Abstract:
Leverage is often seen as villain in financial crises. Leverage of traders and financial intermediaries is procyclical and changes in credit are correlated with asset price movements (Adrian & Shin, 2010). Further, leverage growth predicts excess returns in
several asset classes (Adrian et al., 2010). In the recent crisis, sudden decreases in lending by financial intermediaries are regarded as one of the main culprits for fire sales and sharp increases in stock market volatility during 2008-2009 (Brunnermeier, 2009). In frictionless markets, changes in lending to investors have no asset pricing implications. However, recent theories establish a direct link between changes in margin credit and stock price movements (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009; Gromb &
Vayanos, 2002). If investors cannot satisfy margin calls, a decrease in leverage may lead to fire sales. With downward-sloping asset demand, this induces price dislocations, which may reinforce further deleveraging.
There is growing support for the hypothesis that traders' and intermediaries' balance sheet conditions matter for asset pricing. Several empirical studies show a relationship between changes in margin credit and asset price movements. Broker-dealer leverage is a significant pricing factor for stock
returns (Adrian et al., 2011). Changes in leverage of financial intermediaries are strongly correlated with stock market risk (Adrian & Shin, 2010). However, it has proven difficult to establish a direct link between changes in credit
and asset price movements. Leverage rarely varies exogenously; changes in credit are mostly endogenous decisions by financial intermediaries, other financiers, or investors. Further, when balance sheets are marked-to-market, changes in asset prices directly affect leverage.
In this paper I examine the asset pricing consequences of a large shock to financial intermediaries' margin lending. In May 1927, the German central bank forced banks to decrease credit for stock purchases given out to their clients. However, this shock affected only a subset of banks. Clients of
the affected banks mostly had to unwind their positions to meet the margin calls. Using a particular bias in their portfolios, I am able to differentiate between firms mostly held by clients of affected banks or unaffected banks. I show in a difference-in-differences framework that deleveraging had
large asset pricing implications. During the weeks following the shock on margin credit, stocks connected to affected banks declined 50 percent more than other stocks. They experienced negative cumulative returns of almost 400 percent (annualized). Further, return volatility of these stocks
doubled. Connecting stocks directly with specific intermediaries and changes in their balance sheets, I find that mean daily returns were not affected by the cut in margin lending. However, a one standard deviation decrease in margin credit increased a stock's volatility by 0.22 standard
deviations.
The historical setting is interwar Germany. During the mid-1920's, increasing stock market valuations went in lockstep with an increase in margin credit. Yet it were mainly the six large "Berlin banks" that enabled their clients to buy assets on credit. Margins could be as low as 10 percent.
However, the rise of stock prices and margin credit drew the attention of the German central bank, the Reichsbank. Mostly for political reasons, its president, Hjalmar Schacht, campaigned against the banks' practices to constantly increase credit supply and to allow highly leveraged positions. This
campaign culminated in the threat of the Reichsbank to cut short term funding for the Berlin banks. The threat was effective. On 12 May 1927, the Berlin banks issued a joint statement. Over the course of the following weeks, each bank would decrease their stock of margin credit by 25 percent while
issuing margin calls towards their clients. The consequences were immediate - 13 May 1927 became known as Black Friday. The stock market declined by 13 percent. The large shock initiated by the Reichsbank trickled down to investors. During the following weeks, banks increased the margins of their
clients' portfolios. As most investors could not satisfy the margin calls, fire sales occurred. However, at a given bank these fire sales were concentrated on a special set of firms - firms that had a close relationship to the bank. Using evidence from the German Federal Archives to establish these
bank-firm connections, I show that stocks differed in their reaction to the deleveraging: A firm's stock price declined stronger and fluctuated more if the firm was connected to a bank that experienced a larger credit crunch.
Figure 1 summarizes the main result. The left panel shows two stock price indices, one index composed of firms connected to the large Berlin banks, and another index of firms with no connection to these banks. Both indices are normalized to 12 May 1927. At this day, the
Berlin banks issued their joint statement and both indices declined. However, over the course of the following month "large bank"-stocks declined more than 12 percent, while other stocks dropped less than 8 percent. Further, volatility almost doubled for firms connected to the Berlin banks. This is
shown in the right panel, which plots volatility indices for both groups of firms. Stocks more exposed to fire sales had more negative returns and experienced larger fluctuations. This causal impact of deleveraging on return volatility is robust to several criticisms. The result still holds when
controlling for attributes such as the number of underwriters or firm size. An instrumental variable strategy further shows that reverse causality does not drive the results.
This study is related to several strands of the literature. Several theoretical papers establish a causal link between margin requirements and asset price behavior (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009; Gromb & Vayanos, 2002). Recent empirical studies provide suggestive evidence for this
link. Leverage is pro-cyclical (Adrian & Shin, 2010) and leverage growth has predictive power for excess returns (Adrian et al., 2010). I contribute to this literature by providing a clean empirical test that changes in margin credit
led to increased volatility in interwar Germany. I further add to the literature on fire sales and price pressures. (Coval & Stafford, 2007) and other empirical studies show that in the short run, selling pressure leads to price dislocations. I complement these studies
and add further evidence that an increase in selling volume leads to disturbances of asset prices. Historically, this study adds to the literature on stock markets in interwar Germany. I complement the study of (Voth, 2003) by providing a disaggregate look at the stock
market crash in 1927.
The next section surveys the related literature. Section 3 describes the historical setting in more detail. It explains the economic situation as well as the banking industry in interwar Germany. Section 4 describes the data. Section 5 shows how the shock to margin lending affected stock price behavior. Section 6 refines the results. Section 7 concludes.
This study is related to several strands of the literature. It relates to the theoretical and empirical literature on margin credit and asset prices, commonality of returns, and the cyclicality of credit. Also, it adds to the literature on price pressure and asset fire sales. On the banking
side, it adds to the literature on intermediary capital.
The connection between margin credit and asset prices received a lot of attention in the wake of the recent financial crisis. However, earlier theoretical papers already examined the causal effects of changes in margins on returns and volatility. In (Gromb & Vayanos,
2002) arbitrageurs cannot finance their arbitrage activity completely with own funds. Margin credit helps traders to pursue their investment strategies. In normal times, credit allows these traders to eliminate arbitrage opportunities and assets are traded at fair prices. Yet when margin
constraints bind, arbitrageurs cannot eliminate price inefficiencies. (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009) provide the microfoundations for binding margin constraints. In their model, financiers give credit to traders. The amount of credit depends on the volatility
of assets and is determined by VaR constraints. When price volatility increases, financiers issue margin calls, which traders may be unable to satisfy. They are forced to sell their assets, which decreases asset prices and further diminishes a trader's wealth. Margin and wealth spirals occur.
(He & Krishnamurthy, 2012) also develop a model where intermediary capital is scarce and relevant for asset pricing in crises times.
The importance of credit for asset prices is also stressed by several macroeconomic models. These theories focus mostly on the cyclical behavior of prices and credit to explain business cycle fluctuations. In (Bernanke & Gertler, 1989), asset prices influence the
balance sheet capacity of borrowers. (Kiyotaki & Moore, 1997) show that collateral requirements change over the business cycle. These changes amplify shocks to the economy.
The relationship between credit or margin requirements and asset prices is the subject of various empirical studies. Earlier studies found no effect of changes in margin requirements on asset prices (Hsieh & Miller, 1990; Moore, 1966; Officer, 1973). More
recently, (Adrian et al., 2010) find that leverage growth has predictive power for excess returns. Furthermore, Wall Street investment banks exhibit procyclical leverage (Adrian & Shin, 2010). When asset prices and the corresponding
balance sheet positions of banks rise, banks adjust their balance sheets and take on more debt - leverage increases. When asset prices decline, an opposite spiral emerges. Further, changes in leverage are correlated with increases in stock market risk.
These papers are related to a broader strand of the literature that investigates fire sales and price pressure. The theoretical literature on asset fire sales is large and summarized by (Shleifer & Vishny, 2011). Several empirical papers suggest that when traders
have to exogenously unwind their positions, prices react. (Coval & Stafford, 2007) show that prices decrease when mutual funds sell large positions. Over the medium run, prices reverse course and recover. (Mitchell & Pulvino, 2012) look
at several markets around the times of the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. When investments banks cut their lending to hedge funds almost completely, these arbitrageurs were unable to follow their typical investment strategies. A large increase in the CDS-bond spread followed, the convertible
securities market seemed mispriced, and merger arbitrage opportunities arose for merger target stocks. (Hendershott & Menkveld, 2013) look at price pressure in the short run and find dislocations of prices on a daily basis. Investigating differences in stock
returns during times of high selling pressure, (Blume et al., 1989) show that stocks included in the S&P 500 declined stronger than other stocks during the 1987 crash. But these stocks also showed a stronger reversal, leading to higher volatility. Explanations for
these differences range from institutional trading to behavioral reasons such as greater visibility. (Greenwood & Thesmar, 2011) use mutual fund data to show that stocks are more "fragile" if their ownership base is more concentrated. Individual liquidity shocks
cannot be cancelled out when only a few investors own a specific stock. But even a diverse ownership base can lead to fragility, if several investors experience correlated liquidity shocks. (Anton & Polk, 2014) show that common ownership of stocks by mutual funds can
explain return commonality in the cross-section.
Further, this article is related to the literature on intervention in asset markets. Most papers focus on intervention in foreign exchange markets. A classical reference on intervention by central banks is (Bagehot, 1873).
On the historical side, the paper adds to the literature on German stock markets in the interwar period. Most literature on German stock markets investigates the period before WW I (Burhop, 2011;
Lehmann, 2011). In one of the few studies on the interwar period, (Voth, 2003) looks at the Black Friday in an aggregate context. He claims that Schacht was wrong and the high
stock price valuations in 1927 did not represent an asset price bubble. My study looks at the same episode, taking a disaggregate view on stocks and the banking sector. The next section explains this historical episode in more detail.
On the evening of 12 May 1927, the six largest German banks published the following statement:
"The members of the union of Berlin banks and bankers (Stempelvereinigung) have come today to the agreement to slowly but noticeably decrease the funds available for stock purchases on credit. Therefore they will decrease the stock of margin credit until the middle of the month by 25 percent and further afterwards. Against clients they will act in the same way." 1One day later, the German stock market lost 13 percent. This section provides a short overview of how this communique came about. The first part looks at the economic situation and the evolution of the stock market during the interwar period. Parts 2 and 3 describe banking in Germany and the evolution of banks' balance sheets. Part 4 describes the Reichsbank's view on increasing stock valuations and banks' lending policies. The last part explains the strong connections between banks and firms before WW II in Germany.
Interwar Germany is often associated with political turmoil, austerity, and high unemployment. However, during the years after the hyperinflation, the outlook was far better. After 1924, the German economy began to recover. Chancellor Gustav Stresemann established a political and civic order,
and a period of falling unemployment and increasing industrial production began. The "Golden Twenties" led to economic recovery, investment, and even a flourishing cultural scene. The recovery also affected the stock market. During the first years after the war, volume on the stock exchange had
been low. Stock prices were at low levels and highly volatile, while interest rates were high and transactions in futures not allowed. As the outlook brightened, the high interest rates attracted foreign capital. In contrast to other central banks, the Reichsbank pursued a policy of high discount
rates. Until February 1925, the discount rate was 10 percent and even during 1926 it still stood at 8 percent.2 This policy was the main driver of foreign
capital inflows. The American diplomat S.P. Gilbert saw these inflows even as a major cause of Germany's economic recovery. When interest rates started to decline and investors searched for higher yields, stock prices began to rise. A short recession during 1925 and the beginning of 1926 did not
hinder this development and at the end of 1925, the aggregate stock market index stood at 99 percent (of its pre-WW I level). During 1926, it rose to 140 percent (November 1926) and even higher in 1927 (178 percent in April 1927).
The new confidence in stock markets increased the demand for margin credit. Already before WW I, margin credit was a major funding source for investors and a large part of banks' investment banking business. When an investor wanted to finance a trade, he had only to pay a fraction of the stock
purchase with his own capital. A bank lent the rest and took the purchased securities as collateral. Investors were able to reach high levels of leverage; margin requirements could be as low as 10 percent. But during the period of hyperinflation, margin credit had come to a standstill and was a
negligible part of banks' balance sheets. As the stock market recovered, margin credit slowly started to increase. Figure 2 shows the evolution of the stock market and margin credit between 1925 and 1928. During the bull market from 1926 to mid-1927, total margin credit
increased from below 100 Million RM to almost 900 Million RM.
However, this increase was not evenly spread across banks; only a handful of banks accounted for a large part of it. Six private banks, all situated in Berlin, had in 1925 a combined level of stock market credit roughly equal to the level of other private banks with branches. During the following
years the Berlin banks increased their margin lending on a large scale, whereas the "province banks" lacked behind significantly. At 31 October 1925, the total amount of margin credit was 303.5 Million RM. A third had been given out by the Berlin banks (101 Million RM). Total credit grew to 1413.9
Million RM (30 April 1927). The largest fraction of credit was given out by the Berlin banks. In 1927, their share grew to 892 Million RM, while combined credit at other private banks was only 200 Million RM. The right panel of Figure 3 shows these differences in margin
lending between the Berlin banks and other, larger private banks. Berlin banks also differed from these banks by how their assets were financed. Leverage was almost double as compared to the province banks, as the left panel in Figure 3 shows.
However, differences existed even among Berlin banks. The next section takes a closer look at these banks.
Berlin banks were substantially different than their peers across Germany. However, they also differed amongst themselves. Danatbank's CEO for example sat on over 100 supervisory boards and pursued an aggressive expansionary strategy. The Berliner Handels Gesellschaft was on the other side of
the spectrum, keeping their stock market activity at a minimum and only giving credit to low-risk borrowers. Leverage as well as margin lending reflected these strategic differences. Figure 4 depicts these differences. The left panel shows the evolution of the ratio of
assets over equity for five of the Berlin banks between 1925 and 1928. During 1927, Danatbank's leverage was almost double Diskonto's leverage. The Danatbank has also been a very active lender for stock purchases, as the right panel shows. While in 1925 banks had comparable levels of margin
lending, at the peak in May 1927 there were sizable differences between them. Again, Databank had given out almost double the amount of margin credit as compared to Diskonto.
While margin credit increased, other highly liquid positions on the banks' asset side deteriorated. An important measure of banks' liquidity was the ratio of cash and short-term assets at the central bank over short-term liabilities. The average of this ratio across the large banks was 5.58 percent
at the end of 1912. After the hyperinflation it had already decreased to 3.21 percent. In February 1927, it reached its low at 2.59 percent. Liquidity increased after the intervention of the Reichsbank and short-term assets over short-term liabilities increased to 4.02 percent until the end of June
1927. The continuous decline in this liquidity ratio was mainly driven by a decrease in banks' cash positions. Before WW I, banks held 112.31 Million RM in cash. At the end of 1925, this position had fallen to 66.9 Million RM. Between February 1927 and June 1927 it increased again from 78.6 Million
RM to 126.8 Million RM.
Low on cash, banks started to rely heavily on a different source of short-term funding: Promissory notes. A promissory note is a promise of firm A to pay back a credit to firm B until a certain date. Firm B can use this promise to obtain cash at a bank. The bank takes over the promissory note,
bearing the default risk of the debtor, firm A. Regularly, a bank was not the ultimate holder of a promissory note as it could redeem the note for cash at the central bank. The central bank accepted promissory notes from almost all industrial firms, which were the majority of the issuers.
The use of promissory notes by banks was inherently linked to margin credit. Investors used credit by banks to roll over their futures positions. At the Berlin stock exchange, futures were settled at the 15. and 30. of every month. If an investor was supposed to settle a long position at these
dates, he often used bank credit. Banks took the bought stocks as collateral until the credit was due the following month. To obtain the liquidity needed to issue margin credits, banks redeemed promissory notes at the Reichsbank. This can be seen in Figure 5. The graph
shows the evolution of promissory notes held by the Reichsbank. The series spikes twice a month, at the days when futures trades had to be settled. During the year before the Black Friday, promissory notes taken by the Reichsbank more than doubled. This reliability of banks on the Reichsbank made
the large Berlin banks vulnerable.
Another source of vulnerability was the sudden stop in long-term foreign capital, which was initiated by the government. Up to the end of 1926, foreign owners of German bonds were not taxed by the German tax authority. But on 4 December 1926, the German government abolished this exemption - foreign
holders of bonds had to pay German capital taxes. As a consequence, the inflow of long-term foreign capital declined from 137.9 Million RM (December 1926) to 13.7 Million RM (January 1927). Banks could no longer obtain long-term foreign funds and had to rely to an even greater extend on the central
bank. The next section turn to this institution; an institution that criticized banks' lending policies and the evolution of the German stock market.
The Reichsbank, and most prominently its president Hjalmar Schacht, had a specific position towards the stock market boom - the view that stocks were overvalued and that the high valuations were bad for the German economy. This view was based on three arguments (James,
1986). First, Hjalmar Schacht believed that funds invested in the stock market would be unavailable for real investment. Second, the surge in the stock market would attract too much short-term foreign capital, a source of instability and uncertainty. And third, in the eyes of Schacht stock
market valuations were too high and irrational and did not reflect the state of the German economy.
Already contemporaries criticized the first argument. Before and after the stock market crash, commentators in newspapers, speeches, and dissertations noted that the stock market boom did not harm real investment (see for example (Benning, 1929)). Their main argument
against Schacht was that one's stock purchase is another one's stock sell. This free capital could be invested in the real economy. Schacht was not convinced by this argumentation and claimed that most revenues from stock sales would flow into luxuries. However, national accounts of the German
Reich do not show an increase in the consumption of luxuries.
The second argument, the fragile nature of short-term foreign capital, was more substantial. However, the Reichsbank itself and the government were the source of the increased instability. Because of high interest rates at the beginning of the recovery, Germany attracted foreign investors.
Initially, foreign capital inflows were both short-term as well as long-term. But the abolishment of the preferential tax treatment for bonds in foreign currency led to a sudden standstill of long-term foreign capital flows. Further, the withdrawal of foreign funds depleted the Reichsbank's
position in foreign exchange (Figure 6). In January 1927, reserves in foreign exchange dropped over 60 percent. New capital inflows were almost exclusively short term, and the Reichsbank was afraid of further withdrawals.
There was no consensus among contemporaries whether Germany experienced a stock market bubble. In the eyes of Hjalmar Schacht, stocks were overvalued. The state of the German economy would be far from good and the stock market would only reflect irrational exuberance. Further, high stock market
valuations did not fit well into his political agenda. He advocated lower reparation payments and argued that the current level of payments restricted the German economy. On 8 May 1927, he wrote in the newspaper Muenchner Neueste Nachrichten that he disagrees with the "false image of the
currently high stock prices at German exchanges, on which the opinion of supposedly regained German strength is mainly based." After months of arguing against high valuations, banks suggested to raise interest rates. Hjalmar Schacht did not commit to such a policy and instead focused on the large
Berlin banks and their lending policies.3 Looking at the level of the stock market, (Voth, 2003) argues that Hjalmar Schacht was
already wrong in his premise of an existing stock market bubble.
The Reichsbank's position towards high stock market valuations together with the large banks' low short-run liquidity culminated in an unofficial threat. The Reichsbank warned the largest private banks: If the banks would not cut their margin lending by at least 25 percent, the Reichsbank would not
redeem their promissory notes anymore. This threat was effective and on 12 May banks declared to cut their margin credit by 25 percent over the coming weeks. This large shock on credit had immediate consequences. On 13 May, later known as the "Black Friday", the whole stock market tumbled. The
average decrease was 13 percent, but some stocks did far worse. In the following weeks, stocks declined further. The large shock on lending was transmitted to investors. The Berlin banks did not prolong the credit used to buy stocks and forced investors to liquidate their positions. Transaction tax
revenues, a proxy for volume, increased during May and June, but dropped sharply afterwards.4 Other German banks did cut their stock market credit on a much
smaller scale. The empirical section will use these differences across banks. However, to establish a link between changes in margin credit and asset price movements, the margin cuts at the Berlin banks must affect different stocks than the margin cuts at other banks. The next section describes how
I establish a relationship between banks and stocks.
The Economist described the German banking system in 1911 like this:
"The German banks have a much wider sphere of action than our English deposit banks. Besides doing the same kind of business they are stock, bill, and exchange brokers and dealers, banker-merchants, trust, financial, and promoting companies, etc. What may be described as their chief merit and defect is their intimate connection with German industrial life...Not only have the banks promoted most of the industrial joint-stock companies, and retain part of their share capital, but their managing directors remain members of the board of these companies..." (The Economist, 21 October 1911) 5German universal banks had very strong firm connections - a bank's CEO sat on the supervisory board of a firm, a bank was a firm's main creditor, and when a firm wanted to go public, its connected firm was the natural choice as underwriter. On the stock market, the connection between a firm and a bank did not end with a public equity offering. A bank held an inventory of stocks of connected firms and actively intervened in the stock market in case of order book imbalances. The bank therefore was a stock's main liquidity provider and soothed price fluctuations due to order imbalances. When it came to investment advice to their clients, banks would strongly suggest to invest in firms they made markets in. These firms were backed by the same institution a client had picked in the first place. When in stocks connected to the same bank, clients also faced more liquid markets. Banks not only made markets at the Berlin stock exchange, but also matched trades internally.
The main data are daily stock prices and underwriter prospectuses to establish bank-firm connections. I use two samples: the full sample and the single-underwriter sample. The full sample consists of daily stock prices for 147 firms between February 1,1927 and July 1, 1927. Most of these firms
had one or two large underwriters, while some firms had up to 6 Berlin banks as underwriters. Same parts of the analysis make use of a sub-sample, which consists of 98 firms that had a single underwriter. Prices are digitalized from newspaper scans of the Berliner Börsen Zeitung.
Bank-firm connections are established with IPO and SEO prospectuses held at the German National Archives in Berlin. The archives hold firm-specific files of over 300 publicly listed firms before WW II and I select all firms still active in 1927. Bank balance sheet data are taken from the newspaper
Vossische Nachrichten, which published banks' balance sheets for the Berlin banks every two months. Aggregate data (monthly stock market index, aggregate margin credit data for all big banks) are taken from the Statistische Jahrbücher für das Deutsche Reich.
Table 3 summarizes firms' characteristics. Most firms are from the manufacturing sector, although they differ in size. While the mean share capital in the lowest size quartile is 1.33 Million RM, the mean share capital is 108.63 Million RM in the largest quartile. These
differences are not perfectly reflected in the number of underwriters. Share capital and the number of underwriters are positively correlated, however, this correlation is far from perfect (0.5). The mean number of underwriters is below 1.5 for all but the biggest firms.
Table 4 summarizes firms with only one large underwriter. It provides mean and median share capital for each bank-specific portfolio. The largest portfolio in the sample is the Deutsche Bank portfolio. Most portfolios are similar in median share capital, with the
Commerzbank being an exception. Mean share capital differs more and ranges from 11.95 Million RM for the BHG to almost 20 Million RM for the Danatbank portfolio.6
When the Berlin banks were forced to change their lending policies, they issued margin calls to their clients. They did not roll-over the majority of stock market debt and increased margins, the proportions investors had to pay out of their own wealth. Most of their clients could not satisfy these margin calls. However, other banks were less affected as they were not subject to the threat of the Reichsbank. This section looks at the asset pricing implications of such a large change in lending policy. The first section shows that stocks affiliated with large banks became more volatile. The second part takes a closer look at this general result. The behavior of returns and volatility differed also across firm size and the number of underwriters.
After the Berlin banks had issued their joint statement, stocks experienced differences in selling pressure. This section provides a first glance at the consequences of these differences. It provides summary statistics for stocks that were connected to Berlin banks and other stocks.
Figure 1, already introduced in a previous section, shows that when the Berlin banks issued their margin calls, stocks of affiliated firms declined. Over the following weeks, the stock price of a firm connected to a large underwriter declined on average more than 12
percent until the end of June. Firms that were not connected to a large underwriter were less affected. Such stocks declined on average only 8 percent. These differences in behavior did not occur immediately when the Berlin banks issued their statement. At 13 May, both groups declined equally. But
over time, the differences became visible. Further, volatility spiked for affected firms. During the following two months, Berlin-bank-affiliated stocks were more volatile than other stocks.
These results can also be seen in Table 5. The table provides mean daily returns, the standard deviation of returns, mean firm-specific return volatility, and measures for order book imbalances before and after 12 May. Mean daily returns decline for both groups of firms
after 12 May. Volatility declines for firms without a connection to Berlin banks. However, volatility almost doubles for firms connected to a large underwriter. As these banks cut their margin lending, asset prices of firms connected to them started to fluctuate. The next section will control for
several factors that may influence this result and show that this basic finding is robust to several criticisms.
The simple descriptive statistics can neither account for differences across firms nor for differences across time. To properly address the question whether a change in lending policy had asset pricing implications, I use a difference-in-differences approach. The baseline specification is given by
$$\displaystyle y_{it}=\beta (Bank_i*May_t)+\gamma_{it}+\epsilon_{it}$$ | (1) |
Given the same shock, selling pressure often differs across stocks. If demand is downward-sloping, these differences have asset pricing implications. (Greenwood & Thesmar, 2011) show that stocks are more fragile if their ownership base is either more
concentrated or when liquidity shocks are correlated across investors. In these cases, selling pressure increases because liquidity shocks are less likely to cancel out across investors. The larger the affected fraction of a stock's ownership base, the larger is the price impact. For example, if
several mutual funds experience the same shock, stocks commonly owned by several funds start to co-move (Anton & Polk, 2014).
The previous section showed that selling pressure was larger for stocks affiliated with the Berlin banks. This section takes a closer look at the differences across stocks before and after 12 May 1927. Besides a large bank connection, which further characteristics determined the selling pressure
after the margin calls? The first part of this section looks at firm size, while the second part looks at the number of underwriters. Both characteristics measure indirectly which proportion of stockholders was affected by the margin calls. The larger this proportion was, the more these stocks
declined over the following weeks. Further, the impact on volatility increased as well.
Firm size affects how widespread stocks are held. Stocks of larger firms are often assumed to be safer and to have smaller information asymmetries. The stock market in interwar Germany was no exception. Stocks of large companies like Siemens were widely held as safe investments. Even banks that
did not act as underwriter for these firms often accepted them as collateral. Clients of Berlin banks held them in their portfolios even if the bank had no direct affiliation. Firm size therefore proxies for how many owners of a stock were affected by margin calls of the large banks. Larger firms
experienced stronger selling pressure.
Figure 7 shows how returns and return volatility differed for firms of different size. Firm size is measured by share capital and the graph plots mean stock price indices and mean volatility indices for each size quartile. Looking at returns, the impact of the margin calls
increases with firm size. On the day of the stock market crash, firms in the first size quartile decreased on average 2.26 percent. The same day, firms in the largest size quartile decreased 11.83 percent. These differences persisted over time. One month after the announcement of the Berlin banks,
small firms had declined on overage 8.32 percent since 12 May. The largest firms had experienced a mean cumulative return of 15.04 percent.
Not only did stocks of large firms decline stronger, they also fluctuated more. The second panel of Figure 7 shows mean firm-specific return variance for the four size quartiles. Before 12 May, a commonly known characteristic can be seen: Larger firms are more stable;
smaller firms fluctuate more. However, this finding turns after 12 May. At the onset of the crisis, stocks of large firms start to fluctuate heavily. Mean volatility for larger firms doubles in the period after 12 May compared to the weeks before. Mean volatility for firms in the first size
percentile decreases slightly from 0.001 to 0.0009.
After 12 May, large firms lost their characteristic as safer investments. Although their "ownership base was disperse", in the words of (Greenwood & Thesmar, 2011), most owners were affected by the Berlin banks' margin calls. As a consequence, these stocks reacted
sharper on impact and fluctuated stronger during the crisis period. The next section turns to another proxy for the impact of the margin call on stockholders.
The previous section argued that larger firms were used more often as collateral because they were considered to be safer investments. This observation is not specific to interwar Germany and even applies to todays markets. However, other characteristics exist to proxy the impact of the margin
call on stockholders. One characteristic is specific to the close bank firm connections in pre-WW II Germany: the number of large underwriters. The fraction of stockholders connected to a large bank increased if a firm had more than one large underwriter. Figure 8 plots
stock price and volatility indices depending on the number of large underwriters. Looking at the returns directly after 12 May, no large differences can be observed. On impact, stocks connected to no large underwriter had the same negative returns as stocks connected to one or more underwriters.
During May and June 1927, however, differences emerged. As large underwriter banks started to send out their margin calls to individual investors, prices of stocks connected to these banks slipped. One month after the shock, prices had declined on average 14 percent for firms with two or more large
underwriters. During the same period, firms with no large underwriters saw negative returns of only 7.3 percent. Further, after the Reichsbank's intervention volatility was increasing in the number of underwriters (right panel).
Firm size and the number of underwriters both allow us to proxy the fraction of the ownership base hit by margin calls. However, these measures are correlated. Although the correlation is far from perfect, the two graphs just described may still pick up the same mechanism.7 Larger firms had more underwriters; the number of underwriters may only reflect this fact. Can each characteristic on its own explain differences in asset price
behavior? To disentangle the effects, I run the following regression:
$$\displaystyle y_{it}=\beta May_t*Charac_i+\gamma_{it}+\epsilon_{it}$$ | (2) |
Aggregate intermediary balance sheet variables have strong predictive power for excess returns (Adrian et al., 2010). This section links asset price behavior directly to changes in margin credit at individual banks. The first part shows that stocks fluctuated more if they were connected to a bank that sharply cut its margin lending. Part 2 turns to order book imbalances. The last part shows that the baseline results are robust to the problem of reverse causality.
The analysis so far showed that a contraction in credit led to higher volatility in interwar Germany. The baseline results use the differences between two groups of firms: Firms connected to large underwriter banks and firms with no connection to these banks. Differences in asset price behavior
are then attributed to different deleveraging between Berlin banks and other banks. Berlin banks had to change their lending policies and stocks related to these banks became more volatile. However, other characteristics influenced returns and volatility as well; Berlin bank related firms may be
inherently different from other firms. This section turns to a more homogeneous sample: Firms that are affiliated with a single Berlin bank. To identify how margin credit affected asset prices, I now use only differences in lending policies between the Berlin banks. For example, Diskonto
Gesellschaft decreased its margin credit by 41.56 percent during May and June. In the same period, Commerzbank cut its credit by only 15.63 percent. In terms of absolute decrease, Deutsche Bank experienced the largest decline - 67.29 Million RM. Did these differences induce different asset price
behavior for affiliated firms?
Table 9 provides a first look at the single underwriter sample. It reports the results of the following regression:
$$\displaystyle y_{ibt}=\beta May_t+\alpha+\epsilon_{ibt}$$ | (3) |
$$\displaystyle y_{ibt} = \beta_1 May_p*Credit_{bp}+\gamma+\epsilon_{ibt}$$ | (4) |
The volume on the Berlin stock exchange increased sharply during May and June 1927.8 So far we saw that the increase in volume did not lead to significantly
higher order book imbalances. However, when comparing only non-Berlin bank firms with Berlin bank firms, we may average out differences within the latter group. Table 11 shows the frequencies of order book imbalances before and after 12 May for each bank-specific
portfolio. The table provides a more detailed view on the behavior of order book imbalances. Excess supply decreased for firms connected to banks with small decreases in margin credit (Commerzbank, Dresdner Bank). If a firm was affiliated to banks with large credit cuts, the frequency of excess
supply increased (Deutsche Bank, Danatbank). These differences across banks are confirmed in Table 12. Instead of returns or volatility, the frequency of order book imbalances is now used as dependent variable. The overall level of margin credit had a negative impact
on the frequency of supply order imbalances and a positive impact on demand order imbalances. During the large deleveraging of some banks, however, the relationship changes. Stocks connected to more active lenders were more likely to be in excess supply. Further, the absolute change in margin
credit had a significant impact on the probability of excess supply during the crisis period (column 2).
This section refined the baseline results and confirmed the negative impact of changes in margin credit on return volatility. But, even in the absence of mark-to-market, the results may still be prone to problems of reverse causality. Higher asset prices could have influenced banks lending
decisions. The next section addresses this criticism.
When intermediaries account for their assets in real time (mark-to-market), changes in asset prices and changes in margin credit may reinforce each other (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009). A decrease in prices can lead to a further tightening of credit
constraints and additional fire sales may follow. In the context of 1927 Germany, the problem of real time accounting is not present. Nevertheless, rising asset prices may still have influenced banks' lending decisions. The previous results may be biased due to the problem of reverse causality.
Further, the previous section used daily returns, whereas banks' balance sheet variables vary at a lower frequency. Within a given two-month balance sheet period, we do not exactly know when the decrease in credit occurred.
I address the latter problem by aggregating all variables on a bi-monthly basis. The following analysis uses mean daily returns and mean firm-specific volatility as dependent variables. Means are taken over the periods where balance sheet variables change.
To address the problem of reverse causality, I use the Reichsbank's threat against the Berlin banks in a two-stage least squares specification. Berlin banks were heavily dependent on promissory notes. Each bank held a large portfolio of such notes. In times of liquidity needs, they could redeem
these claims at the Reichsbank in return for cash. However, the Reichsbank's willingness to redeem large amounts of promissory notes started to decrease during the run-up to the crisis. Although never stated officially, historians agree that Schacht started to threaten private banks: Not cutting
margin lending would come at the price of not having access to the Reichsbank's liquidity. The threat worked. I will instrument the absolute change in margin credit during balance sheet period s by the level of a bank's promissory notes portfolio in period s-1. Further, the interaction term of change in margin credit with the May dummy is instrumented by the interaction of the lagged promissory portfolio and the May dummy. For this to be a valid instrument, the level of a bank's promissory notes portfolio cannot influence future asset
price movements of affiliated firms except through the Reichsbank's threat. Each bank held promissory notes of a large spectrum of industrial firms. While the previous owners of these notes were mainly bank-affiliated firms, the debtors were not. It is therefore reasonable to assume that a
portfolio composed of debts of different firms did not directly influence future asset price movements of bank-affiliated firms.
The first stage regressions are given by
$$\displaystyle Change_{bs}$$ | $$\displaystyle = \beta_1 Notes_{b,s-1}+\beta_2 Notes_{b,s-1}*May_{s}+\gamma_{bs}+\epsilon_{ibs}$$ | (5) |
$$\displaystyle Change_{bs}*May_{s}$$ | $$\displaystyle = \beta_3 Notes_{b,s-1}+\beta_4 Notes_{b,s-1}*May_{s}+\gamma_{bs}+\epsilon_{ibs}$$ | (6) |
$$\displaystyle var_{ibs}= \beta_1 \widehat{Change_{bs}}+\beta_2(\widehat{Change_{bs}*May_s})+\gamma_{ibs}+\epsilon_{ibs}$$ | (7) |
Do tighter lending standards induce fire sales, price dislocations, and worsen financial crises (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009; Gromb & Vayanos, 2002)? This article provides a historical case study where a large change in lending standards induced stock market volatility. When the German central bank forced
some banks to size down their margin lending, stocks connected to the affected banks declined significantly more than other stocks during the following weeks. Return volatility of these stocks doubled.
In the absence of marking-to-market, this study is a lower bound of the impact of deleveraging on asset prices. However, this historical case cannot answer the severeness of second round effects, asset price spirals, and margin spirals. The recent crisis has shown the importance of a more detailed
knowledge of these issues, for academics as well as policy makers. Further quantitative studies can guide regulation regarding capital buffers and intermediaries' balance sheet capacity.
Before being appointed as head of the Federal Reserve, Janet Yellen said that "it is important for the Fed, as hard as it is, to try to detect asset bubbles when they are forming."9 Yet the experience of 1927 shows that more research is needed to understand the interaction of asset market intervention, bank balance sheets, and macroeconomic outcomes. (Adrian et al., 2010) provide first insights in the co-movement of
banks' balance sheets and macroeconomic dynamics. The results presented here show the importance of a financial sector in quantitative macroeconomic models. Adopting regulators' and policy makers' toolkit to incorporate a financial sector poses a challenge for future research. An emerging
literature takes on this challenge (see, for example, (Brunnermeier & Sannikov, 2014)) and future research in this direction will be important to avoid the mistakes of 1927.
Table 1: Balance sheets: Berlin banks and other banks.
This table provides an overview of various bank balance sheet variables for the Berlin banks and province banks. All variables are in Million RM. Equity in the last line is defined as share capital plus reserves.Feb 1925 | Feb 1926 | Feb 1927 | Oct 1927 | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Berlin Banks | ||||
N | 6 | 6 | 6 | 6 |
Total assets | 4472.6 | 5466.2 | 7447.4 | 8560 |
Stock market credit | 53.2 | 164.8 | 896.1 | 556.2 |
Promissory notes | 883.5 | 1243.9 | 1486.8 | 2083.3 |
Share capital | 452 | 452 | 509 | 527 |
Reserves | 170.3 | 177.7 | 213.4 | 261.3 |
Assets/Equity | 7.19 | 8.68 | 10.31 | 10.86 |
Provincial banks | ||||
N | 75 | 80 | 79 | 74 |
Total assets | 1543 | 2197.4 | 3275.4 | 3569.6 |
Stock market credit | 33.7 | 43.6 | 198.3 | 107.2 |
Promissory notes | 287.3 | 362.8 | 408 | 461.3 |
Share capital | 281.1 | 318.8 | 367.7 | 395.5 |
Reserves | 58 | 77.5 | 101.7 | 106.4 |
Assets/Equity | 4.55 | 5.54 | 6.98 | 7.11 |
Table 2: Berlin banks' balance sheets.
This table provides an overview of various bank balance sheet variables at different points in time. The table reports on the asset side the stock of promissory notes, the value of the stock portfolio, and stock market credit. On the liabilities side, share capital is reported. Liquidity is the ratio of short-term assets over short-term liabilities. All variables are in Million RM.30.4.1925 | 30.4.1927 | 30.6.1927 | Change (in percent) 30.4.25-30.4.27 | Change (in percent) 30.4.27-30.6.27 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Deutsche Bank Promissory notes | 320.76 | 410.38 | 167.52 | 27.94 | -59.18 |
Deutsche Bank Stock portfolio | 12.88 | 28.88 | 26.95 | 124.22 | -6.68 |
Deutsche Bank Stock market credit | 3.03 | 198.7 | 131.41 | 6457.76 | -33.87 |
Deutsche Bank Share capital | 150 | 150 | 150 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
Deutsche Bank Liquidity | 0.039 | 0.045 | 0.047 | 16.34 | 4.92 |
Disconto Gesellschaft Promissory notes | 149.56 | 248 | 275.06 | 65.82 | 10.91 |
Disconto Gesellschaft Stock portfolio | 5.18 | 10 | 10.22 | 93.05 | 2.20 |
Disconto Gesellschaft Stock market credit | 0.73 | 113.68 | 66.43 | 15472.60 | -41.56 |
Disconto Gesellschaft Share capital | 100 | 135 | 135 | 35.00 | 0.00 |
Disconto Gesellschaft Liquidity | 0.020 | 0.038 | 0.034 | 92.03 | -10.80 |
Dresdner Bank Promissory notes | 198.39 | 291.52 | 262.8 | 46.94 | -9.85 |
Dresdner Bank Stock portfolio | 12.36 | 26.09 | 25.47 | 111.08 | -2.38 |
Dresdner Bank Stock market credit | 13.22 | 171.1 | 115.12 | 1194.25 | -32.72 |
Dresdner Bank Share capital | 78 | 100 | 100 | 28.21 | 0.00 |
Dresdner Bank Liquidity | 0.032 | 0.020 | 0.036 | -37.42 | 79.63 |
Danatbank Promissory notes | 203.8 | 268.15 | 270.94 | 31.58 | 1.04 |
Danatbank Stock portfolio | 18.24 | 19.64 | 22.13 | 7.68 | 12.68 |
Danatbank Stock market credit | 16.55 | 182.89 | 123.8 | 1005.08 | -32.31 |
Danatbank Share capital | 60 | 60 | 60 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
Commerzbank Promissory notes | 106.33 | 169.34 | 165.9 | 59.26 | -2.03 |
Commerzbank Stock portfolio | 14.91 | 15.83 | 15.42 | 6.17 | -2.59 |
Commerzbank Stock market credit | 27.56 | 155.68 | 131.35 | 464.88 | -15.63 |
Commerzbank Share capital | 42 | 60 | 60 | 42.86 | 0.00 |
Commerzbank Liquidity | 0.030 | 0.018 | 0.038 | -38.16 | 106.37 |
Table 3: Descriptive statistics (Full sample).
This table provides descriptive statistics related to firms' share capital. For the total sample as well as for each share capital quartile the table provides the mean, the standard deviation, and the median capital. The table also states the mean number of large underwriters for the total sample as well as for each size quartile. All variables are in Million RM.Total | 1st Size quartile | 2nd Size quartile | 3rd Size quartile | 4th Size quartile | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Share capital, Mean | 31.88 | 1.33 | 4.57 | 13.85 | 108.63 |
Share capital, St.Dev. | 114.19 | 0.50 | 1.64 | 4.95 | 213.23 |
Share capital, Median | 7.50 | 1.30 | 4.32 | 12.68 | 50.00 |
No. of underwriter, Mean | 1.41 | 0.97 | 1.22 | 1.44 | 2.00 |
N | 145 | 37 | 36 | 36 | 36 |
Table 4: Descriptive statistics (Single underwriter sample).
This table provides the mean and median share capital and its standard deviation for firms within a bank-specific portfolio. A firm is connected to a bank if the bank is the single underwriter. All variables are in Million RM.Share capital | (1) BHG | (2) Commerz | (3) Deutsche | (4) Diskonto | (5) Danat | (6) Dresdner |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | 11.95 | 15.72 | 16.01 | 13.79 | 19.82 | 15.42 |
Stan.Dev. | 11.91 | 24.25 | 21.64 | 14.74 | 26.54 | 33.86 |
Median | 9.20 | 2.50 | 7.50 | 7.55 | 7.50 | 6.00 |
N | 3 | 13 | 27 | 16 | 19 | 21 |
Table 5: Summary statistics before and after margin call.
This table provides summary statistics of the main variables. The variables are differentiated along two dimensions: Whether a firm is connected to a large Berlin bank (Large bank) or not (No large bank) and whether the period is before or after the margin call. The period before the margin call is from February until 12 May, the period after the margin call is from 13 May until 28 June. The statistics provided are mean daily returns, the standard deviation of daily returns within the large bank or non-large bank sample during the given period, mean volatility (where firm-specific volatility is measured as the variance of returns in a 5 day rolling window), mean supply order book imbalances (Excess supply), and mean demand order book imbalances (Excess demand).Before margin call | After margin call | |
---|---|---|
Returns Large bank | -0.0005 | -0.0037 |
Returns No large bank | -0.0029 | -0.0055 |
St.Dev Large bank | 0.026 | 0.041 |
St.Dev No large bank | 0.028 | 0.032 |
Volatility Large bank | 0.00072 | 0.00138 |
Volatility No large bank | 0.00068 | 0.00056 |
Excess Supply Large bank | 0.13 | 0.12 |
Excess Supply No large bank | 0.12 | 0.1 |
Excess Demand Large bank | 0.36 | 0.3 |
Excess Demand No large bank | 0.43 | 0.26 |
Table 6: Baseline regression: Variance and returns.
This table provides the results for the following regression: $$ y_{it}=\beta (Bank_i*May_t)+\gamma_{it}+\epsilon_{it}$$ , where yit is the value of the dependent variable for firm i at time t. Banki is a dummy that is 1 if firm i is connected to a large Berlin bank and 0 otherwise, Mayt is a dummy that is 1 after the margin call at 12 May (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927), and $$ \gamma_{it}$$ is a vector of firm and time dummies. The dependent variables are the return variance calculated as the variance of returns in a 5 day rolling window in columns 1 and 2, and daily returns in columns 3 and 4. Robust standard errors are reported.(1) Variance | (2) Variance | (3) Returns | (4) Returns | |
---|---|---|---|---|
May*Bank | 0.000778*** | 0.000684*** | -0.000620 | -0.00141 |
(0.000103) | (0.0000963) | (0.00321) | (0.00314) | |
May | -0.000117 | -0.00260 | ||
(0.0000880) | (0.00310) | |||
Bank | 0.0000442 | 0.00236 | ||
(0.0000628) | (0.00174) | |||
Constant | 0.000681*** | 0.00120*** | -0.00292* | 0.0127** |
(0.0000591) | (0.000256) | (0.00170) | (0.00566) | |
Firm FE | No | Yes | No | Yes |
Time FE | No | Yes | No | Yes |
N | 11273 | 11273 | 9107 | 9107 |
R2 | 0.020 | 0.230 | 0.002 | 0.277 |
Table 7: Baseline regression: Order book imbalances.
This table provides the results for the following regression: $$ y_{it}=\beta (Bank_i*May_t)+\gamma_{it}+\epsilon_{it}$$ , where yit is the value of the dependent variable for firm i at time t. Banki is a dummy that is 1 if firm i is connected to a large Berlin bank and 0 otherwise, Mayt is a dummy that is 1 after the margin call at 12 May (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927), and $$ \gamma_{it}$$ is a vector of firm and time dummies. The dependent variables are a dummy that is 1 if excess supply existed and 0 otherwise (columns 1 and 2), and a dummy that is 1 if excess demand existed and 0 otherwise (columns 3 and 4). Robust standard errors are reported.(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
ExcSupply | ExcSupply | ExcDemand | ExcDemand | ExcDemand | |
May*Bank | 0.0101 | 0.0101 | 0.108*** | 0.108*** | -0.00137 |
(0.0239) | (0.0230) | (0.0357) | (0.0334) | (0.0765) | |
May | -0.0214 | -0.168*** | |||
(0.0228) | (0.0343) | ||||
Bank | 0.0161 | -0.0694*** | |||
(0.0176) | (0.0266) | ||||
Constant | 0.120*** | 0.0704 | 0.433*** | -0.0756 | -0.0146 |
(0.0168) | (0.0527) | (0.0256) | (0.0586) | (0.0955) | |
Firm FE | No | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Time FE | No | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
N | 9996 | 9996 | 9996 | 9996 | 9860 |
R2 | 0.001 | 0.126 | 0.006 | 0.214 | 0.229 |
Table 8: Firm size and number of underwriters.
This table provides the results for the following regression: $$ y_{it}=\beta May_p*Charac_i+\gamma_{ipt}+\epsilon_{it}$$ where yit is the return of stock i at day t or return volatility measured over the period t-5 to t. Mayp is a dummy that is 1 after 12 May 1927 (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927) and $$ \gamma$$ is a vector of controls that includes firm dummies and a constant. Characi describes a firm characteristic. This variable is either a dummy for each firm size quartile (Size 1,2,3,4) or a vector of dummies whether firm i has 0, 1, or more large underwriters (1UW, 2+UW).Returns | Returns | Returns | Volatility | Volatility | Volatility | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
May*Size 2 | 0.000979 | 0.00129 | 0.000225 | 0.000170 | ||
(0.00145) | (0.00160) | (0.000240) | (0.000258) | |||
May*Size 3 | 0.00141 | 0.00167 | 0.00112*** | 0.00106*** | ||
(0.00156) | (0.00167) | (0.000365) | (0.000378) | |||
May*Size 4 | 0.00248* | 0.00264* | 0.000779*** | 0.000689*** | ||
(0.00141) | (0.00154) | (0.000242) | (0.000257) | |||
May* 1 UW | -0.00185 | -0.00258 | 0.000601*** | 0.000304 | ||
(0.00176) | (0.00196) | (0.000165) | (0.000230) | |||
May*2+ UW | -0.000232 | -0.00138 | 0.000909*** | 0.000512** | ||
(0.00172) | (0.00185) | (0.000177) | (0.000249) | |||
Constant | -0.0234*** | -0.0268*** | -0.0243*** | 0.00179*** | 0.000980*** | 0.00249*** |
(0.00293) | (0.00241) | (0.00297) | (0.000268) | (0.000227) | (0.000278) | |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Time FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 8970 | 9107 | 8970 | 11106 | 11273 | 11106 |
R2 | 0.276 | 0.277 | 0.277 | 0.236 | 0.230 | 0.237 |
Table 9: Bank-specific regressions: Returns and volatility.
This table provides the results for estimating the regression $$ y_{ibt}=\beta May_t+\alpha+\epsilon_{ibt}$$ , where yibt is the daily stock return of stock i connected to bank b at day t in the upper panel of the table. In the lower panel the dependent variable is return volatility measured as average firm-specific return variance (5 day rolling window). May is a dummy that is 1 after 12 May (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927). The regression is estimated for each bank-portfolio b separately. Standardized coefficients are reported.(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Commerz | Deutsche | Diskonto | Danat | Dresdner | |
Returns, May | -0.039 | -0.057** | -0.011 | -0.054 | -0.027 |
(0.00253) | (0.00187) | (0.00230) | (0.00200) | (0.00191) | |
N | 968 | 2026 | 1003 | 1307 | 1665 |
R2 | 0.010 | 0.025 | 0.010 | 0.010 | 0.023 |
Variance, May | 0.036* | 0.161*** | 0.174*** | 0.147*** | 0.106*** |
(0.000133) | (0.000164) | (0.0000898) | (0.0000852) | (0.000103) | |
N | 1174 | 2451 | 1248 | 1597 | 2011 |
R2 | 0.174 | 0.109 | 0.144 | 0.109 | 0.142 |
Table 10: Credit and stock prices.
This table provides the results for the regression $$ y_{ibt}=\beta_1 CredMeasure_{bs}+\beta_2 CredMeasure_{bs}*May_p+\gamma_{ibt}$$ , where yibt is the return of stock i connected to bank b at day t (columns 1 and 2) or return variance (columns 3 and 4). Mayp is a dummy that is 1 after 12 May (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927). The variable CredMeasurebs is the level of margin lending by bank b during the bi-monthly period s in columns 1 and 3 and the absolute change of credit in columns 2 and 4. Robust standard errors are reported.(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Returns | Returns | Volatility | Volatility | |
Credit | 0.0000234 | -0.0000145*** | ||
(0.0000508) | (0.00000353) | |||
May*Credit | -0.0000497 | 0.00000119 | ||
(0.0000344) | (0.00000195) | |||
Credit Change | -0.0000116 | 0.00000517 | ||
(0.0000867) | (0.00000603) | |||
May*(Credit Change) | 0.0000743 | -0.0000192*** | ||
(0.0000832) | (0.00000629) | |||
Constant | -0.0220*** | -0.0205*** | 0.00272*** | 0.00105*** |
(0.00498) | (0.00629) | (0.000498) | (0.000236) | |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Time FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 6969 | 6969 | 8481 | 8481 |
R2 | 0.247 | 0.247 | 0.210 | 0.210 |
Table 11: Order book imbalances.
This table provides the frequency of order book imbalances. Order book imbalances are measured by the price tags quoted in the official stock price list.Bank | Exc.supply Before 12 May | Exc.supply After 12 May | Exc.Demand Before 12 May | Exc.Demand After 12 May |
---|---|---|---|---|
Commerz | 0.13 | 0.12 | 0.25 | 0.31 |
Deutsche | 0.12 | 0.21 | 0.40 | 0.31 |
Diskonto | 0.13 | 0.11 | 0.31 | 0.36 |
Danat | 0.11 | 0.14 | 0.28 | 0.31 |
Dresdner | 0.13 | 0.12 | 0.33 | 0.36 |
Table 12: Credit and order book imbalances.
This table provides the results for the regression $$ y_{ibt}=\beta_1 CredMeasure_{bs}+\beta_2 CredMeasure_{bs}*May_p+\gamma_{ibt}$$ , where yibt is excess supply or excess demand of stock i connected to bank b at day t. Mayp is a dummy that is 1 after 12 May (13 May 1927-30 July 1927) and 0 before (1 February 1927-12 May 1927). The variable CredMeasurebs is the level of margin lending by bank b during the bi-monthly period s in columns 1 and 3 and the absolute change of credit in columns 2 and 4. Robust standard errors are reported.(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
ExcSupply | ExcSupply | ExcDemand | ExcDemand | |
Credit | -0.00160*** | 0.00291*** | ||
(0.000431) | (0.000552) | |||
May*Credit | 0.000969*** | -0.000951** | ||
(0.000303) | (0.000401) | |||
Credit Change | -0.000490 | 0.00261** | ||
(0.000864) | (0.00114) | |||
May*(Credit Change) | -0.00207*** | 0.00158 | ||
(0.000763) | (0.000979) | |||
Constant | 0.269*** | -0.00340 | 0.186* | 0.676*** |
(0.0826) | (0.0352) | (0.109) | (0.0585) | |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Time FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 10584 | 10584 | 10584 | 10584 |
R2 | 0.099 | 0.099 | 0.216 | 0.215 |
Table 13: IV results.
This table provides the results for the second stage regression $$ y_{ibs}=\beta_1 abs.CreditChange_{bs}+\beta_2 abs.CreditChange_{bs}*May_s+\gamma_{ibs}$$ , where yibs is the daily return of stock i connected to bank b during the bi-monthly period s (column 1) or return volatility (column 2). Mayp is a dummy that is 1 for May and June. The variable $$ abs.CreditChange_{bs}$$ is instrumented by $$ Prom.notes_{b,s-1}$$ , which is the level of promissory notes of bank b during the previous period. The interaction term $$ abs.CreditChange_{bs}*May_s$$ is instrumented by $$ Prom.notes_{b,s-1}*May_s$$ . The instruments are relevant and the first-stage t-statistics are 9.68 and -21.21, respectively.(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Returns | Volatility | |
abs.CreditChange | -0.0000461 | 0.0000916* |
(0.000276) | (0.0000535) | |
May*(abs.CreditChange) | 0.0000622 | -0.0000832** |
(0.000210) | (0.0000393) | |
Constant | 0.00181 | 0.00108 |
(0.00844) | (0.000829) | |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes |
Balancedate FE | Yes | Yes |
N | 267 | 264 |
R2 | 0.611 | 0.550 |
Figure 1: Returns and volatility.
This figure plots stock price indices and return volatility for two groups of firms. The "Non large banks" group is composed of firms that do not have a connection to a large Berlin bank. The "large bank" group is composed of firms that have a connection to at least one large Berlin bank. All stock price indices are normalized to 100 at 12 May 1927. Volatility is calculated as the average firm-specific return variance using a 5 day rolling window.
Figure 2: Stock market credit and the overall stock market.
This figure plots a stock market index and the overall position of banks' margin lending between January 1925 and January 1928. The vertical line represents 12 May 1927. The aggregate data are taken from the statistical yearbooks of the German Reich.
Figure 3: Berlin banks and province banks.
This figure plots the ratio of assets over equity and the level of margin lending for two groups of banks, the Berlin banks and province banks. The left panel shows the ratio of assets over equity for both groups. The right panel shows the level of margin lending by both groups.
Figure 4: Leverage and margin lending by Berlin banks.
This figure plots the ratio of assets over equity and the level of margin lending each of the Berlin banks. The left panel shows the ratio of assets over equity for each bank. The right panel shows the level of margin lending by each bank.
Figure 5: The Reichsbank's promissory notes portfolio.
This figure plots the evolution of the promissory notes held by the Reichsbank between January 1926 and July 1928. The vertical line marks 12 May 1927. No data are available between November 1927 and March 1928. The data are taken from the statistical yearbooks of the German Reich.
Figure 6: The Reichsbank's foreign exchange.
This graph shows the evolution of the foreign exchange in the hands of the Reichsbank as stated in the Reichsbank's balance sheets. The vertical line marks 12 May 1927. No data are available between November 1927 and March 1928. The data are taken from the statistical yearbooks of the German Reich.
Figure 7: Differences by size.
This figure plots stock price indices and return volatility for firm size quartiles. Firm size is measured by share capital. All stock price indices are normalized to 100 at 12 May 1927. Volatility is calculated as the average firm-specific return variance using a 5 day rolling window.
Figure 8: Differnces by number of underwriters.
This figure plots stock price indices and return volatility for different number of large underwriter banks. The index of underwriter banks is 0 if a firm has no large underwriter, 1 if it has one large underwriter, or 2 if it has two or more large underwriters. All stock price indices are normalized to 100 at 12 May 1927. Volatility is calculated as the average firm-specific return variance using a 5 day rolling window.