Figure 1: Increases in House Prices and Rent in Response to an Unanticipated Population Constraint
Figure 1 shows the evolution of prices and rents in response to the population constraint. The x-axis shows the number of years since the shock, while the y-axis shows the cumulative percentage change since year zero. Initially, rent (the red dashed line) is unchanged because the population constraint only affects future growth. But prices (the blue solid line) jump by about 4 percent in response to anticipated future rent increases. Over time, prices and rents rise by similar amounts, so that the net increase in prices remains larger. Although the differential between prices and rents becomes a smaller fraction of rent as time goes on, it is still quite substantial after 30 years. Figure 1 shows the evolution of prices and rents in response to the population constraint. The x-axis shows the number of years since the shock, while the y-axis shows the cumulative percentage change since year zero. Initially, rent (the red dashed line) is unchanged because the population constraint only affects future growth. But prices (the blue solid line) jump by about 4 percent in response to anticipated future rent increases. Over time, prices and rents rise by similar amounts, so that the net increase in prices remains larger. Although the differential between prices and rents becomes a smaller fraction of rent as time goes on, it is still quite substantial after 30 years.
Figure 2: Distribution of Housing Unit Density Among Central Parts of Metropolitan Areas
Note. The figure shows the distribution of housing units per square kilometer across metropolitan areas in 1980 and 2016. In each metropolitan area, density is
calculated only among counties that are designated as "central" according to the 2013 OMB delineation. The sample is restricted to metropolitan areas for which not all counties are designated as central.
Figure 2 shows how housing unit density in the central parts of metropolitan areas has changed from 1980 (the blue line) to 2016 (the red line). The x-axis shows the number of units per square kilometer, while the y-axis indicates the density of the distribution. In 1980, about two-thirds of metropolitan areas had an average density of less than 40 units per square kilometer in their central counties, indicated by a large hump in the density to the left of 40. By 2016, only about one-third of metros had an average density this low in their central counties. The hump in the density in 2016 has become smaller in magnitude and shifted to the right, as some cities have become appreciably more dense.
Figure 3: Identification of Low-Demand Areas Based on Growth in Housing Stock and House Value 1980-2016
Note. Housing units include single-family and multifamily units. Median value is expressed relative to the price index for personal consumption
expenditures.
Figure 3 is a scatterplot with the change in log housing units from 1980 to 2016 on the x-axis and the change in log median value from 1980 to 2016 on the y-axis. We calculate ex-post housing demand in each metro area as the sum of these two values. Metro areas that meet our definition of "low demand" (those in the bottom quartile of the demand distribution) are marked in blue and show up in the lower left quadrant, while those that do not meet that definition are marked in red.
Figure 4
Note. The chart shows the estimated effects of a supply constraint on the change in the fraction of people in each decile of the national income distribution from 1980 to 2016. Regressions control for the variables listed in Appendix
Table 2. Regressions are weighted using the average number of housing units in 1980 and 2016.
Figure 4: Effect of Regulatory Constraints on the Fraction of People in Each Income Decile (Panel A) and Effect of Geographic Constraints on the Fraction of People in Each Income Decile (Panel B) Figure 4 shows the estimated effects of each supply constraint on the change in the fraction of people in each decile of the national income distribution from 1980 to 2016. Panel A shows that regulatory constraints have led to a somewhat larger shares of individuals in the top two deciles and a smaller share of individuals in the middle of the income distribution. Panel B shows no clear evidence of income sorting in response to geographic constraints.
Figure 5
Note. The dots show coefficient estimates from regressions using the same specification as shown in Table 7, except that regressions are estimated separately for households in each decile in the national distribution of household
income.
Figure 5: Effect of Supply Constraints on Ln(Real Housing Expenditures) by Decile of Household Income (Panel A) and Effect of Supply Constraints on Housing Expenditure Shares by Decile of Household Income (Panel B) The two panels of figure 5 are each sub-divided to show the effects of regulatory constraints (on the left) and geographic constraints (on the right). The figure indicates that the estimated effects of both constraints on expenditures (panel A) are fairly similar across the income distribution, but are somewhat smaller for the bottom-most deciles. The effects of both constraints on the indicator for having high housing expenditures relative to income (panel B) are more hump-shaped, with the largest effects of in the middle of the income distribution. For households in the top decile and the bottom deciles, supply constraints appear to have no effect on the probability of spending a large fraction of income on housing.
Figure 6: Effect of Demand on House Value, Rent, and Fraction High-Income, by Constraint Quartiles
Note. The squares show the effect of a 1 percent increase in local demand, estimated separately for each quartile of regulation (left-hand panels) and
geographic constraints (right-hand panels). Regressions also control for a linear function of the other supply constraint (i.e., the regression estimated on the lowest quartile of regulatory constraint controls for a linear function of geographic constraints). Price and rent regressions also
control for housing unit characteristics.
Figure 6 contains a matrix of six panels. The left side of the page shows the effects of demand on three outcomes (house value, rent, and fraction high-income), split by quartiles of regulatory constraints within each panel. The right side of the page shows the effects of demand on the same three outcomes, split by quartiles of geographic constraints within each panel. As expected, demand appears to have larger effects on house prices in metros with tighter supply constraints, although the gradient is more clear for regulation than for geographic constraints (the top panels). By contrast, effects on rent are more similar across quartiles for both constraints (the middle panels). Turning to sorting by income (the bottom panels), it again appears that there is a positive gradient for regulation but not for geographic constraints.