Abstract:
Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (TIPS) are fixed-income securities whose semiannual coupons and principal payments are indexed to the non-seasonally-adjusted consumption price index for all urban consumers.1 Since its inception in 1997, the market for TIPS has grown substantially and now comprises about 8% of the outstanding Treasury debt market. More than fifteen years of TIPS data provides a rich source of information to market participants and academic researchers alike. From a portfolio management perspective, TIPS provide a stream of known "real" payments at horizons up to 30 years and are therefore highly attractive to long-term investors such as retirement savings accounts who would like to hedge themselves against inflation risks. In addition, TIPS prices frequently moved in opposite directions of stock prices in recent years and can be used to hedge against equity price variations.2 More broadly, TIPS yields can be viewed as rough measures of real risk-free interest rates, which are an important determinant of the costs for financing private investment projects and public debt and also provide a better gauge of the stance of monetary policy than nominal interest rates. Information about real yields also has direct implications for asset pricing models, many of which are written in terms of real consumption. Finally, the differential between yields on nominal Treasury securities and on TIPS of comparable maturities, also called the "breakeven inflation rate" (BEI) or "inflation compensation,"is often used as proxy for market participants' inflation expectation, a key variable entering the decisions of firms, investors, and monetary policy makers.
Despite the potential usefulness of such securities, this paper presents evidence that it is essential to take into account the lower liquidity of TIPS relative to their nominal counterparts when using them to measure real interest rates and inflation expectations. In particular, TIPS investors demand premiums for holding these less liquid securities, therefore pushing up TIPS yields above the true real yields and pushing down TIPS BEI below its fundamental levels. Treating the TIPS BEI as a clean proxy for inflation expectation can be especially problematic, since an economically significant TIPS liquidity premium combined with a positive inflation risk premium could potentially drive a large wedge between the TIPS BEI and true inflation expectations. We show that the early years of the TIPS market and the recent financial crisis provide two examples when poor liquidity significantly distorted the information content of TIPS prices.
To demonstrate the existence of TIPS liquidity premiums, we model nominal Treasury yields, TIPS yields, and inflation jointly in a no-arbitrage asset pricing framework. We examine several different specifications for such models, where the nominal Treasury-TIPS liquidity differential is either ignored or modeled as an additional stochastic factor that influences TIPS but not nominal Treasury yields. All models we use are from the Gaussian essentially-affine no-arbitrage term structure family and allow flexible specifications for both real and nominal market prices of risk. This approach differs significantly from that of the other two studies of TIPS liquidities in the literature, Shen (2006) and Pflueger and Viceira (2013), who based their results on regression analysis of either TIPS BEI itself or the difference between TIPS BEI and survey-based measures of inflation expectations. The usage of a pricing model allows us to bring in additional information from the cross section of yields and TIPS BEI and realized inflation to better distinguish between the liquidity and the inflation risk premium components of TIPS BEI. Moreover, the Gaussian bond pricing framework used here allows for a flexible correlation structure between the factors, which is important for identifying risk premiums, which arise from correlations between pricing kernels and asset returns. This framework therefore allows an accurate decomposition of the TIPS BEI into expected inflation, the inflation risk premium, and the TIPS liquidity premium.
Our main findings can be summarized as follows. First, a standard 3-factor model that assumes no TIPS liquidity premium generates not only large pricing errors for TIPS yields but also estimates of inflation expectations that differ significantly from survey inflation forecasts and estimates of
inflation risk premiums that carry a counterintuitive negative sign. In comparison, the two 4-factor models allowing TIPS yields to differ from the true real yields by a liquidity spread generate notably smaller TIPS pricing errors, more reasonable estimates of inflation risk premiums, and
estimated inflation expectations that agree well with survey inflation forecasts. Second, the liquidity premium estimates from both 4-factor models share the feature that they were large (
1%) in the early years, declined steadily until late 2003, and remained at relatively low levels until the recent crisis, consistent with the notion that TIPS market liquidity conditions had been improving over time. Those estimates jumped to well above 3% in July 2008 during the TIPS sell-off but
had largely returned to their pre-crisis levels by the beginning of 2010, a pattern similar to what has been found for many other markets. Third, regression analysis shows that around 77-86% of the variations in our estimates of TIPS liquidity premiums can be explained by observable measures of the
liquidity conditions in the TIPS market. Finally, when applied to the UK data, one variant of our model reveals liquidity premiums in index-linked gilt yields that were fairly low in normal times but spiked to about 250 basis points at the height of the recent crisis.
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to model the TIPS liquidity premium in a no-arbitrage framework and as such is related to the fast-growing literature on the link between liquidity and asset returns.3 Previous studies have documented that assets with similar payoffs can carry significantly different prices due to their liquidity differences.4 This paper adds to the evidence by showing that although nominal Treasury securities and TIPS are both issued by the U.S. Treasury and perceived as largely free of credit risks, they are priced differently due to their distinct liquidities after controlling for the differences in their real payoffs. Our paper is also related to studies of the pricing of indexed bonds, most of which are applied to countries with longer histories for such bonds than the U.S.,5 while studies using TIPS and other U.S. inflation-linked assets are fairly recent and relatively few.6 Most of the studies using TIPS yields take them at their face value and as a result typically produce real yield estimates that seem too high and inflation risk premium estimates that are insignificant or negative in the few years following the introduction of TIPS. In contrast, this paper shows that there is a persistent liquidity premium component in TIPS prices that, when ignored, will significantly bias the results. Finally, this paper is also related to the vast literature studying the behavior of real interest rates, inflation expectations, and inflation risk premiums but without incorporating information from indexed bonds.7
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we provide evidence that TIPS yields and TIPS breakeven inflation contain an additional factor, likely reflecting the relative illiquidity of TIPS, beyond those driving the nominal interest rates. Section 3 spells out the details of the no-arbitrage models we use, including the specification of the additional liquidity factor. Section 4 describes the data and our empirical methodology, and Section 5 presents the main empirical results. Section 6 provides further discussions on the model estimates of the TIPS liquidity premiums, showing that those estimates are indeed linked to the liquidity conditions in the TIPS markets and that they account for a significant portion of the time series variations in TIPS BEI. Section 7 applies the model to the U.K. data. Finally, Section 8 concludes.
In this section we present evidence that there is a component of TIPS yields that is not reflected in nominal Treasury yields but is related to the liquidity of the TIPS market. This serves as the motivation for introducing a TIPS-specific factor when we model nominal and TIPS yields jointly in later sections.
Simple Regression Analysis
In the first analysis, we regress the 10-year TIPS BEI, defined as the spread between the 10-year nominal yield and the 10-year TIPS yield, on 3-month, 2-year and 10-year nominal yields as well as a constant:8
Regression (1) is estimated both in levels and in weekly differences using three samples. The first sample corresponds to the full sample period of January 6, 1999 to March 27, 2013, which is then split into two sub-samples: the pre-crisis period from January 6, 1999
to December 31, 2007, and the post-crisis period from January 2, 2008 to March 27, 2013. The results are reported in the left columns in Panel A of Table 1. The from the full-sample regression is merely
in levels and
in weekly differences, well below the levels of
in excess of
typically reported when regressing one nominal yield onto other nominal yields. In the pre-crisis period, the
is higher for both specifications,
in levels and
in differences, indicating that the very low
is mostly due to the post-crisis period, during which it declines to
and
in levels and differences, respectively. This evidence suggests that a large portion of variations in the 10-year BEI cannot be explained by factors driving the nominal yields, and even more so when
the most recent financial crisis is included in the sample.
Principal Components Analysis
Next, we conduct a principal component analysis (PCA) of the cross section of nominal and TIPS yields over the full sample. It is well known that, in the case of nominal yields, three factors explain most of the nominal yield curve movements. This is confirmed by looking at the left panels in Table 1, Panel B: Over 97% of variations in the weekly changes of nominal yields can be explained by the first three principal components; once we add TIPS yields, at least four factors are needed to explain the same portion of the total variance. The left columns in Panel C of Table 1 report the correlations between the first four PCA factors extracted from nominal yields alone and those from nominal and TIPS yields jointly. It is interesting to note that, the first, second, and fourth factors constructed from all yields largely retain their interpretations as the level, slope and curvature of the nominal yield curve, as can be seen from their high correlations with the first, the second and the third nominal factors, respectively. However, the third PCA factor extracted from nominal and TIPS yields combined is not highly correlated with any of the nominal PCA factors.
A Case for TIPS Liquidity Premium
One interpretation of the TIPS-specific factor we mentioned above is that it reflects a "liquidity premium": investors would demand a compensation for holding a relative new and illiquid instrument like TIPS, either in the early years or during episodes like the most recent financial crisis.
Indeed, several measures related to TIPS market liquidity conditions, as well as anecdotal reports, indicate that the liquidity in TIPS market was much poorer than that of nominal securities, and that TIPS market liquidity improved over time, although this improvement was not a smooth, steady process. The top panel of Figure 1 shows the gross TIPS issuance over the period 1997-2013. The TIPS issuance dipped slightly in 2000-2001 before rising substantially in 2004. According to Sack and Elsasser (2004), there were talks around 2001 that the Treasury might discontinue the TIPS due to the relatively weak demand for TIPS. TIPS outstanding, shown in the bottom panel of Figure 1, began to grow at a faster pace from 2004 onward and now exceeds 800 billion dollars. Figure 2 tells a similar story from the demand side: TIPS transaction volumes grew almost tenfold between 1999 and 2004, and TIPS mutual funds also experienced significant growth.9 . Transaction volumes declined sharply at the end of 2008 and remained at a lower level until 2010. In view of this institutional history, it is not unreasonable to suppose that TIPS contained a significant liquidity premium in its early years and again during the financial crisis.
A liquidity premium in TIPS can also help resolve an apparent inconsistency between long-term survey inflation forecasts--proxied by the 10-year inflation forecasts from the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) and the long-term inflation forecast from the Thompson Reuters/Michigan Survey of Consumers--and the 10-year TIPS BEI, all of which are plotted in Figure 3.10 Recall that the true BEI, defined as the yield differential between nominal and real bonds of comparable maturities, is the sum of expected inflation and the inflation risk premium, therefore would tend to be higher than inflation expectations from surveys, and can be considered as a good measure of true expected inflation if the inflation risk premium is relatively small and does not vary too much over time. However, Figure 3 shows that this is not the case: the TIPS BEI lied below both measures of survey inflation forecasts almost all the time before 2004.11 12 In addition, TIPS yields surged shortly after Lehman failed while conventional nominal yields plummeted, pushing 10-year TIPS BEI close to zero at the end of 2008, while survey inflation expectations were practically unchanged over the same period. Such disparities cannot be attributed solely to the existence of inflation risk premium, as such an explanation would require the inflation risk premium to be mostly negative during these two episodes and highly volatile, which stands in contrast with most studies in the literature that find inflation risk premiums to be positive on average and relatively smooth.13
A positive TIPS liquidity premium, on the other hand, would push the TIPS-based BEI below the true BEI and potentially even below survey inflation forecasts, if the TIPS liquidity premium exceeds the inflation risk premium. Part of the volatility of the TIPS BEI may also be due to the volatility of the TIPS liquidity premium. In order to study these issues quantitatively, we need a framework for identifying and measuring the relevant components, including the TIPS liquidity premium, inflation expectations, and inflation risk premium. For this purpose, we use the no-arbitrage term structure modeling framework, to which we now turn.
This section details the no-arbitrage framework that we use to model nominal and TIPS yields and inflation jointly. The no-arbitrage approach has the benefit of avoiding the tight assumptions that go into structural, utility-based models, while still allowing term structure variations to be modeled in a dynamically consistent manner by requiring the cross section of yields to satisfy the no-arbitrage restrictions.
We assume that real yields, expected inflation, and nominal yields are all driven by a vector of three latent variables,
, that follows a multivariate Gaussian process,
The nominal short rate is specified as
The nominal pricing kernel takes the form
The price level processes takes the form:
A real bond can be thought of as a nominal asset paying realized inflation upon maturity. Therefore, the real and the nominal pricing kernels are linked by the no-arbitrage relation
![]() |
![]() |
(C-10) |
![]() |
(C-11) |
![]() |
(C-12) |
![]() |
(C-13) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-14) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-15) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-16) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-17) |
By the definition of nominal and real pricing kernels, the time- prices of
-period nominal and real bonds,
and
, are given by
![]() |
(C-18) |
Following the standard literature,14 it is straightforward to derive a closed-form solution for the bond prices:
![]() |
(C-20) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-21) |
![]() |
![]() |
(C-22) |
Nominal and real yields therefore both take the affine form,
In this model, inflation expectations also take an affine form,
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() |
From equations (23)-(25), it can be seen that both the BEI, defined as the difference between zero coupon nominal and real yields of identical maturities, and the inflation risk premium, defined as the difference between the BEI and the expected log inflation over the same horizon, are affine in the state variables:
Using Equation (9) we can write the price of a -period nominal bond as
![]() |
(C-29) |
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() |
Given the evidence presented in Section 2 on the existence of a TIPS-specific factor, we allow the TIPS yield to deviate from the true underlying real yield. The spread between the TIPS yield and the true real yield,
To model
, we assume that the investors discount TIPS cash flows by adjusting the true instantaneous real short rate with a positive liquidity spread, resulting in a TIPS yield that exceeds
the true real yield by
The instantaneous liquidity spread is given by
![]() |
(C-34) |
Appendix A shows that the TIPS liquidity premium takes the affine form
The TIPS yields in our model is given by
Besides its tractability, the affine-Gaussian bond pricing framework used here allows for a flexible correlation structure between the factors. As the inflation risk premium arises from the correlation between the real pricing kernel and inflation, it is important to allow for a general correlation structure. On the other hand, the affine-Gaussian setup does not capture the time-varying inflation uncertainty and therefore cannot further decompose inflation risk premiums into the part due to time-varying inflation risks and time-varying prices of inflation risk. Nonetheless, the affine-Gaussian model could still provide reasonable estimates of the inflation risk premium, similar to the way it generates reasonable measures of term premia despite its inability to capture time-varying interest rate volatilities. We view the general affine-Gaussian model as an important benchmark to investigate before exploring more sophisticated models.
Some of the models studied in the earlier literature, such as Pennacchi (1991) and Campbell and Viceira (2001), can be viewed as special cases of this model. For example, Pennacchi (1991)'s model corresponds to a two-factor version of our model with constant market price of risk. Campbell and Viceira (2001) is also a special case of this model, as their real term structure has a lower dimension than the nominal term structure, with nominal yields described by two factors and real yields described by one. In this paper, we let the data decide whether the real term structure should have the same dimensionality as the nominal term structure or a lower one. A related point is that in a reduced-form setup like ours, one cannot classify factors into real and nominal ones, as the correlation effects in the model make such a distinction meaningless.
Overall, compared with previous studies, two main features of this model help us better distinguish the inflation risk premium and the liquidity premium components of the TIPS BEI. On the one hand, the use of price level data in the estimation and the unrestricted correlation structure between factor innovations help us better pin down expected inflation and the inflation risk premium. On the other hand, the higher-dimensionality of the real term structure, the estimation of
which is assisted by the additional information from TIPS yields, allows us to better identify the parameters governing the "true" real yields dynamic. As a result, the wedge between TIPS and true real yields, our measure of liquidity premium, is pinned down, and can be estimated separately from
the inflation risk premium. These features cannot be fully appreciated unless considered within the context of the empirical methodology used to estimate the model, which is described in the next section.
We use 3- and 6-month, 1-, 2-, 4-, 7-, and 10-year nominal yields and CPI-U data from January 1990 to March 2013. In contrast, our TIPS yields are restricted by data availability and cover a shorter period from January 1999 to March 2013, with the earlier period without TIPS data (1990-1998) treated as missing observations.18 We sample yields at the weekly frequency and assume that the monthly CPI-U data is observed on the last Wednesday of the current month.19 As discussed in the internet appendix, shorter-maturity TIPS yields are affected to a larger degree by the problem of indexation lags. They also cannot be estimated reliably before 2002, as only one TIPS with maturities below 5 years existed over that period. We therefore only use 5-, 7-, and 10-year TIPS yields in our estimation. All nominal and TIPS yields used in the estimation are plotted in Figure 4. TIPS are indexed to non-seasonally-adjusted CPI; however,because the models we estimate do not accommodate seasonalities, we use seasonally-adjusted CPI inflation in the estimation. This is not expected to have a big effect due to the relatively long maturities of TIPS yields that we examine.
The sample period 1990-2013 was chosen as a compromise between having more data in order to improve the efficiency of estimation, and having a more homogeneous sample so as to avoid possible structural breaks20 in the relation between term structure variables and inflation. This sample period roughly spans Greenspan's tenure and most of Bernanke's as well.
Results from Kim and Orphanides (2012) suggest that the standard technique of estimating our models using only nominal and TIPS yields and inflation data for a relative short sample period of 1990-2013 will almost surely run into small sample problems:
variables like
and
may not be reliably estimated, and the model-implied path of expected future short rate over the next 5 to 10 years is typically too smooth compared to survey-based measures of
interest rates expectations. Therefore, we supplement the aforementioned data with survey forecasts of 3-month T-bill yields to help stabilize the estimation and to better pin down some of the model parameters. Note that survey inflation forecast data are not used in the estimation, as we would like to use survey inflation forecasts as a means for model testing.
To be specific, we use the 6- and 12-month-ahead forecasts of the 3-month T-bill yield from Blue Chip Financial Forecasts, which are available monthly, and allow the size of the measurement errors to be determined within the estimation. We also use long-range forecast of 3-month T-bill yield over the next 5 to 10 years from the same survey, which are available twice a year, with the standard deviation of its measurement error fixed at a fairly large value of 75 basis points at an annual rate. This is done to prevent the long-horizon survey forecasts from having unduly strong influence on the estimation, and can be viewed as similar to a quasi-informative prior in a Bayesian estimation.
We denote the short-horizon survey forecasts by and
and the
long-range forecast by
. The standard deviation of their measurement errors are denoted denoted
and
, respectively. These survey-based forecasts are taken as noisy measures of the corresponding true market expectations. More specifically, we assume that the short-term
survey forecasts take the form of
![]() |
(D-38) |
![]() |
(D-39) |
![]() |
(D-40) |
![]() |
![]() |
(D-41) |
![]() |
![]() |
(D-42) |
We only impose restrictions that are necessary for achieving identification so as to allow a maximally flexible correlation structure between the factors, which has shown to be critical in fitting the rich behavior in risk premiums that we observe in the data.21 In particular, we employ the following normalization:
To summarize, we estimate three models that differ in how TIPS liquidity premium is modeled, including one model that equates TIPS yields with true real yields and assumes zero liquidity premium on TIPS (Model NL), a model with an independent liquidity factor (Model L-I), and a model allowing the TIPS liquidity premium to be correlated with other state variables (Model L-II). Table 2 summarizes the models and the parameter restrictions. Two things are worth noting here: First, as shown in Section 3.5, Models NL and L-I can all both considered as special cases of Model L-II. Second, Model NL has a 3-factor representation of TIPS yields, while in the other two models TIPS yields have a 4-factor specification.
We rewrite the model in a state-space form and estimate it by the Kalman filter. Denote by
the augmented state vector including the log price level,
, and the TIPS liquidity factor,
. The state equation is derived as Euler discretization of equations (3), (7), and (33) and can be
written in a matrix form as
![]() |
(D-45) |
We specify the set of nominal yields as
, and the set of TIPS yields as
, and collect in
all data used in the estimation, including the log price level
, all nominal yields
, all TIPS yields
, and 6 month-ahead, 12 month-ahead, and long-horizon forecasts of future 3-month nominal yield:
![]() |
(D-46) |
We assume that all nominal and TIPS yields and survey forecasts of nominal short rate are observed with error. The observation equation therefore takes the form
![]() |
(D-48) |
Based on the state equation (44) and the observation equation (47), it is straightforward to implement the Kalman-filter and perform the maximum likelihood estimation. The details are given in Appendix B. Two aspects
are worth noting here: first, the log price level is nonstationary, so we use a diffuse prior for
when initializing the Kalman filter. Second, inflation, survey forecasts, and TIPS yields are not available for all dates, which introduces missing data in the observation equation and are handled in the standard way by allowing the dimensions of the matrices
and
in Equation (47) to be time-dependent (see, for
example, Harvey (1989, sec. 3.4.7)).
To facilitate the estimation and also to make the results easily replicable, we follow the following steps in estimating all our models:
In this Section, we discuss and compare the empirical performance of the various Models. As we shall see, there are notable differences between the model equating TIPS yields with the true real yields (Model NL) and the models that allow the two sets of yields to differ by a liquidity premium component (Models L-I and L-II).
Parameter Estimates
Table 3 reports selected parameter estimates for all three models.23 Four things are worth noting here: First, estimates of parameters governing the nominal term structure seem to be fairly robustly estimated and are almost identical across all models. In particular, all estimations uncover a factor that is fairly persistent with a half life of about 5 years. All three models also exhibit a similar fit to nominal yields and survey forecasts of nominal short-term interest rates, generating fitting errors in the order of 6 basis points or less for most maturities and slightly larger at around 13 basis points for the 3-month yield.
Second, there are notable differences in the estimates of parameters governing the expected inflation process. In particular, the loading of the instantaneous inflation on the second and the most persistent factor,
, is negligible in the model without a TIPS liquidity factor (Model NL) but becomes positive and more significant in the two models with a TIPS liquidity factor (Models L-I
and L-II). As a result, the monthly autocorrelation of one-year-ahead inflation expectation is about 0.9 in Model NL but above 0.99 in all other models. As we will see later, the lack of persistence in the inflation expectation process prevents Model NL from generating meaningful variations in
longer-term inflation expectations as we observe in the data.
Third, parameter estimates for the TIPS liquidity factor process are significant in both Models L-I and L-II and assume similar values. The price of liquidity risk depends negatively on the liquidity factor, as can been from the negative
, implying that the same amount of liquidity risk carries higher risk premiums when liquidity is poor. This is intuitive as one would generally expect any deterioration of
liquidity conditions to occur during bad economic times. In Model L-II, the loading of the instantaneous TIPS liquidity premium on each of the three state variables,
, is estimated to
be indistinguishable from zero; however, a likelihood ratio test shows that they are jointly significant.
Finally, the fit to TIPS yields is significantly better in models with a TIPS liquidity factor. For example, the fitting errors on the 10-year TIPS yield is around 40 basis points in Model NL but are much smaller at around 7 basis points in Models L-I and L-II. The fitting errors are found to have substantial serial correlations. For example, in the case of the 5-year TIPS, we obtain a weekly AR(1) coefficient of 0.96, 0.75, and 0.75 for Models NL, L-I, and L-II, respectively. The finding of serial correlation in term structure fitting errors are however a fairly common phenomenon, and have been noted by Chen and Scott (1993) and others.
Panel A of Table 4 reports some test statistics that compare the overall fit of the three models. We first report two information criteria commonly used for model selection, the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC). Both information criteria are minimized by the most general model, Model L-II.
We also report results from likelihood ratio (LR) tests of the two restricted models, Models NL and L-I, against their more general counterparts, Model L-I and L-II, respectively. Compared to Model L-I, Model NL imposes the restriction
. The standard likelihood ratio test does not apply here because the nuisance parameters,
,
,
and
, are not identified under the null (Model NL) and appear only under the alternative (Model L-I).24 Here we follow Garcia and Perron (1996) and calculate a conservative upper bound for the significance of the likelihood ratio test statistic as suggested by Davies
(1987), the details of which is outlined in Appendix C. Apply this procedure to testing the null of Model NL against the alternative of Model L-I gives an estimate of the maximal p value of essentially zero, hence Model NL is overwhelmingly rejected in favor of Model
L-I. With the LR statistic estimated as
with 1 degree of freedom, we feel confident that using alternative econometric procedures to deal with the nuisance parameter
problem is unlikely to overturn the rejection.
The LR test of Model L-I against Model L-II, on the other hand, is fairly standard. Based on the likelihood estimates of the two models, we obtain a LR statistic of
The estimated standard deviations of TIPS measurement errors reported in Table 3 suggest that Model NL has trouble fitting the TIPS yields. A better understanding of the problem can be seen by comparing the top panels from Figures 5 and 6, which plot the actual and model-implied TIPS yields and TIPS BEI as well as the model-implied true real yields and true BEI for Models NL and L-II, respectively.25 By construction, the model-implied TIPS yields (TIPS BEI) and the model-implied real yields (BEI) coincide under Model NL.
The top left panel of Figures 5 shows that Model NL attributes the decline in 10-year TIPS yields from 1999 to 2004 to a broad downward shift in real yields since the early 1990's, with real yields estimated to have come down from a level as high as in the early 90's to about
around 2003. Over the same period, the 10-year nominal
yield declined by less than 5% from around
to a little over
, which Model
NL attributes almost entirely to a lower real yield, leaving little room for lower inflation expectation or lower inflation risk premiums. However, the literature generally finds that long-term inflation expectations likely have edged down during this period,26 and it is hard to imagine economic mechanisms that would generate such a large decline in long-term real yields. Furthermore, although Model NL matches the general trend of TIPS yields
during this period, it has problem fitting the time variations, frequently resulting in large fitting errors, especially in the early part of the sample and again during the recent financial crisis. In contrast, the top left panel of Figure 6 shows a less pronounced and more
gradual decline in real yields based on Model L-II, and the model is able to fit TIPS yields almost perfectly, as shown by the juxtaposition of the red and black lines.
In addition, the top right panel of Figure 5 shows that the 10-year BEI implied by Model NL, which by construction should equal the 10-year TIPS BEI, appears too smooth compared to the actual data and misses most of its short-run variations. The poor fitting of the TIPS BEI highlights the difficulty that the 3-factor model has in fitting nominal and TIPS yields simultaneously. In contrast, the 10-year BEI implied by Models L-II, shown in the top right panel of Figure 6, exhibits substantial variations that closely match those of the actual TIPS BEI. In particular, the model-implied and the TIPS-based BEI plunge toward the end of 2008 following the Lehman collapse, consistent with reports of substantial liquidation of TIPS holdings over this period.27
To quantify the improvement in terms of the model fit, Panels B and C of Table 4 provide three goodness-of-fit statistics for TIPS yields at the 5-, 7- and 10-year maturities and TIPS BEI at the 7- and 10-year maturities, respectively. The first statistic, CORR, is
the simple sample correlation between the fitted series and its data counterpart. The next two statistics are based on one-step-ahead model prediction errors from the Kalman Filter, , defined in Equation (B-14) in Appendix B, and are designed to capture how well each model can explain the data without resorting to large exogenous shocks or measurement errors. In particular, the second statistic is
the root mean squared prediction errors (RMSE), and the third statistic is the coefficient of determination (
), defined as the percentage of in-sample variations of each data series
explained by the model:
All three statistics suggest that allowing a TIPS liquidity premium component improves the model fit for raw TIPS yields and even more so for TIPS BEI. For example, the correlation between model-implied and actual 10-year TIPS breakevens rises from to over
once we move from Model NL to the other models. Although Model NL generates a respectable sample correlation
for TIPS yields of around 93%, the seemingly reasonable fit is only achieved by assuming large exogenous shocks to the state variables, as can be seen from the larger RMSEs and lower
s
compared with the other two models. The fit of Model NL for TIPS BEI is even worse, with a
of
at the 10-year maturity, compared to
s of more than
at both maturities.
It is conceivable that a model with more parameters like Model L-II could generate smaller in-sample fitting errors for variables whose fit is explicitly optimized but produce undesirable implications for variables not used in the estimation. To check this possibility, we examine how closely the model-implied inflation expectations mimic survey-based inflation forecasts, which are not used in our estimation. Ang, Bekaert, and Wei (2007) provide recent evidence that survey inflation forecasts outperforms various other measures of inflation expectations in predicting future inflation. In addition, survey inflation forecast has the benefit of being a real-time, model-free measure, and hence not subject to model estimation errors or look-ahead biases that could affect measures based on in-sample fitting of realized inflation.29
Panel D of Table 4 reports the three goodness-of-fit statistics, CORR, RMSE and , for 1- and 10-year ahead inflation forecasts from the SPF. Neither
Model NL nor Model L-I generates inflation expectations that agree well with survey inflation forecasts, as can be seen from the large RMSEs and small and even negative
statistics. In
contrast, Model L-II implies inflation expectations that are more than
correlated with their survey counterparts, generates smaller RMSEs at both horizons, and is able to explain a
large amount of sample variations in survey inflation forecasts.
A visual comparison of the model-implied inflation expectations and survey forecasts help shed more light on those results. The middle panels of Figure 5, which plot Model NL-implied 1- and 10-year inflation expectation together with the survey forecasts, suggest that Model NL fails to capture the downward trend in survey inflation forecasts during much of the sample period, especially at the 10-year horizon, and implies a 10-year inflation expectations that moved little over the sample period. This is the flip side of the discussions in Section 5.2, where we see a Model-NL-implied 10-year real rate that is too variable and is used by the model to explain the entire decline in nominal yields during the 1990s. Overall, the near-constancy of the long-term inflation expectation is the most problematic feature of Model NL. In contrast, as can be seen from the middle panels of Figure 6, Model L-II produces 1- and 10-year inflation expectations that show a more visible downward trend, consistent with the survey evidence. In the internet appendix, we show that Model L-I generates inflation expectations that match the downward trend of the survey forecasts but are much more volatile, which explains its poor fit to survey inflation forecasts as seen in Panel D of Table 4.
Finally, the bottom left panels of Figures 5 and 6 plot model-implied 1- and 10-year inflation risk premiums implied by Models NL and L-II, respectively. One immediately notable feature is that Model NL implies an inflation risk premium that is negative and increasing over time in the 1990-2013 period. In contrast, most existing studies find positive inflation risk premiums on average, as noted in Section 2. Furthermore, studies such as Clarida and Friedman (1984) indicate that the inflation risk premium likely was positive and substantial in the early 1980s and probably has come down since then. Indeed, the two models that allow for a liquidity premium, Models L-I and L-II, both generate 10-year inflation risk premiums that are mostly positive and fluctuate in the 0 to 0.5% range over the same sample period. The short-term inflation risk premiums implied by these two models, on the other hand, are fairly small, consistent with our intuition.
In summary, we find that Model NL, which equates TIPS yields with true underlying real yields, fares poorly along a number of dimensions, including generating a poor fit with TIPS yields and BEI, as well as inflation expectations and inflation risk premiums with counterintuitive properties. In contrast, models that allow for TIPS liquidity premiums show improvements along those dimensions. In particular, Model L-II produces short- and long-term inflation expectations that agree quite well with survey forecasts, suggesting it is important to allow for a systematic component in TIPS liquidity premiums. In the remainder of our analysis we'll be mainly focusing on this model.
The TIPS liquidity premiums implied by Model L-II are plotted in the bottom right panels of Figure 6 for maturities of 5, 7 and 10 years. Three things are worth noting from this graph: First, liquidity premiums exhibit substantial time variations at all maturities. The
substantial variability at maturities as long as 10 years is in part due to the fact that the independent liquidity factor is estimated to be quite persistent under the risk-neutral measure. As can be seen from Table 3, the risk-neutral persistence of the liquidity factor,
, is estimated to be very small at around 0.1 in all models and is tightly estimated, with a standard error of about
0.006. In contrast, the persistence parameter under the physical measure,
, is not as precisely estimated, with its value and the associated standard error both estimated to be around 0.2.
Second, the term structure of implied TIPS liquidity premiums is downward sloping during the 2001-2004 and 2008-2011 periods. Technically, a market price of risk on the independent liquidity factor that is on average positive, as is the case here, would contribute to a downward-sloping term structure of TIPS liquidity premium.30 This is in contrast to the standard one-factor interest rate models, where the market price of interest rate risk is typically found to be negative leading to an upward-sloping term structure of the term premium.
Finally, TIPS liquidity premiums were fairly high (1.5-2% range) when TIPS were first introduced but had been steadily declining until around 2004, likely reflecting the maturing process of a relatively new financial instrument. Liquidity premiums surged to record-high levels ( 3.5%) after the Lehman bankruptcy, reflecting a sharp increase in transaction and funding costs of TIPS as well as heightened aversion towards liquidity risks.31 The large flight-to-safety flows into the nominal Treasury market likely also contributed to the larger liquidity differential between nominal Treasuries and TIPS that led to a higher
liquidity discount in TIPS relative to its nominal counterpart. Similarly sharp rise in liquidity premium and/or illiquidity measures were seen in other key markets during the recent financial crisis, including equity and corporate bond markets.32 Outside those two periods, TIPS liquidity premiums appear low and stationary, fluctuating between -50 and 50 basis points.
The behavior of the liquidity premiums seen in Figure 6 and described above seems broadly consistent with the perception that TIPS market liquidity conditions had improved over time till the inception of the recent financial crisis. However, given the unobserved nature of the liquidity factor in our model, one may question whether it is indeed capturing TIPS liquidity rather than other aspects of TIPS yields that are orthogonal to nominal Treasury yields. In this section, we verify the validity of our liquidity premium estimates by linking them to various observable measures of TIPS liquidity. One immediate difficulty we face is the lack of precise, real-time measures of liquidity conditions in the TIPS market. For example, as shown in the top left panel of Figure 7, one widely used measure of illiquidity, the bid-ask spread, only became available for TIPS in 2003 from TradeWeb. A TIPS liquidity measure that is available over a longer sample is the relative trading volumes of TIPS versus nominal coupon Treasury securities.33 As can be seen from the top right panel of Figure 7, the trading volumes in TIPS remained low compared to nominal Treasury coupon securities up to mid 2004 and then rose substantially, suggesting steady improvement in TIPS liquidity during the pre-crisis sample period.34 The rise coincides roughly with the decline in our TIPS liquidity premium estimates over the same period, whose correlations with the TIPS relative trading volumes are about -80% over the period of January 1999 to December 2007.
Another observable measure of TIPS liquidity used in the literature is the average absolute fitting errors from the Svensson TIPS yield curve, plotted in the middle left panel of Figure 7. The logic behind this measure derives from funding constraints and limits to arbitrage that prevent investors from eliminating the deviations of yields from their fundamental values as measured from the fitted yield curve. Similar measures have been used by Fontaine and Garcia (2012) and Hu, Pan, and Wang (2012) to measure the liquidity of nominal Treasury securities, and by Grishchenko and Huang (2013) for TIPS. It is plausible that during a financial crisis, capital becomes more scarce and risk aversion run higher, leaving significant arbitrage opportunities unexploited. According to this measure, liquidity conditions in the TIPS market were fine until the inception of the financial crisis, when they suddenly deteriorated.
All three measures mentioned so far capture current liquidity conditions in the TIPS market but not expected future liquidity conditions or the risk premiums investors place on bearing such liquidity risks. They also capture the absolute level of (il)liquidity of TIPS rather than the relative liquidity against that of nominal Treasury securities. To capture those additional components, we also examine two closely-related measures based on asset prices. The first such measure is the difference between TIPS and off-the-run nominal asset swap (ASW) spreads obtained from Barclays.35 ASW spreads vary over time and across securities according to the perceived default and liquidity risk of the underlying securities. Because both nominal Treasury and TIPS are usually considered free of default risks, their ASW spreads can be regarded as a good market-based measure of the liquidity premiums in those assets. Consistent with their relative liquidity, we usually observe that ASW spreads became increasingly more negative as we move across asset classes from TIPS to off-the-run nominal Treasuries and then to on-the-run nominal Treasuries. The difference between TIPS and nominal Treasury ASW spreads would therefore be an ideal measure of the relative illiquidity of TIPS.36 Unfortunately TIPS ASWs only started trading in 2006; we therefore use the difference between the off-the-run and the on-the-run 10-year nominal Treasury ASW spreads from JP Morgan as an approximation when studying the full-sample. The correlation between the two measures of ASW spread differences is 0.93 since 2006 when both are available. As can be seen from the middle right and the bottom left panels of Figure 7, both measures spiked during the crisis, reflecting general funding pressures leading to a dramatic widening between prices of securities with only small liquidity differentials.
The second forward-looking measure of TIPS liquidity premiums is the difference between inflation swaps and TIPS BEI, available since late 2004 and plotted in the bottom right panel of of Figure 7.37 As noted by Campbell, Shiller, and Viceira (2009), in theory this measure is linked to the difference between the TIPS and nominal ASW spreads through a no-arbitrage relationship; empirically, the two measures have a high correlation of 88% in the post-2006 sample when both are available, although the swap-BEI difference exhibits a smaller spike during the recent crisis and also an earlier return to its normal levels afterwards.
Panel A of Table 5 reports the pairwise correlations between Model L-II-implied TIPS liquidity premium estimates and the six observable liquidity measures mentioned above. As expected, model liquidity premium estimates are negatively correlated with the relative transaction volumes and positively correlated with all other liquidity measures. The magnitude of the correlation is the largest for the ASW spread-based measures and the swap-BEI difference, suggesting a large part of the variations in model liquidity premium are related to future liquidity risks and liquidity risk premiums. Among the six observable liquidity measures, the three forward-looking measures are highly correlated with each other and with the TIPS bid-ask spread and the TIPS curve fitting errors. The relative TIPS trading volumes are not highly correlated with the other measures and show counterintuitive positive correlations with the bid-ask spread, although those correlations are higher and all with the expected signs during the pre-crisis period, suggesting that trading activities may have become a less important determinant of TIPS liquidity once the TIPS market has matured.
To quantify the effects of these factors on our estimates of TIPS liquidity premiums, we run univariate and multivariate regressions of the 10-year TIPS liquidity premiums from Model L-II on various liquidity measures. Panel B of Table 5 examines the full sample using the three measures that are available over the entire sample period--the relative TIPS-nominal trading volumes, the nominal on- and off-the-run ASW spread difference, and the average TIPS curve fitting errors. The coefficients on the three variables all carry the expected signs and are statistically significant. In general, TIPS liquidity premiums are lower when TIPS transaction volumes rise relative to those of nominal Treasury securities, when nominal on- and off-the-run ASW spreads trade closer to each other, and/or when TIPS yields show smaller deviations from their fundamental values. Together these three variables explain 77% of the variations in 10-year TIPS liquidity premium estimates.
Panel C of Table 5 expands the regressions to include all six liquidity measures over the sample period since September 20, 2006, when all measures became available. Again, most coefficients are of the expected sign and statistically significant, except for the TIPS bid-ask spread and the swaps-BEI difference, which are significant on their own but become insignificant when all TIPS liquidity measures are included. The magnitude of the coefficients on the relative TIPS trading volumes is smaller than those from the full-sample regressions, consistent with the correlation pattern documented above and with the intuition that the "growing pains" of TIPS market is a more important story in the earlier part of the sample. In the univariate regression, the coefficient on the TIPS fitting errors nearly doubled and the regression now explains a much larger portion of liquidity premium variations, reflecting the important role of funding constraints and limits to arbitrage in driving TIPS liquidity during the recent crisis. The same three variables as in Panel B explain a slightly higher percentage (79.1%) of the variations in model liquidity premium estimates, while this percentage rises further to 86.3% when all observable liquidity measures (except the differences between nominal on- and off-the run ASW spreads) are included.
The results from Table 5 confirm that the model-implied liquidity premiums are indeed capturing current and expected future relative liquidity conditions in the TIPS market as well as the associated liquidity risk premiums. We caution, however, that this type of regressions should be viewed only as a rough gauge of the relationship between the observed measures and the liquidity premiums embedded in TIPS yields, as quantities like bid-ask spreads and trading volumes cannot be expected to have a simple linear relationship with the liquidity premium. As a result, we feel that the latent-liquidity-factor approach used in this paper has the advantage of being more flexible than rigidly linking the liquidity premiums to one or more observable measures. Nonetheless, our analysis confirms that the difference between the TIPS and nominal ASW spreads stands out as the most promising real-time, observable measure of TIPS liquidity premiums, at least over the short sample period when it is available.
In this section we assess the economic significance of the TIPS liquidity premiums by examining the proportions of variations in TIPS yields and TIPS BEI that can be attributed to variations in TIPS liquidity premiums. Using Equations (2) and (30), we can decompose TIPS yields,
, and TIPS BEI,
, into different components:
For TIPS yields, real yields dominate TIPS liquidity premiums in accounting for the time variations. In comparison, TIPS liquidity premiums are more important in driving TIPS BEI variations, explaining 10-15% of its variations across the three maturities, although expected inflation still accounts for the majority of time variations in TIPS BEI. Our results suggest that one should be especially cautious in interpreting variations in TIPS BEI solely in terms of changes in inflation expectation or inflation risk premiums.
To asses the robustness of our findings, in this section we apply our models to data from the U.K., one of the first developed countries to issue indexed securities when it introduced the index-linked gilts in 1981.38 Those gilts are indexed to the retail price index (RPI) and have an indexation lag of about 8 months. The inflation-indexed gilt market grew rapidly and now makes up about one quarter of the inflation-adjusted total amount of government bonds outstanding, far higher than the ratio in the U.S. One distinguishing feature of the U.K. index-linked gilt market is the dominance of institutional investors--defined as pension funds and combined insurance companies.39
Given the longer history of the index-linked gilt market and the much higher demand for such securities from market participants, we expect that liquidity premiums would account for a smaller portion of the variations in index-linked gilt yields than those in TIPS yields over our sample period. Indeed, as can be seen from Panel A of Table 1, three conventional gilt yields explain a much higher proportion of variations in the level of the 10-year BEI than in the U.S., although that proportion has declined notably since the onset of the recent crisis. In addition, as shown in Figure 9, two observable measures of the liquidity in the index-linked gilt market--the difference between the 10-year U.K. inflation swap rate (from Bloomberg) and the 10-year BEI, and the difference between the ASW spreads on index-linked gilts and those on the nominal counterparts (from Barclays)--have generally fluctuated at lower levels than those from the U.S. over the period since 2004 when they became available; both measures show notable increases during the financial crisis, similar to what we observe for the U.S.
We estimate the models over a monthly sample of January 1993 to March 2013. The starting date was motivated by the desire to avoid a potential structural break when the U.K. first adopted an inflation target in October 1992 following its departure from the Exchange Rate Mechanism.40 We use end-of-month zero-coupon yields on conventional gilts with maturities of 3 and 6 months and 1, 2, 4, 7, and 10 years and those on index-linked gilts with maturities of 5, 7, and 10 years, as implied by the spline curves proposed by Anderson and Sleath (2001) and maintained by the Bank of England (BoE).41 The inflation measure is the quarterly seasonally-adjusted RPI. Figure 10 plots both sets of yields, the BEI rates, and realized inflation. In addition to yields and inflation, we use survey forecasts of the 3-month interbank rate 3-month and 1-year ahead, available monthly from the Consensus Forecast survey. Unfortunately no long-range survey forecast of the short rate is available. To better pin down model parameters, we also use survey forecasts of inflation over the next year, available monthly, and over the next 5 to 10 years, available twice a year in April and October from the same survey.42
We estimate all three models with either three or four nominal factors; the potentially larger number of nominal factors is motivated by the observation that the first three principal components explain a slightly smaller proportion of nominal yields in the UK than in the U.S., as can be seen from Panel B of Table 1.43 The best model is Model L-I with four nominal factors and the results from this model are shown in Figure 11. As shown in the bottom right panel of that figure, liquidity premiums in indexed gilt yields fluctuates within plus and minus 50 basis points prior to the crisis, confirming our earlier conjecture that, on average, index-linked gilt yields contain smaller liquidity premiums than TIPS over that period. Liquidity premiums jumped to about 250 basis points at the height of the crisis, a level only slightly lower than those of TIPS, reflecting common funding liquidity shortages across those two countries with well-integrated financial markets. Much of the decline in 10-year BEI over the sample period is attributed to lower inflation risk premiums, while inflation expectations remained stable. Overall these results offer encouraging evidence that our model works well in a setting different from what it is originally designed for. Nonetheless, given the large differences in the institutional setup of the two markets, a more careful examination of the UK data than what is done here is needed to verify the findings in this section.
We document in this paper the existence of a TIPS-specific factor that appears important for explaining TIPS yield and TIPS BEI variations, and provide evidence that this factor likely reflects an (il)liquidity premium in TIPS yields.
We develop a joint no-arbitrage term structure model of nominal and TIPS yields incorporating two different specifications of the TIPS liquidity premiums. We show that ignoring the liquidity premium components leads to a poor model fit of TIPS yields, TIPS BEI, and survey inflation forecasts.
Our estimated TIPS liquidity premiums were fairly large until about 2003 and fluctuated within narrow ranges between then and the onset of the crisis, consistent with the common
perception that TIPS market liquidity was poor when TIPS were first introduced but it had steadily improved over time. TIPS liquidity premium estimates shot up to near 350 basis points after the Lehman bankruptcy, reflecting the stringent funding liquidity conditions over that period. The model
liquidity premium estimates are shown to be linked to changes in some observable measures of TIPS liquidity. When applied to the U.K. data, our model uncovers liquidity premiums on index-linked gilts that are fairly low in normal times, consistent with the larger size of the index-linked gilt
market, but spiked to about 250 basis points at the height of the financial crisis.
TIPS BEI has increasingly gained attention as a measure of investors' inflation expectations that is available in real-time and at high frequencies. However, our results raise caution in interpreting movement in TIPS BEI solely in terms of changing inflation expectations, as substantial liquidity premiums and inflation risk premiums could drive a large wedge between the two, as demonstrated vividly during the recent financial crisis. A better understanding of the determinants of TIPS liquidity premiums and the sources of its variation remains an interesting topic for future research.
Since
is independent of the other state variables in
, the first term
on the right-hand side of Equation (31) can be written as the sum of two components:
![]() |
||
![]() |
![]() |
(A-1) |
![]() |
(A-2) |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
(A-3) |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
(A-4) |
![]() |
(A-6) |
![]() |
![]() |
(A-9) |
![]() |
![]() |
(A-10) |
![]() |
![]() |
|
![]() |
(A-11) |
We use the Kalman filter to compute optimal estimates of the unobservable state factors based on all available information. For example, given the initial guess for the state factors
, it follows from the state equation (44) that the optimal estimate of the state factor
at time
is given by
This section describes the details in constructing the Davies (1987) Likelihood Ration Test Statistic mentioned in Section 5.1. Denote by the vector of nuisance parameters of size
, and define the likelihood ratio statistic as a function of
:
U.S. Sample | U.S. in level | U.S. in weekly changes | U.K. Sample | U.K. in level | U.K. in monthly changes |
Full Sample | 6.0 | 39.3 | Full Sample | 73.2 | 39.0 |
1999-2007 | 30.2 | 57.3 | 1993-2007 | 88.5 | 58.0 |
2008-2013 | 5.4 | 26.7 | 2008-2013 | 32.4 | 36.3 |
PC | U.S. nominal yields only | U.S. nominal and TIPS yields | U.K. nominal yields only | U.K. nominal and indexed yields |
1st | 70.6 | 65.2 | 66.0 | 54.2 |
2nd | 92.7 | 86.1 | 82.7 | 77.8 |
3rd | 97.6 | 94.1 | 95.8 | 88.0 |
4th | 99.2 | 97.6 | 99.3 | 96.5 |
nominal yields alone | U.S. nominal and TIPS yields PC1 | U.S. nominal and TIPS yields PC2 | U.S. nominal and TIPS yields PC3 | U.S. nominal and TIPS yields PC4 | U.K. nominal and indexed yields PC1 | U.K. nominal and indexed yields PC2 | U.K. nominal and indexed yields PC3 | U.K. nominal and indexed yields PC4 |
PC1 | 0.95 | -0.28 | -0.15 | 0.01 | 0.94 | -0.34 | -0.04 | 0.04 |
PC2 | 0.18 | 0.86 | -0.48 | 0.02 | 0.14 | 0.52 | -0.76 | 0.35 |
PC3 | 0.03 | 0.07 | 0.17 | 0.98 | 0.07 | 0.22 | 0.54 | 0.81 |
PC4 | 0.01 | 0.02 | 0.06 | -0.05 | 0.07 | 0.20 | 0.12 | -0.18 |
Model | Restrictions and Identifications |
Model NL |
![]() ![]() ![]() |
Model L-I |
![]() ![]() |
Model L-II |
![]() |
Model NL parameter estimate | Model NL standard error | Model L-I parameter estimate | Model L-I standard error | Model L-II parameter estimate | Model L-II standard error | |
![]() |
0.8604 | ( 0.9710) | 0.8227 | ( 0.3514) | 0.8106 | ( 0.8240) |
![]() |
0.1316 | ( 0.0534) | 0.1318 | ( 0.0536) | 0.1311 | ( 0.0549) |
![]() |
1.4528 | ( 1.1180) | 1.4652 | ( 0.3786) | 1.4833 | ( 0.9599) |
![]() |
-0.7358 | ( 1.0533) | -0.7685 | ( 0.5582) | -0.7724 | ( 1.0446) |
![]() |
-4.4381 | ( 16.7353) | -4.0872 | ( 4.2439) | -3.8970 | ( 11.1829) |
![]() |
-0.9482 | ( 0.2934) | -0.9848 | ( 0.2389) | -0.9827 | ( 0.2644) |
Model NL parameter estimate | Model NL standard error | Model L-I parameter estimate | Model L-I standard error | Model L-II parameter estimate | Model L-II standard error | |
![]() |
0.0269 | ( 0.0016) | 0.0355 | ( 0.0031) | 0.0297 | ( 0.0031) |
![]() |
-0.0209 | ( 1.7085) | 1.0897 | ( 0.5285) | 0.4419 | ( 1.2812) |
![]() |
0.1072 | ( 0.0607) | 0.3698 | ( 0.0806) | 0.1952 | ( 0.1091) |
![]() |
-0.2214 | ( 0.4512) | 0.0064 | ( 0.1497) | 0.0569 | ( 0.3339) |
![]() |
-0.0712 | ( 0.0451) | -0.1033 | ( 0.0411) | -0.0923 | ( 0.0559) |
![]() |
-0.0038 | ( 0.0709) | 0.0627 | ( 0.0613) | 0.0933 | ( 0.0759) |
![]() |
-0.0601 | ( 0.0672) | 0.0167 | ( 0.0610) | -0.0100 | ( 0.0688) |
![]() |
0.9136 | ( 0.0280) | 0.9209 | ( 0.0295) | 0.8916 | ( 0.0285) |
Model NL parameter estimate | Model NL standard error | Model L-I parameter estimate | Model L-I standard error | Model L-II parameter estimate | Model L-II standard error | |
![]() |
0.9500 | ( 0.0287) | 0.9650 | ( 0.0292) | ||
![]() |
0.2199 | ( 0.2227) | 0.2211 | ( 0.2294) | ||
![]() |
0.0119 | ( 0.0102) | 0.0042 | ( 0.0111) | ||
![]() |
0.1973 | ( 0.4285) | 0.1278 | ( 0.2954) | ||
![]() |
-0.0876 | ( 0.2228) | -0.0867 | ( 0.2296) | ||
![]() |
-0.3621 | ( 1.1991) | ||||
![]() |
-0.1987 | ( 0.1226) | ||||
![]() |
0.1671 | ( 0.4911) |
Model NL parameter estimate | Model NL standard error | Model L-I parameter estimate | Model L-I standard error | Model L-II parameter estimate | Model L-II standard error | |
![]() |
0.6006 | ( 0.1104) | 0.0900 | ( 0.0042) | 0.0892 | ( 0.0042) |
![]() |
0.4707 | ( 0.1263) | -0.0000 | (1905.3160) | 0.0000 | (113.6434) |
![]() |
0.4112 | ( 0.0742) | 0.0683 | ( 0.0037) | -0.0680 | ( 0.0037) |
Model NL parameter estimate | Model NL standard error | Model L-I parameter estimate | Model L-I standard error | Model L-II parameter estimate | Model L-II standard error | |
![]() |
0.1900 | ( 0.0147) | 0.1901 | ( 0.0149) | 0.1902 | ( 0.0148) |
![]() |
0.2979 | ( 0.0224) | 0.2980 | ( 0.0228) | 0.2981 | ( 0.0227) |
Model NL | Model L-I | Model L-II | |
No. of parameters | 42 | 47 | 50 |
Log likelihood | 72,768.06 | 76,723.65 | 76,734.05 |
AIC | -145,452.12 | -153,353.30 | -153,368.10 |
BIC | -145,237.89 | -153,113.56 | -153,113.06 |
LR p-value | ![]() |
0.04 |
Model NL | Model L-I | Model L-II | |
5-year CORR (in %) | 93.21 | 99.87 | 99.87 |
5-year RMSE | 0.60 | 0.16 | 0.16 |
5-year ![]() |
84.79 | 98.86 | 98.86 |
7-year CORR (in %) | 94.57 | 100.00 | 100.00 |
7-year RMSE | 0.48 | 0.13 | 0.13 |
7-year ![]() |
88.63 | 99.16 | 99.16 |
10-year CORR (in %) | 95.34 | 99.86 | 99.86 |
10-year RMSE | 0.43 | 0.14 | 0.14 |
10-year ![]() |
88.32 | 98.75 | 98.75 |
Model NL | Model L-I | Model L-II | |
7-year CORR (in %) | 36.08 | 100.00 | 100.00 |
7-year RMSE | 0.47 | 0.11 | 0.11 |
7-year ![]() |
10.62 | 95.12 | 95.08 |
10-year CORR (in %) | 17.74 | 98.53 | 98.53 |
10-year RMSE | 0.40 | 0.12 | 0.12 |
10-year ![]() |
-12.96 | 89.19 | 89.21 |
Model NL | Model L-I | Model L-II | |
1-year CORR (in %) | 44.05 | 64.00 | 77.06 |
1-year RMSE | 0.65 | 0.80 | 0.43 |
1-year ![]() |
3.91 | -45.14 | 57.71 |
10-year CORR (in %) | 63.02 | 67.03 | 71.15 |
10-yearRMSE | 0.49 | 0.65 | 0.40 |
10-year![]() |
16.56 | -48.02 | 43.62 |
Liquidity Premiums 5-year | Liquidity Premiums 7-year | Liquidity Premiums 10-year | Rel TIPS Trading Vol | TIPS Curve Fit Err | Nom On/Off ASW Diff | TIPS-Nom ASW Diff | Swaps-BEI Diff | |
Ten-year TIPS bid-ask spread | 0.51 | 0.49 | 0.47 | 0.30 | 0.66 | 0.57 | 0.58 | 0.41 |
Relative TIPS transaction volume | -0.57 | -0.57 | -0.56 | 0.39 | -0.28 | -0.12 | 0.01 | |
Average TIPS curve fitting err | 0.41 | 0.40 | 0.38 | 0.60 | 0.83 | 0.69 | ||
Nominal On/off ASW spread diff | 0.80 | 0.79 | 0.78 | 0.93 | 0.67 | |||
TIPS-nominal ASW spread diff | 0.91 | 0.92 | 0.91 | 0.88 | ||||
Inf swaps-BEI difference | 0.74 | 0.76 | 0.79 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
Constant | 1.2286 | 0.1008 | 0.4598 | 0.8646 |
Constant, standard error | (0.0371) | (0.0179) | (0.0196) | (0.0372) |
Relative TIPS transaction volume | -0.4043 | -0.4119 | ||
Relative TIPS transaction volume, standard error | (0.0218) | (0.0185) | ||
Nominal On/off ASW spread diff | 0.0311 | 0.0163 | ||
Nominal On/off ASW spread diff, standard error | (0.0009) | (0.0012) | ||
Averge TIPS curve fitting error | 0.0396 | 0.0360 | ||
Averge TIPS curve fitting error, standard error | (0.0036) | (0.0032) | ||
No. of observations | 743 | 743 | 743 | 743 |
Adjusted R-squared | 31.7% | 60.7% | 14.2% | 77.2% |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | |
Constant | 0.0694 | 1.0066 | 0.0717 | 0.0148 | -0.2715 | -0.3300 | 0.6599 | 0.2576 |
Constant, standard error | (0.0409) | (0.1249) | (0.0232) | (0.0214) | (0.0205) | (0.0357) | (0.0682) | (0.0632) |
Ten-year TIPS bid-ask spread, standard error | (0.0140) | (0.0078) | ||||||
Relative TIPS transaction volume | -0.2753 | -0.3184 | -0.2276 | |||||
Relative TIPS transaction volume, standard error | (0.0591) | (0.0316) | (0.0279) | |||||
Average TIPS curve fitting err | 0.0682 | 0.0466 | 0.0237 | |||||
Average TIPS curve fitting err, standard error | (0.0030) | (0.0041) | (0.0037) | |||||
Nominal On/off ASW spread diff | 0.0278 | 0.0122 | ||||||
Nominal On/off ASW spread diff, standard error | (0.0010) | (0.0016) | ||||||
TIPS-nominal ASW spread diff | 0.0187 | 0.0124 | ||||||
TIPS-nominal ASW spread diff, standard error | (0.0005) | (0.0013) | ||||||
Inf swaps-BEI difference | 0.0260 | 0.0023 | ||||||
Inf swaps-BEI difference, standard error | (0.0011) | (0.0015) | ||||||
No. of observations | 341 | 341 | 341 | 341 | 341 | 341 | 341 | 341 |
Adjusted R-squared | 27.0% | 5.7% | 61.1% | 69.3% | 83.3% | 63.3% | 79.1% | 86.3% |
Maturity | TIPS yield real yield | TIPS yield liq prem | TIPS BEI inf exp | TIPS BEI inf risk prem | TIPS BEI liq prem |
5-year | 0.9985 | 0.0015 | 0.7020 | 0.1392 | 0.1588 |
5-year, standard error | (0.2609) | (0.2609) | (0.5122) | (0.2212) | (0.6377) |
7-year | 1.0021 | -0.0021 | 0.7040 | 0.1704 | 0.1256 |
7-year, standard error | (0.2533) | (0.2533) | (0.5267) | (0.2588) | (0.6767) |
10-year | 1.0183 | -0.0183 | 0.6763 | 0.2103 | 0.1135 |
10-year, standard error | (0.2444) | (0.2444) | (0.5088) | (0.2929) | (0.6842) |