions in overall mortality. Overall mortality includes all deaths, infant and older. Infant deaths are around 9 percent of total deaths in our sample, so even if the program provided no reductions in mortality for non-infants, we might still expect to see some effects for overall mortality, entirely driven by the observed reductions in infant mortality. However, as Table 3, row (1), column (4) shows, our estimates are noisy, and we cannot rule out large negative or positive effects. While we find no effects on overall mortality, our results cannot be interpreted to conclude the insurance had no effect on health outcomes. It is possible that the UMWA insurance improved the health outcomes of adult miners along dimensions which are not well measured by reductions in mortality, such as enhanced mobility from physical rehabilitation for which we lack data to estimate the effect.
In section III.1.a, we find that the insurance program increased hospital births and overall hospital admissions, even though many eligible people lived far from a quality hospital. These results point to increased demand for hospital care, and, as a result, an increase in the equilibrium amount of hospital care. Therefore, we might expect to see corresponding increases in measures of hospital care supply to meet this new demand. We analyze this response using the number of hospital beds per 1,000. Row (1), column (5) of Table 3 shows results for the impact of the insurance program on hospital beds per 1,000. We find no clear evidence of increased hospital beds. However, we cannot rule out large effects, as the standard errors are large.
Though our paper analyzes an area in the U.S., given the health and living conditions in Appalachia at the time, our results may also inform the development literature on health care interventions in underserved areas outside the U.S. Programs such as subsidized insurance and incentivized doctor visits in developing countries, such as in Kenya and Indonesia, often suffer from problems such as low take-up and limited supply side response . In comparison, our results do suggest that the programs in Appalachia generally had high take up. However, like some of these health insurance programs in developing countries, the UMWA's concerns about the supply side of hospital care was a key factor in the decision to build new hospitals in coal country.
We now turn to results on the UMWA's second intervention, the union hospitals. Our results measure a type of local average treatment effect (LATE), answering the following policy-relevant question: What happens when hospitals are built in areas where large shares of the population can afford to use them? As with the insurance program results, across each table, each column has a different set of controls. To test for pre-trends, we turn to the right graphs of Figures 4 through 6. These figures represent an event-study version of equation (2), displaying coefficients for the hospital intervention multiplied by indicators for each year. The year before the intervention (1955) is normalized to zero.
We find stark increases in hospital beds in counties with UMWA hospitals. Table 4, row (1), columns (5) and (6) estimate equation (2) with the total number of hospital beds and full-time equivalent hospital employees as dependent variables, respectively. For the average county with a UMWA hospital, there was an increase of around 1.6 beds per thousand people (column 5). This represents a percent increase of around 80 percent for counties with UMWA hospitals.41 Figure 6, panel (a) right graph, shows a large, clear, persistent jump in the number of beds post-1956. We also find no evidence of differential pre-trends between counties where the UMWA built hospitals and counties where they did not. Even though we see no pre-trends in the top-right graph, to be cautious, we note that in the left graph, the point estimates suggest evidence of a steady and growing increase in beds in high insurance counties before the hospitals opened in 1956. However, these increases are noisy and much smaller in magnitude than those in the right graph. This is especially true considering results in the left graph must be scaled down: the estimates are for a county with 100 percent of its population age 14 and older employed in mining. The highest mining employment county had around 30 percent of the population employed in mining.
We find large increases in the number of hospital FTEs. Table 4, column (6), shows an increase of around 3 FTEs per thousand, more than double the employees compared to a pre-intervention mean of around 2 per thousand.42 Figure 6, panel (b) shows a sharp increase in FTEs with no evidence of differential pre-intervention trends.
The increases in hospital beds and FTEs suggest a complementarity between the union insurance and the union hospitals. We further explore this complementarity by directly comparing our results to the Hill-Burton hospital construction program in Chung, Gaynor, and Richards-Shubik (2017). The Hill-Burton program was a contemporary of the UMWA's programs, but it did not explicitly target counties where large shares of people already had health insurance. Moreover, it began well before the US public insurance programs expanded health insurance coverage on a widespread basis. Therefore, the scope for complementarities between Hill-Burton hospitals and insurance was limited. Another key difference is that, unlike the Hill-Burton program, the UMWA program actively recruited quality doctors and paid them a salary rather than fee-for-service. Differences between the impacts of the UMWA program and the Hill-Burton program are likely driven by complementarities between the insurance and the hospitals.43
We directly compare our findings to the Hill-Burton program by running a specification that measures the impact of the UMWA hospitals on a "per new bed" basis. In Figure 7, we run an event-study version of (2) with a different measure of intervention for the hospital program, similar to a specification used to analyze Hill-Burton in Chung, Gaynor, and Richards-Shubik (2017). Instead of using an indicator for whether a county got a hospital, we instead use the number of additional hospital beds in the new UMWA hospitals in a given county (not the total number of hospital beds, only the new beds in the new UMWA hospitals). The right-hand side is the same as in Table 4 column (5), total beds in a given county (UMWA beds plus other existing hospital beds in each county).
We find that the union hospitals had far lower crowd-out rates than the Hill-Burton program. To compare the two programs, we take a conservative approach and look at results a few years after the hospitals opened, giving the market more time to adjust to the new UMWA hospital entry. If we look at results for 1959, after the hospitals had been open for four years, we find that for every additional new UMWA hospital bed, total hospital beds increase by around 0.70, or a crowd-out rate of 0.30. This rate is significantly higher than that found in a comparable time frame by Chung, Gaynor, and Richards-Shubik (2017).44
We do not find evidence of additional effects on health care utilization. Table 4, column (2) row (3) presents results for the impact of the hospital intervention on admissions per thousand, which positive but statistically insignificant. The UMWA hospitals increased hospital admissions by 18 additional admissions per 1,000, or a percent increase of around 15 percent for the average county. Table 4, column (1) row (3) shows statistically significant increases in hospital births. However, these results do not hold up to state-year trends (Table A.2). Our results are noisy, and we cannot rule out large positive or large negative effects.
We also do not find evidence of further improvements in health outcomes. While the point estimates in Table 4, column (3) row (3) show statistically significant declines in infant mortality, the right graph in Figure 5 panel (a)shows pre-trends, which is not surprising given that the declines in infant mortality caused by the insurance were increasing in magnitude over time (panel (a), left graph). Finally, while Table 4, column (4) row (3) shows that the hospitals may have reduced overall mortality, the right graph of Figure 5, panel (b) shows some evidence of pre-trends.
These results do not rule out positive effects on health care utilization or other measures of health status. Mortality is a relatively coarse measure of health status that may not capture the marginal improvements in health care provided by the union hospitals. For example, the union hospitals provided state-of-the-art specialists in rehabilitation care for injured coal miners. Better measures of health status such as mobility would likely show further improvements once the hospitals opened. It may be that the marginal improvement in maternal and infant care at the union hospitals was not large enough to detect additional improvements in hospital births or infant mortality.
We address a number of alternative explanations for our results. First, we show that unobserved state-year time trends have little effect on the qualitative discussion of the results above (Tables A.1 and A.2). Second, we investigate coal wages compared to overall non-farm wages during our sample and find little evidence for increased coal income as a driver for the observed improvements in health care outcomes. If coal wages were growing much faster than wages for other occupations during the 1950s, then higher wage growth would be correlated with the insurance intervention as measured by the coal employment to working age population ratio. Assuming health care is a normal good, coal miner households may simply be getting paid more and consuming more health care as a result. Our observed increases in hospital care from the UMWA insurance may not be due to health insurance at all but instead simply an income effect due to higher coal wages. Figure 8 plots real hourly wages for all non-farm workers and real hourly coal wages from 1947 to 1965 . While coal wages are higher, on average, the trends in the two series are similar. It would be worrisome if there was a differential trend break in 1950 for mining wages compared to non-mining wages. Therefore, it is unlikely that the effects we observe are income effects rather than direct effects of the health insurance.
Third, we address potential effects of the Second Great Migration. Though the 1940s and 1950s were a historic period of migration for African Americans from southern rural areas to northern cities, it is unlikely that this movement could cause the observed improvements in health care that we attribute to the union health care programs. If African Americans were migrating out of mining counties, there could be differential effects driven by outmigration rather than the UMWA health programs. More African Americans families were living in poverty than white families at this time, so outmigration would tend to make the overall population richer on average, and therefore demand more health care . Alternatively, there could be more African American out-migration in the control counties (non-mining/UMWA hospital). If this is the case, the control counties would be getting differentially higher income, on average, which would attenuate our treatment effects rather than augment them. However, unlike other areas in the American South, there were very few African Americans in Appalachia, and even fewer in areas with high levels of coal mining, our intervention areas. The average U.S. county had a nonwhite population of around 11 percent in 1950, while the average Appalachian county in the 90th percentile of coal employment to population had a nonwhite population of just 3.5 percent.
Fourth, other programs, such as the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) and the War on Poverty programs, also likely have little impact on our results. The TVA funded a series of large investments in the Tennessee valley region, which some evidence suggests led to an increase in both agricultural and manufacturing employment in region .45 During the time frame of our analysis, TVA increased and then sharply decreased funding to counties in the region. The increase coincided with the UMWA's insurance program, and the decrease happened three years after the UMWA hospitals opened. The increase in income associated with high employment levels could increase health care utilization and health outcomes, and the decrease could have the opposite effect. 111 counties are part of both the TVA and Appalachia. Of these 111 counties, only 26 counties had mining employment as a share of the population greater than one percent. As a result, the TVA counties in our sample primarily serve as control counties in our analysis. For the insurance program TVA would likely bias our results to zero, since the control counties would be getting richer as a result of the program (just as is the case if there was differential out-migration by African Americans in our control counties). For the hospitals, the opposite is true, but we do not observe any differential changes in our estimates starting in 1959, when TVA began to cut funding. Nevertheless, we conduct our analysis excluding the TVA counties. Our findings, reported in Tables A.3 and A.4, are robust to excluding these counties from the analysis.
Finally, to address any confounding effects of the War on Poverty programs, we end our sample period in 1965. Medicare and Medicaid did not begin providing benefits until 1966 . Similarly, Medicare did not begin providing benefits until 1966. Other programs, such as the funding of the Appalachian Development Highway System, did not begin until 1965 . Alternatively, because some of the War on Poverty programs such as the Area Redevelopment Act of 1961 and the Food Stamp Program began before 1965, our results are robust to excluding years after 1959 (results available upon request).
We examine the impacts of a union hospital care insurance program with and without a complementary hospital construction program. Without the hospitals, the insurance program increased hospital births and reduced infant mortality. The program reduced infant mortality by 0.02 per 1,000 births, equal to around 30 percent of the overall gap in infant mortality between the U.S. and Appalachia. However, we do not find statistically significant increases in the supply of hospitals or health care workers to treat newly insured union patients. Once the union hospitals opened, the supply of hospital beds and health care workers increased substantially. We, however, do not find statistically significant improvements in health care utilization or mortality after the hospitals opened.
Our findings suggest a role for complementary effects of hospitals in areas with a large insured population. The union hospitals substantially increased the net number of hospital beds and health care workers. These effects suggest that existing private hospitals did not adequately meet demand for hospital care. Moreover, crowd-out rates were much lower compared to a similar hospital construction program that did not complement any existing insurance program. However, with our data, we do not find statistically significant evidence that mortality, both infant and overall, improved as a result. Therefore, we cannot conclude that the hospitals made the insurance more effective at preventing deaths. It is possible that the hospitals improved outcomes along other dimensions that we cannot measure with our data, such as mobility or even financial security. It is also possible that there were no further improvements. As policymakers look to expand public health insurance in underserved areas, further research with other data on health outcomes and household finance can improve our understanding of complementarities between insurance and hospitals.
We interpret our results for hospital births rates as household level probabilities by running an alternate specification of (1). To generate this specification, we start with the simple case where mining employment is randomly assigned across households in the population. If we had household level data on occupation and births, we would run the following regression for the sample of households with women who gave birth in each given year:
$${hosp\_ birth}_{{hct}} = \alpha + \gamma{mining1950}_{{hc}} + v_{{ict}}$$ (3) for $$h$$ with a birth in year $$t$$,
where $${hosp\_ birth}_{{hct}}$$ is an indicator for whether a given birth in a given household $$h$$ was in a hospital in county $$c$$ year $$t$$. $${mining1950}_{{hct}}$$ is an indicator for whether the household that had a birth is also a mining household in 1950 when the program launched. We can aggregate (3) to the county level, and we have
where $${hosp\_ birth}_{{ct}}$$ is total hospital births in county $$c$$ year $$t$$, and $${mining1950}_{{ct}}$$ is total households that were both mining households in 1950 and had a child in county $$c$$ year $$t$$ (recall that being a mining household in 1950 is simply a proxy for treatment, as we assume miners stay on the UMWA insurance once they become eligible). We can divide both sides of the equation by $${total\_ births}_{{ct}}$$ to get:
$$\frac{{hosp\_ birth}_{{ct}}}{{total\_ births1950}_{c}} = \frac{\alpha}{{total\_ births1950}_{c}} + \gamma\frac{{mining1950}_{c}}{{total\_ births1950}_{c}} + \frac{n_{{ict}}}{{total\_ births1950}_{c}}$$ (3')
We must assume one birth per household per year, then $${total\_ births}_{c}$$ is equal to the number of households that had a child in a given county-year. We also assume one miner per household. With these assumptions, we can interpret the numerator $${mining1950}_{{ct}}$$ as total mining households that had a child in a given county-year. The term $$\frac{{mining1950}_{c}}{{total\_ births1950}_{c}} = \frac{{total\_ mining\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}{{total\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}$$ is then share of eligible households among all households that had a child in a given year. In our main regression (1), we have $${ME}_{c} = \frac{{total\_ mining\_ workers1950}_{c}}{{population\_ over141950}_{c}}$$. For this exercise, we again assume one miner per household, meaning that $${total\_ mining\_ workers}_{c} = \ {total\_ mining\_ households}_{c}$$.
We use the county level data to arrive at calculation of $$\frac{{total\_ mining\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}{{total\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}$$ . We already have the denominator, $${total\_ hh\_ withbirth}_{{ct}} = {total\_ births}_{{ct}}$$, in the county-level data. We are missing the numerator, the number of mining households also had a child in a given year. Instead, we have total mining households (regardless of whether they had a child). To calculate a measure of the numerator, we scale total mining households down by the average county-level birth rate across all households in 1950. We then adjust that number up 2.7 percentage points for each county. Our adjustment is derived from the 1% sample of the 1950 decennial census . Specifically, we calculate that in the 1% sample of the 1950 decennial census white males between the ages of 16 and 59 working in coal mining and living in a state with at least one county in Appalachia (Alabama, Georgia, Kentucky, Maryland, Mississippi, New York, North Carolina, Ohio, Pennsylvania, South Carolina, Tennessee, Virginia, and West Virginia) are 2.7 percentage points more likely to have a child under the age of one, a proxy for a birth in the year 1950, than white males working in an industry that is not coal mining and living in a state with at least one county in Appalachia. Given our other assumptions, we can refer to our estimate from the 1% sample of the 1950 census as the estimate for mining households.
We proxy for $$\frac{{total\_ mining\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}{{total\_ mining\_ households}_{{ct}}}$$ with $$\frac{{total\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}{{{total\_ hh\_ 1950}_{c}}_{c}} + 0.027$$
We apply this calculation to our difference-in-differences specification by running a version of (1) with a different treatment variable. Instead of mining employment as a share of population 14+ ( $${ME}_{c} = \frac{{total\_ mining\_ workers}_{c}}{{population\_ over14}_{c}}$$), we use the above proxy for the share of mining households that had a birth in 1950, or the share of births in households that gained insurance in 1950 ( $$\frac{{total\_ mining\_ households1950}_{c} \times (\frac{{total\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}{{{total\_ hh\_ 1950}_{c}}_{c}} + 0.027)}{{total\_ hh\_ withbirth1950}_{c}}$$).
Number of Observations (1) |
Mean (2) |
Standard Deviation (3) |
Minimum (4) |
Maximum (5) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Fraction Births in Hospital | 7,980 | 0.816 | 0.214 | 0.0380 | 1 |
Infant Mortality per 1000 Births | 7,980 | 30.30 | 11.44 | 0 | 100 |
Adult Mortality per 1000 | 7,980 | 9.216 | 1.995 | 3.254 | 21.30 |
Population | 7,980 | 44,188 | 93,915 | 2,875 | 1,628,587 |
Number of Hospitals | 7,161 | 1.394 | 1.990 | 0 | 27 |
County Real Median Household Income (in 2016$) | 7,980 | 35,752 | 16,125 | 5,467 | 84,627 |
Mining Employment-to-Population Share 1950 | 7,980 | 0.0311 | 0.0526 | 0 | 0.282 |
Hospital County (Indicator) | 7,980 | 0.0251 | 0.156 | 0 | 1 |
Births per Female Population | 7,980 | 0.111 | 0.0184 | 0.0490 | 0.235 |
First Year Hill-Burton | 6,840 | 1,954 | 6.122 | 1,947 | 1,971 |
Hill Burton Beds/1000 | 7,980 | 0.934 | 1.457 | 0 | 10.52 |
Admissions/1000 | 6,989 | 84.40 | 84.17 | 0 | 1,053 |
Beds/1000 | 7,134 | 2.215 | 2.190 | 0 | 23.00 |
Hospital Full-Time Equivalent Employees per 1000 | 5,819 | 3.048 | 3.550 | 0 | 54.20 |
Doctors(MDs)/1000 | 1,197 | 0.599 | 0.368 | 0 | 5.081 |
Mean (1) |
Standard Deviation (2) |
Minimum (3) |
Maximum (4) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|
Fraction Births in Hospital | 0.614 | 0.232 | 0.0795 | 0.995 |
Infant Mortality per 1,000 Births | 36.38 | 11.97 | 0 | 71.21 |
Adult Mortality per 1,000 | 8.712 | 2.155 | 3.615 | 21.30 |
Population | 43,374 | 89,474 | 3,515 | 1,494,497 |
Number of Hospitals | 1.190 | 1.963 | 0 | 25 |
County Real Median Household Income (in 2016$) | 18,336 | 7,082 | 5,467 | 36,071 |
Hospital County (Indicator) | 0.0251 | 0.157 | 0 | 1 |
Mining Employment-to-Population Share (Decade) | 0.0276 | 0.0464 | 0 | 0.298 |
Births per Female Pop | 0.120 | 0.0197 | 0.0778 | 0.190 |
Admissions per 1,000 | 53.15 | 66.35 | 0 | 525.9 |
Beds per 1,000 | 1.460 | 1.745 | 0 | 12.90 |
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, Hill-Burton Project Register, and the American Hospital Association Annual Survey.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
Beds (5) |
Hospital Births (6) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Insurance x Mining EPop Share 1950 |
0.660*** (0.0796) |
65.56* (36.39) |
-21.45*** (4.818) |
-0.369 (0.651) |
0.287 (0.464) |
|
Post Insurance x Household Mining Share 1950 |
0.0308* (0.0162) |
|||||
Mean dependent variable in 1948 | 0.61 | 53.15 | 36.38 | 8.71 | 1.46 | 0.61 |
Mean mining Employment-to-Population Share in 1950 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | |
Mean mining share of households in 1950 | 0.092 | |||||
Observations | 3,990 | 3,138 | 3,990 | 3,990 | 3,192 | 3,990 |
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, Hill-Burton Project Register, and the American Hospital Association Annual Survey.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
Beds (5) |
FTEs (6) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Hosp. x Hosp. County (Indicator) |
0.0660*** (0.0199) |
10.52 (9.623) |
-5.629*** (1.948) |
0.266 (0.164) |
1.609*** (0.261) |
3.080*** (0.534) |
Mean dependent variable (average 1951-1955) | 0.80 | 71.75 | 30.76 | 8.69 | 1.94 | 2.07 |
Share of counties with a UMWA hospital | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 |
Observations | 5,985 | 5,813 | 5,985 | 5,985 | 5,937 | 5,819 |
Figure 1: County Mining Employment in 1950 as a Share of Population Age 14 and Older in the Appalachian Region
Notes: The counties within the blue bolded line are considered Appalachia. Counties are defined as part of Appalachia using the Appalachian
Regional Commission's (ARC) 1967 definition of Appalachian counties. Only states with at least one county in Appalachia are included in the figure. The fraction of mining employment in each county is calculated as the fraction of individuals employed in mining divided by total county population age
14 and older.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File and data from the ARC 1967 provided by James Ziliak.
Figure 2: Locations of the United Mine Workers Hospitals and the County Mining Employment as a Share of Population Age 14 and Older in Central Appalachia
Notes: Only Appalachia counties in states in Central Appalachia are included. The United Mine Workers
of America (UMWA) opened ten state-of-the-art hospitals in central Appalachia in 1956, known as the Miners' Memorial Hospitals, indicated by the green triangles in the map. The UMWA hospitals were opened in ten counties with a high concentration of health insurance coverage. While these hospitals
were run by the UMWA, the hospitals served both miners and non-miners.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File and hospital location based on Ford et al. (1962).
Figure 3: Timeline of Interventions
Notes: The United Mine Workers of America (UMWA) began providing free hospital care insurance in June 1950 and opened ten state-of-the-art hospitals in central Appalachia in late 1955 and 1956. We chose 1946 as the
starting year of our analysis period because 1946 marks the beginning of the post-World War II period. We chose 1965 as the last year in our analysis period to avoid confounding effects from the introduction of Medicare and Medicaid in 1966.
Source: Authors' illustration.
Figure 4: Effects of UMWA Programs on Health Care Utilization
Notes: Each dot represents the coefficient from a county-year regression interacting a set of year fixed effects with treatment variable. The bars show the 95 percent confidence interval of the
coefficient estimates. In the left figures, the sample includes years from 1946 to 1956 and the treatment variable is the fraction of mining employment of each county in 1950. In the right figures, the sample includes years from 1951 to 1965 and the treatment variable is a dummy variable for a UMWA
hospital. The dashed lines indicate the year of the interventions - 1950 for the insurance intervention and 1956 for the completion of the hospitals. Standard errors are clustered at the county level. Control variables included in the regression are the number of births of residence in the county,
the population of the county, and the fraction of mining employment in the county, year fixed effects (omitting 1948 in the right graph and 1955 in the left graph), and county fixed effects. In addition, the figures on the left include an interaction between the post indicator (equal to one for
years 1950 and later) and the total number of births. To correct for differences in the county-year error term and improve precision, we estimate the regressions using Weighted Least Squares. The analysis in (a) is weighted by county-level births and the analysis in (b) is weighted by county-level
population.
Source: Authors' calculation using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, Hill-Burton Project Register, the American Hospital Association's annual survey, and the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure 5: Effects of UMWA Programs on Mortality
Notes: Each dot represents the coefficient from a county-year regression interacting a set of year fixed effects with each treatment variable. The bars show the 95 percent confidence interval of the
coefficient estimates. In the left figures, the sample includes years 1946- 1956 and the treatment variable is the fraction of mining employment of each county in 1950. In the right figures, the sample includes years from 1951 to 1965 and the treatment variable is a dummy variable for a UMWA
hospital. The dashed lines indicate the year of the interventions - 1950 for the insurance intervention and 1956 for the completion of the hospitals. Standard errors are clustered at the county level. Control variables included in the regression are the number of births of residents in the county,
the population of the county, and the fraction of mining employment in the county, year fixed effects (omitting 1948 in the right graph and 1955 in the left graph), and county fixed effects. In addition, the figures on the left include an interaction between the post indicator (equal to one for
years 1950 and later) and the total number of births. To correct for differences in the county-year error term and improve precision, we estimate the regressions using Weighted Least Squares. The analysis in (a) is weighted by county-level births and the analysis in (b) is weighted by county-level
population.
Source: Authors' calculation using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, Hill-Burton Project Register, the American Hospital Association's annual survey, and the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure 6: Effects of UMWA Programs on Inputs to Hospital Supply
Notes: Each dot represents the coefficient from a county-year regression interacting a set of year fixed effects with each treatment variable. The bars show the 95 percent confidence interval
of the coefficient estimates. For the estimates of the effect of hospital beds per 1,000, the sample in the left figure of panel (a) includes all years prior to 1956 and the treatment variable is the fraction of mining employment of each county in 1950. In the right figure of panel (a), the sample
includes years from 1951 to 1965 and the treatment variable is a dummy variable for a UMWA hospital. For the estimates of the effect on full-time equivalent employees (FTEs) in panel (b), the American Hospitals Association (AHA) hospital survey does not include data on FTEs until 1951. As a result,
we cannot perform estimates for the effects of the insurance on FTEs. The dashed lines indicate the year of the interventions - 1950 for the insurance intervention and 1956 for the completion of the hospitals. Standard errors are clustered at the county level. Control variables included in the
regression are the number of births of residence in the county, the population of the county, and the fraction of mining employment in the county, year fixed effects (omitting 1948 in the right graph and 1955 in the left graph for the hospital beds per 1,000, and omitting 1955), and county fixed
effects. In addition, the left figure of panel (a) includes an interaction between the post indicator (equal to one for years 1950 and later) and the total number of births. To correct for differences in the county-year error term and improve precision, we estimate the regressions using Weighted
Least Squares. The analysis in (a) is weighted by county-level births and the analysis in (b) is weighted by county-level population. Source: Authors' calculation using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, Hill-Burton Project Register, the American Hospital Association's annual survey, and the
United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure 7: Crowd-out Effects of UMWA Hospitals
Notes: Each dot represents the coefficient from a county-year regression interacting a set of year fixed effects with each treatment variable. The bars show the 95 percent confidence interval of the coefficient
estimates. The sample includes years from 1951 to 1965. Instead of using an indicator for whether a county got a hospital, we instead use the number of additional hospital beds in the new UMWA hospitals in a given county (not the total number of hospital beds, only the new beds in the new UMWA
hospitals). The right-hand side is the total beds in a given county (UMWA beds plus other existing hospital beds in each county). The dashed line indicates the year of the intervention -1956 for the completion of the hospitals. Standard errors are clustered at the county level. Control variables
included in the regression are the number of births of residence in the county, the population of the county, and the fraction of mining employment in the county, year fixed effects (omitting 1955), and county fixed effects.
Source: Authors' calculation using data from the Hill-Burton Project
Register, the American Hospital Association's annual survey, and the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure 8: Real Hourly Wages 1947-1965.
Source: Authors' calculation using data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1991. "Employment, Hours, and Earnings, United States, 1909-1990 Volume 1."
Notes: Asterisks denote levels of significance: 1% (***) level of significance; 5% (**) level of significance; and 10% (*) level of significance. Each column represents a separate regression. The dependent variable of each regression is indicated by the column heading - (1) hospital births per 1,000, (2) admission per 1,000, (3) infant morality per 1,000 births, (4) overall mortality per 1,000, and (5) hospital beds per 1,000. Controls in each regression include county population, county fertility rate (births to female population), an indicator for whether the year was after the county first received Hill-Burton funding, the number of additional beds the county received that were funded by Hill-Burton, county fixed effects, year fixed effects, and state-by-year time trends. In addition, each regression includes an interaction between the post indicator (equal to one for years 1950 and later) and the total number of births to control for the fact that, after the creation of the UMWA insurance, women had fewer children, likely because more children were expected to survive into adulthood. The variable of interest in each regression is the interaction of the indicator after the insurance was implemented (equal to one for years 1950 and later) and the 1950 county-level mining employment as a share of total population age 14 and older. The sample is limited to years 1946 to 1955, with 1955 being the last year in the sample because, in 1956, the UMWA hospitals opened. In columns (2) and (5), the sample size is reduced because the dependent variables are drawn from the American Hospital Association's (AHA) annual survey, which does not begin until 1948. Additional observations are lost in column (5) due to missing data on the number of beds in the AHA data. To correct for differences in the county-year error term and improve precision, we estimate the regressions using Weighted Least Squares. Columns (1) and (3) are weighted by county-level births. Columns (2), (4), and (5) are weighted by county-level population. The mean of the 1950 county-level mining employment as a share of total population age 14 and older and the mean of the dependent variable are unweighted.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, and the American Hospital Association Annual Survey.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
Beds (5) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Ins. x Mining EPop Share 1950 |
0.650*** (0.0786) |
100.3*** (38.18) |
-17.26*** (6.116) |
-0.352 (0.741) |
0.552 (0.555) |
Mean dependent variable in 1948 | 0.614 | 53.153 | 36.381 | 8.712 | 1.460 |
Mean mining EPop Share in 1950 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 |
Observations | 3,990 | 3,138 | 3,990 | 3,990 | 3,192 |
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, and the American Hospital Association Annual Survey.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
FTEs (5) |
Beds (6) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Hosp. x Hosp. County (Indicator) |
-0.00153 (0.0261) |
3.558 (10.75) |
-3.748* (2.104) |
-0.0214 (0.183) |
3.007*** (0.577) |
1.424*** (0.279) |
Mean dependent variable in 1951 | 0.730 | 63.533 | 32.077 | 8.697 | 1.686 | 1.689 |
Share of counties with a UMWA hospital | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 |
Observations | 5,985 | 5,813 | 5,985 | 5,985 | 5,819 | 5,937 |
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, the American Hospital Association Annual Survey, and the Kline and Moretti (2013) replication file.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
Beds (5) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Ins. x Mining EPop Share 1950 |
0.694*** (0.0830) |
91.78*** (35.13) |
-18.69*** (4.751) |
-0.223 (0.718) |
0.200 (0.501) |
Mean dependent variable in 1948 | 0.614 | 53.153 | 36.381 | 8.712 | 1.460 |
Mean mining EPop Share in 1950 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.031 |
Observations | 2,880 | 2,263 | 2,880 | 2,880 | 2,304 |
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the U.S. Vital Statistics, the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File, the American Hospital Association Annual Survey, and the Kline and Moretti (2013) replication file.
Hospital Births (1) |
Admissions (2) |
Infant Mortality (3) |
Overall Mortality (4) |
FTEs (5) |
Beds (6) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Post Hosp. x Hosp. County (Indicator) |
0.0676*** (0.0215) |
10.59 (10.71) |
-5.075** (1.999) |
0.326* (0.176) |
3.043*** (0.589) |
1.619*** (0.289) |
Mean dependent variable in 1951 | 0.730 | 63.533 | 32.077 | 8.697 | 1.686 | 1.689 |
Share of counties with a UMWA hospital | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.025 |
Observations | 4,320 | 4,202 | 4,320 | 4,320 | 4,204 | 4,293 |
Figure A.1: County Mining Employment as a Share of Total Population Age 14 and Older by County, 1950
Notes: The counties within the blue bolded line are considered Appalachia. The fraction of mining employment in each county is calculated as the
fraction of individuals employed in mining divided by total population age 14 and older.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure A.2: Cumulative Hill-Burton Beds Provided per 1,000, 1950 and 1960
Notes: Maps include all states that contain at least one county in the Appalachian Regional Commission's list of counties in Appalachia. Hill-Burton provided beds are
defined as the number of cumulative beds each project that received Hill-Burton funding provided. Because the Hill-Burton Project Register only provides data on when the project received initial approval from the Public Health Service Regional Offices, we define the year in which the Hill-Burton
beds were provided as the year the project was approved. The number of cumulative Hill-Burton beds is divided by the population in county in the relevant year. The cutoffs are defined as the quintiles of those counties that received at least some Hill-Burton funding as of the relevant year.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the Hill-Burton Project Register and the United States County and City Data Book Consolidated File.
Figure A.3: Cumulative Hill-Burton Funding per 1,000, 1950 and 1960
Notes: Hill-Burton provided funds are defined as total cumulative Hill-Burton funding each project received through the Hill-Burton program. Because the Hill-Burton Project
Register only provides data on when the project received initial approval from the Public Health Service Regional Offices, we define the year in which the Hill-Burton funds were provided as the year the project was approved. The cumulative amount of Hill-Burton funding received is divided by the
population in county in the relevant year. The cutoffs are defined as the quintiles of those counties that received at least some Hill-Burton funding as of the relevant year.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the Hill-Burton Project Register and the United States County and City Data
Book Consolidated File.
Figure A.4: Cumulative Hill-Burton Beds Provided per 1,000, 1950 and 1960
Notes: Hill-Burton provided beds are defined as the cumulative number of additional beds each project that received Hill-Burton funding provided. Because the Hill-Burton
Project Register only provides data on when the project received initial approval from the Public Health Service Regional Offices, we define the year in which the Hill-Burton beds were provided as the year the project was approved. The number of Hill-Burton beds is divided by the population in
county in the relevant year. The cutoffs are defined as the quintiles of those counties that received at least some Hill-Burton funding as of the relevant year.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the Hill-Burton Project Register and the United States County and City Data Book
Consolidated File.
Figure A.5: Cumulative Hill-Burton Funding Provided per 1,000, 1950 and 1960
Notes: Hill-Burton provided funds are defined as total cumulative Hill-Burton funding each project received through the Hill-Burton program. Because the Hill-Burton
Project Register only provides data on when the project received initial approval from the Public Health Service Regional Offices, we define the year in which the Hill-Burton funds were provided as the year the project was approved. The amount of Hill-Burton funding received is divided by the
population in county in the relevant year. The cutoffs are defined as the quintiles of those counties that received at least some Hill-Burton funding as of the relevant year.
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the Hill-Burton Project Register and City Data Book Consolidated
File.