Abstract:
0section
To support the economic recovery from the Great Recession, the Federal Reserve held the federal funds rate near zero for over seven years and acquired large holdings of longer-term securities. Despite these extraordinary measures, real GDP has grown at only a modest pace during the recovery. Meanwhile, long-term interest rates have declined whereas measures of longer-term inflation expectations have been relatively stable, resulting in lower real long-term interest rates, as shown in Figure 1. Some observers, such as Rogoff (2015), trace these developments to persistent, but ultimately transitory, debt deleveraging and borrowing headwinds in the wake of the global financial crisis. Others, like Summers (2014) and Eggertsson & Mehrotra (2014), see these developments as symptomatic of "secular stagnation," by which a confluence of changes in the structure or functioning of the economy is leading to weak GDP growth and low interest rates of an enduring rather than cyclical nature.1 Commentators and policymakers have described this combination of low growth and low interest rates as a "new normal" for the U.S..2 This paper seeks to understand how much of the new normal can be explained by demographic factors in the United States.
The United States, like other advanced economies, is undergoing a dramatic demographic transition related to the unfolding of the post-war baby boom.3 As a consequence, the growth rate of the labor force has declined and should remain low for the foreseeable future.4 In this paper, we investigate the extent to which demographic changes, especially those related to the baby boom, can explain the currently low levels of real interest rates and GDP growth. We build an overlapping generation (OG) model that is consistent with observed and projected changes in fertility, labor supply, life expectancy, family composition, and international migration. The model allows us to explore the extent to which demographic changes, in and of themselves, can explain the timing and magnitude of movements in real interest rates and real GDP growth during the post-war period and beyond. Because we are interested in longer-term trends, we do not attempt to model business cycle variation, abstract from nominal rigidities, and posit that factor markets are perfectly competitive. We also assume no intentional bequest motives for our households; without such motives, the finite lifespan of households allows demographic transitions to influence real interest rates. By contrast, in the standard real business cycle (RBC) model in which households have infinite planning horizons, demographic transitions may have no such effect on real interest rates.
We find that demographic factors alone can account for a $$ 1\frac{1}{4}$$ -percentage-point decline in the equilibrium real interest rate in the model since 1980--much, if not all, of the permanent decline in real interest rates over that period according to some recent time-series estimates, such as Johannsen & Mertens (2016b) and Holston et al. (2016). The model is also consistent with demographics having lowered real GDP growth $$ 1\frac{1}{4}$$ percentage points since 1980, primarily through lower growth in the labor supply; this decline is in line with changes in estimates of the trend of GDP growth over that period. Interestingly, the model also implies that these declines have been most pronounced since the early 2000s, so that downward pressures on interest rates and GDP growth due to demographics could be easily misinterpreted as persistent but ultimately temporary influences of the global financial crisis. When we enrich our model with total factor productivity (TFP) growth consistent with the observed historical trend, the predicted declines in GDP growth and the equilibrium real rate between 1980 and the present are essentially unchanged but the pace at which the economy has been transitioning to the new normal over the past decade is more dramatic.
In the model, the dynamics of interest rates and GDP growth are most directly connected to the consequences of the post-war baby boom. As the baby-boom generation reached working age in the 1960s, the aggregate labor supply, GDP growth, and interest rates all increased. The abundance of labor was accentuated by the fact that the baby boomers had far fewer children than their parents did, leading the United States to reap a "demographic dividend" by which the number of workers relative to the number of dependents climbed to historically high levels by the turn of the 21st century. The demographic situation stimulated aggregate capital formation as members of an unusually large cohort with few dependents simultaneously supplied labor and aimed to save ahead of retirement. The low fertility rates of the baby-boom generation also supported the accumulation of capital by facilitating greater labor-force participation of women and by freeing resources that families would have otherwise allocated to consumption by children. Furthermore, steady gains in health and life expectancy have increased the amount of time households expect to spend in retirement, in turn boosting their desire to save. The baby-boom generation has since begun to retire and the growth rates of the aggregate labor supply and aggregate output have accordingly slowed. From our model's perspective, these factors have led to a current abundance of capital relative to labor, depressing the return on capital and also causing aggregate investment to decline, a phenomenon that we see as consistent with puzzlingly low rates of capital investment in the recovery from the global financial crisis. Going forward, the model predicts that the capital-labor ratio will remain elevated despite low rates of aggregate investment in capital because the growth rate of the labor supply will also be low, so that both real interest rates and GDP growth will linger near their current low levels.
One remarkable feature of our model is that the macroeconomic effects of the demographic transition have been largely predictable. In making this point, we use the model to show that the most consequential demographic changes for interest rates and GDP growth today took place before the 1980s. Had demographic variables held constant at their 1960 levels, both real interest rates and GDP growth today would be similar to their levels in 1980. In sharp contrast, had demographic variables held constant at their 1980 levels, the declines in the equilibrium real rate and real GDP growth would have been largely as predicted under the baseline calibration of the demographic variables. We also use these simulations to parse out the relative contributions of each of the demographic factors to those declines. In the case of real GDP growth, the sharp drop in fertility rates in the 1960s and 1970s, which ultimately led to a slowing in the growth rate of the labor supply, is the predominant contributor to the decline since 1980. In the case of real interest rates, we find that falling fertility rates and increased employment rates in the 1960s and 1970s have each contributed ½ percentage point to the decline in the equilibrium real rate between 1980 and the present, with longer life expectancies accounting for the residual. Taken together, these and our earlier results show that demographic factors tend to reinforce each other in the transition to a new normal for the U.S..
In an earlier contribution, Krueger & Ludwig (2007) use an OG model to explore the consequences of demographic transition in advanced economies for capital accumulation and rates of return from 2005 to 2080. Our study focuses on the United States and traces the extent to which historical demographic changes can account for both past and future changes in interest rates and GDP growth as well as a seemingly rapid transition to the new normal. Our results also complement those of Ikeda & Saito (2014) for Japan and Carvalho et al. (2016) for the OECD. These studies focus on the distinction between working-age adults and retired adults, and show that a rise in the proportion of retired adults lowers real interest rates. Our model is richer, taking into account differences in demographic characteristics over the life time and across birth cohorts. We argue that the consideration of a rich model matters for obtaining reliable empirical estimates of the size and timing of the macroeconomic effects of demographics. In particular, the model of Carvalho et al. (2016) predicts a sharp decline in the equilibrium real interest rate in the 1990s driven by increased life expectancy, which we show, within the context of our larger model, has had relatively little effect on interest rates over the past several decades.
The paper is organized as follows. Section section presents our model economy. Section section details the demographic data and other parameters of our calibration, as well as our approach to computing the model's dynamic general equilibrium. Section section shows the main results under our baseline calibration and gauges the relative importance of demographic factors through the consideration of a number of alternative scenarios. Section section offers a series of robustness checks and observations pertaining to our choice of a technology growth process, the elasticity of substitution in production, the role of dependents in household preferences, and open-economy considerations. Finally, section section concludes.
Our OG model borrows from the vast literature exploring the long-run fiscal and macroeconomic implications of demographic transitions and social security programs. See, among many related contributions, Yaari (1965), Fehr et al. (2003), or, more recently, Reichling & Smetters (2015). The economy is comprised of households and representative firms. Households are headed by adults who are representative of their birth cohort in terms of life-cycle characteristics. Each period, these adults inelastically supply their labor endowment, which varies over the life cycle. Additionally, these adults decide how much they and their children who have yet to reach adulthood consume, and how much capital to save for retirement. Representative firms operate a constant returns to scale production technology that uses capital and labor inputs. Given our focus on low-frequency dynamics, we abstract from business cycle shocks and aggregate uncertainty. Instead, we assume that adults and firms have perfect foresight with respect to aggregate and demographic variables, and that they face no idiosyncratic risk besides the uninsurable risk of death. The timing of events is as follows: At the beginning of each period, children are born with no capital holdings according to fertility rates that depend on the age and birth cohort of the adults. After children are born, some household members die, with probabilities conditional on age and birth cohort, and orphans are redistributed among surviving adults belonging to the same cohort as the deceased parent. The capital held by dead adults is then uniformly redistributed to surviving adults. Finally, surviving adults make their consumption/saving decisions and firms produce.
We assume that adults derive utility from their children's consumption as in the recent work of Curtis et al. (2015a) and Curtis et al. (2015b). Consider a cohort-representative adult aged a in period t. This adult maximizes
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\left(\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}+\epsilon\left(n_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{\eta}\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}^{c}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}\right),$$ | (1) |
Our specification implies that adults derive utility only in periods in which they are alive and that they have no intentional bequest motive. The probability that an adult aged a in period t survives through the end of the next s periods is given by the cohort-specific function $$ \Gamma_{a,t,t+s}$$ . We assume that no adult survives past some finite length of life, A. Households face the following sequence of budget constraints
$$\displaystyle C_{a+s,t+s}+n_{a+s,t+s}C_{a+s,t+s}^{c}+K_{a+s+1,t+s+1}=\left(K_{a+s,t+s}+\phi\Xi_{t+s}\right)\left(R_{t+s}^{K}+1-\delta\right)+e_{a+s,t+s}W_{t+s}.$$ | (2) |
Adults optimally choose consumption per dependent child be proportional to their own consumption so that
$$\displaystyle \frac{C_{a+s,t+s}^{c}}{C_{a+s,t+s}}=\left(\epsilon n_{a+s,t+s}^{\eta-1}\right)^{\frac{1}{\nu}}.$$ | (3) |
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\kappa_{a+s,t+s}\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu},$$ | (4) |
$$\displaystyle \kappa_{a+s,t+s}\equiv\left(1+\epsilon^{\frac{1}{\nu}}\left(n_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{1+\frac{\eta-1}{\nu}}\right).$$ | (5) |
$$\displaystyle \left(\frac{C_{a+1,t+1}^{h}}{C_{a,t}^{h}}\right)^{\nu}=\beta\Gamma_{a,t,t+1}\frac{\kappa_{a+1,t+1}}{\kappa_{a,t}}\left(1+R_{t+1}^{K}-\delta\right).$$ | (6) |
Equation (22) illustrates how life-cycle elements affect the consumption and saving decisions of the household. The effective discount factor of adults depends on the usual discount factor, $$ \beta$$ , adjusted by the probability of surviving to enjoy consumption in the next period, $$ \Gamma_{a,t,t+1}$$ . In the absence of a bequest motive, adults therefore become increasingly impatient as they approach the end of their lives and the probability of dying rises. To the extent that the probability of surviving is close to 1 in the early decades of adulthood, consumption growth is fairly steady because the young are relatively patient.5 The term $$ \kappa_{a+1,t+1}/\kappa_{a,t}$$ , is increasing with the projected increase in family size, making the household act as if it were relatively patient. As an illustration, consider a situation in which the number of children is projected to increase between the current and next periods. In this case, the household would like to transfer resources to the next period, so as to smooth adult consumption and to provide for a larger number of dependent children. This mechanism helps produce hump-shaped consumption profiles over the life cycle of a typical household with dependent children. Thus, as was the case with mortality, changes in family size over time enter the household decision directly through their effects on the effective rate at which households discount future household consumption.
The representative firm rents capital and labor inputs in perfectly competitive factor markets. It uses those factors in a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) production function to produce final output, Yt. The functional form of the production technology is given by
$$\displaystyle Y_{t}=\left(\alpha\left(K_{t}\right)^{\rho}+\left(1-\alpha\right)\left(Z_{t}L_{t}\right)^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{1}{\rho}},$$ | (7) |
$$\displaystyle \left(\alpha\left(K_{t}\right)^{\rho}+\left(1-\alpha\right)\left(Z_{t}L_{t}\right)^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{1}{\rho}}-L_{t}W_{t}-R_{t}^{K}K_{t}.$$ | (8) |
$$\displaystyle W_{t}=Z_{t}\left(1-\alpha\right)\left(\frac{Y_{t}}{Z_{t}L_{t}}\right)^{1-\rho}.$$ | (10) |
In addition to births and deaths, we allow the population to change through international migration, a feature that helps us to ensure that, in our simulations, the size and composition of the population matches official estimates and projections of the U.S..
At the beginning of each period, a measure $$ m_{a,t}$$ of individuals aged a enters the economy on net. For simplicity, we assume that these immigrants (or emigrants, if $$ m_{a,t}$$ is negative) are identical in terms of asset holdings, labor endowments, and demographic characteristics to the resident population of age a.6
Let $$ \mu_{a,t}$$ be the number of individuals aged a at the beginning of period t after accounting for net migration and births, but before deaths have occurred. Given our assumptions, this variable evolves according to $$ \mu_{a,t}=\mu_{a-1,t-1}\Gamma_{a-1,t-1}+m_{a,t}$$ for all $$ a>0$$ , and $$ \mu_{0,t}=births_{t}+m_{0,t}$$ for newborns. Equilibrium in the labor market requires that
$$\displaystyle K_{t}=\sum_{a=A_{c}+1}^{A}\mu_{a,t}\Gamma_{a,t,t+1}K_{a,t}+\phi\sum_{a=A_{c}+1}^{A}\mu_{a,t}\left(1-\Gamma_{a,t,t+1}\right)K_{a,t}.$$ | (12) |
$$\displaystyle Y_{t}=\sum_{a=A_{c}+1}^{A}\mu_{a,t}\gamma_{a,t}C_{a,t}^{h}+\sum_{a=A_{c}+1}^{A}\mu_{a,t}\left(K_{t+1,a}-\left(1-\delta\right)\left(K_{t,a}+\phi\Xi_{t}\right)\right).$$ | (13) |
We consider a perfect-foresight equilibrium such that, in each period, (a) goods and factor markets clear, (b) factor prices correspond to their marginal products, (c) the bequests received by surviving adults sum up to the capital held by adults who passed away at the beginning of the period (net of any destroyed capital), and (d) household optimality conditions are satisfied. While uncertainty may influence household decision making, we are interested in the low frequency effects of demographic changes, which are predictable far in advance. Thus, we view the perfect foresight assumption as an innocuous abstraction for the questions addressed by this paper.
We describe our solution method to find the perfect-foresight general equilibrium in the appendix. In short, we conjecture the paths of aggregate variables over the simulation period and solve the problem of the cohort-representative adults. The solution to this problem is conditional on those paths and on the household's demographic variables (namely the mortality rates, fertility rates, and labor endowments conditional on age and birth cohort), net migration, and the initial conditions at the start of the simulation period in 1900. We next compute new paths for the aggregate objects by aggregating across the individual investment, saving, and labor supply decisions of the cohort-representative adults and by imposing the first-order conditions of the representative firms. If these paths differ from our initial guesses, then we update the paths and iterate an additional time. Once we have reached numerical convergence, our search for the equilibrium stops. Because the equilibrium is conditional on an initial distribution of capital holdings and population at the start of 1900, all aggregate objects, including the equilibrium real rate, depend on these distributions. However, 1900 is sufficiently far in the past that reasonable choices of the initial distributions have little influence on equilibrium outcomes in the post-war period. The solution method is sufficiently rapid that we solve the model at a quarterly frequency.
We take as inputs to our model demographic data, as well as labor-market participation rates. In particular, we use data on mortality to calibrate $$ \Gamma_{t,t,t+a}$$ for each age-specific cohort. We use population data to calibrate the number of dependent children per adult, $$ n_{a,t}$$ , for each representative adult aged a at each time t. These data pin down the effective discount rate in Equation (22) for each household aged a at every date. Furthermore, the data on population ensure that the correct proportions of old and young households obtain at every point in time, so that the rental rate of capital and real interest rates reflect the relative supply of savers and borrowers. Finally, we use labor market data to ensure that the supply of labor by age and over time is consistent with the data.
In this section, we describe the historical demographic data that we utilize to calibrate our model as well as the projections we utilize to calculate household expectations about the future. We also discuss the calibration of the model's parameters. A key feature of our calibration is that the economy eventually converges to a balanced growth path, which facilitates the computation of a solution. The simulation period runs from 1900 to 2400; such a long period recognizes that life-cycle decisions at any point in time take into account the evolution of factor prices and demographic variables over both the past and the next several decades.
Our individual life expectancy data are derived from mortality rate estimates and projections reported by Bell & Miller (2005) from the U.S.Security Administration. These estimates and projections cover every decade from 1900 to 2100 and are reported separately for men and women. We aggregate mortality rates by age and birth cohort across genders in proportion to the number of surviving males and females up to the period. We interpolate mortality rates conditional on age and cohort within inter-census periods and age groups using a cubic spline. In our applications, we assume that the mortality rates in 1900 prevailed in all earlier periods and, similarly, that the mortality rates in 2100 prevail in all subsequent periods.7 Figure 2 shows a dramatic drop in infant mortality in the early 20th century, along with a realized and projected steady increase in adult life expectancy. The most dramatic gains in life expectancy were apparently achieved early in the 20th century.
To determine family composition over time, we combine our data on mortality rates with data on the number of live births, female fertility, and yearly infant population estimates. Data on live births are published by the National Center for Health Statistics (NCHS) starting in 1972.8 Prior to that year, we construct live birth estimates by adjusting infant population estimates from the Census Bureau for mortality. We note that, in recent decades, yearly observations from the NCHS series essentially coincide with corresponding five-year data from the United Nations' World Population Prospects (WPP): 2015 Revision. We use the WPP data, which extend through 2100, to construct birth-rate estimates beyond 2014. Of note, by the end of the current century, the WPP data project that live birth rates have essentially stabilized. Using this observation, we impose that the number of live births is constant from 2100 onward. Further details regarding the construction of fertility rates are available in our appendix.
We obtain a measure of the number of dependent children per representative adult in two steps. We first estimate the number of births per mother of a given age. The main data source is a set of fertility tables published by Hamilton & Cosgrove (2010) from the Center for Disease Control (CDC). The tables provide estimates of the number of live births in each calendar year conditional on the age (in years) of the mother. We then adjust the age of the mother by an estimate of the age difference between married men and women to obtain the age of the representative parent. This adjustment is based on our interpolation of historical information on the median ages of men and women at time of their first marriage published by the Census Bureau. The data are available from 1890 through 2015. Figure 4 shows that the median age gap between men and women has been somewhat stable over the past several decades, at between 1.5 and 2.5 years. In our application, we assume that the average age difference observed in recent years will prevail beyond 2015. We then fit a polynomial to the historical and projected values to obtain a smooth series.
A question arises with teen pregnancies because young parents may still be dependent children themselves. In the absence of detailed information, we follow a somewhat simple procedure. Whenever a child is born to a representative parent whose average age is less than 18 years old, we temporarily allocate the child to her representative grandparent until the representative parent turns 18 years old, at which point the representative parent becomes fully responsible for her child's consumption.
With all of the above fertility data we can allocate children at the end of 1899 to their parents and calculate the average number of dependents entering the parents' consumption function. Figure 5 shows the share of births by age of the mother. We then iteratively calculate the population and family structure over the full sample period by letting the population evolve according to births, deaths, and net migration. Finally, we note that our procedure works only with averages rather than actual family cells. For example, deaths of adults and children do not result in discrete jumps in the number of surviving parents or dependents. Figure 6 shows the average number of dependent children by the age of their parents for a number of birth cohorts.
Throughout the paper, we assume that adults aged 18 years or more make all life-cycle decisions for themselves and their dependents. Once a child turns 18 years old, he or she begins life as a decision-maker.
We calibrate the labor endowments of adults in the model using data on the employment-population ratios (EPRs) by age groups published by the BLS since 1948. We complement these data with a forecast of the EPRs for 2024 based on sectoral employment projections published by the BLS. Given that we do not model labor force participation, we interchangeably refer to the EPRs as the "employment rates," although our EPR measures do not correspond to official employment rates, which are conditional on labor force participation and thus less suited for measuring the aggregate labor supply. We assume that employment rates by age before 1948 and after 2024 correspond to the employment rates by age in those years. Cyclical fluctuations in employment rates are evident in the raw data; given our focus on explaining longer-term trends in interest rates and GDP growth, we use filtered versions of the published series that strip out these movements.9 We set the employment rates of people aged less than 18 years to zero so as to conform with the model's treatment of dependent children.
Figure 7 shows our fitted employment rates by age. A few patterns are apparent. Most notably, employment rates have risen overall since the 1950s, a consequence of women participating in the labor force in greater numbers so as to more than offset corresponding declines in male employment. The employment rates rise steeply over an individual's late teens and early 20s, but then plateau for the next few decades. Some dynamics are also apparent around the time of retirement. In the early 1960s, workers typically remained active in the labor market until later in life than in the subsequent decades. The employment rates of older workers initially declined for a couple of decades, a tendency that subsequently reversed. Our projections are consistent with a continuation of the trend toward increased participation of older workers in the labor force in the coming decade.10
Most of the remaining parameters of the model pertain to the representative adult's utility function and to the representative firm's production function. We set the elasticity of substitution in the utility function to unity ($$ \nu=1$$ ). We follow Curtis et al. (2015b,a) in setting $$ \eta=0.76$$ and $$ \epsilon=0.65$$ to relate the consumption of adults with that of their dependent children. When we consider a version of the model without dependent children, we set $$ \epsilon=0$$ . In our baseline model, we set the elasticity of substitution in the production function to 1, so that the function is of the Cobb-Douglas form, and set the share of capital, $$ \alpha$$ , to 0.35. We also set $$ \phi=1$$ so that no capital is destroyed in the inheritance process.
To isolate the effects of demographic factors on the aggregate objects of interest, our baseline calibration features no technology growth (that is, $$ Z_{t}/Z_{t-1}=1$$ ). In some simulations, we will augment the model with a TFP series matching low-frequency movements in productivity growth to refine our analysis of the transition to the new normal. Our main TFP data source is an updated version of the data from Fernald (2014), whose data sample runs from 1947:Q2 to 2016:Q1. Before 1947, we assume that TFP grew at an annual rate of 2 percent, which is in the middle of the range of estimates surveyed by Shackleton (2013). After 2016, we assume that TFP is growing at a rate of 1.1 percent, which is consistent with the projections of Gordon (2015). As with employment rates, we filter our TFP series so as to strip out cyclical fluctuations.11
The last parameter that we need to pin down is the household's discount factor, $$ \beta$$ . We calibrate this parameter such that the average level in the 1980s of the real short-term interest rate in the model--which we refer to as the equilibrium real rate--matches the average point estimate of the real interest rate expected in the long run calculated by Johannsen & Mertens (2016b) for that decade. We compare the model's path for the short-term real interest rate to the estimate from Johannsen & Mertens (2016a) of the real interest rate expected in the long run. We see these authors' estimate as a good benchmark because, like our model, it seeks to capture low-frequency movements in real interest rates that are unrelated to business cycle developments. Moreover, the contour of the estimate accords with low-frequency movements in observed real interest rates, being low in the 1960s, somewhat higher in the 1970s and 1980s, and low again in the recent period. We will return in section section to the discussion of our benchmark for the equilibrium real rate. For now, we note that changing $$ \beta$$ shifts the level of the equilibrium real rate path in our simulations but otherwise has little effect on the contribution of demographic factors to observed changes in real interest rates and real GDP growth over time.
Our dynamic simulations track the evolution of the U.S. from 1900 to 2400. However, our discussion focuses on the implications of the U.S.transition for the recent and next few decades, especially as they relate to a possible new normal for the U.S.. One reason to discount the model results for the early decades of the 20th century is that the initialization of the simulation is subject to some uncertainty. Our sample begins only 35 years after the end of the U.S. Civil War, which saw the destruction of a substantial amount of capital and the tragic death of 2.5 percent of the population--mostly men who would have been part of the labor force.12 The first half of the 20th century also encompasses two world wars and the Great Depression, whose economic consequences are outside of our framework. The uncertainty surrounding demographic projections and future technology growth similarly grows with the time horizon. That said, knowledge of the current distribution of population, mortality rates, birth rates, and immigration rates imply that the evolution of the population over the next few decades is reasonably certain.
Figure 8 shows the model's dynamic equilibrium real rate over the 1960-2030 period under our baseline specification with dependent children. At a qualitative level, the model generates a path of the equilibrium real interest rate that resembles that of Johannsen & Mertens (2016b) over the period: The equilibrium real rate rises through most of the 1960s and 1970s, reaches a peak around 1980, and falls thereafter. Time-series estimates of the equilibrium real rate are inherently uncertain, as the band in the panel highlights. Nonetheless, we find the similarity in the timing of the rise, peak, and decline in the equilibrium real rate between these authors' estimates and our baseline estimates rather remarkable. Since 1980, Johannsen & Mertens (2016b) estimate that the long-run equilibrium real rate has fallen 3/4 percentage point, whereas our model predicts a modestly larger fall, at 1¼ percentage points. Put differently, demographic factors appear to be an economically important contributor to low-frequency movements in the equilibrium real rate, possibly explaining all of the permanent declines in real interest rates in recent decades.
As the figure shows, the results are broadly similar when we assume that children's consumption does not enter enter the household utility function, a common assumption in macroeconomic models. When dependents are ignored, the fall in the equilibrium real rate since 1980 occurs somewhat more gradually. By contrast, our model with dependent children has the steepest declines in real interest rates shortly after the year 2000, and thus predicts that the equilibrium real rate was falling especially rapidly during the Great Recession and its aftermath.
Figure 9 offers some guidance to understand the demographic forces that are driving our simulation. The top panel shows that the economy-wide employment rate increased consistently as the baby-boom generation entered the labor market, peaking about the year 2000. The bottom panel shows that the number of dependent children per adult dropped precipitously as the baby-boom generation reached the age of maturity. Additionally, the number of inactive adults relative to employed adults--a measure of the importance of older dependents--similarly reached a turning point around the year 2000 and is projected to increase in the next few decades as the baby-boom generation retires.13 In this sense, the U.S. economy has had a demographic dividend as of late, in that the number of workers relative to the total population has been historically high.
Figure 10 shows the predictions from our baseline model for real GDP growth. Our baseline model abstracts from productivity growth, yet GDP grows at different rates over time for a variety of reasons. Most importantly, movements in the total number of working-age adults and in their employment rates affect the total labor supply, and thus have direct effects on real GDP growth. Demographic factors also affect the accumulation of capital, although the corresponding contribution to movements in GDP growth is small. Our model predicts that demographic factors caused real GDP growth to rise about a percentage point from 1960 to 1980. From 1980 to 2015, the transition toward lower growth in the labor supply erased that increase: Initially, the decline was modest but picked up around the year 2000.
Figure 11 provides information about the effects of the demographic changes in our data on some economic variables. By construction, the real rental rate of capital in our model (shown in the upper-left panel) mimics movements in the equilibrium real rate. The real rental rate of capital increases as the baby-boom generation enters the labor force and capital is relatively scarce. The net saving rate follows a similar pattern as the rental rate of capital in that it peaks around 1980 and declines sharply after the year 2000. Changes in the net saving rate reflect the desire of the baby-boom generation to save for retirement. After these workers leave the labor force, they draw down their capital, depressing net saving rates. When we include dependent children in our model, the contour of the net saving rate is somewhat changed from 1980 through 2010, reflecting the resources that the baby-boom generation allocates toward its dependent children. However, these differences are small relative to the effect of retirement saving and spending by baby-boom generation. During the period in which the proportion of adults active in the labor market is at its highest, the capital-labor ratio is relatively low, even though net savings is high (as shown in the lower-left panel). The capital-labor ratio rises even as the net saving rate falls because the retirement of workers from the baby-boom generation puts downward pressure on the growth rate of the labor supply.
The real wage (measured in efficiency units, and shown in the bottom-right panel) remained low and falls through most of the 1960s and 1970s, reaching a trough in the 1980s, before steadily rising. The movements in the real wage are much smaller than the movements in the capital-labor ratio and reflect the relative scarcity of factors of production; that is, labor is relatively scarce in our model after workers in the baby-boom generation begin to retire. Even though the net saving rate is declining after the year 2000, the model predicts that the equilibrium real interest rate is falling because the capital-labor ratio is dramatically increasing. This observation cautions that simple dynamic analyses that ignore the rich variation in demographic factors and composition of the population might draw incorrect conclusions. Moreover, it suggests that demographic factors offer an explanation for puzzlingly weak business investment in the wake of the Great Recession, which some authors, such as Banerjee et al. (2015), have instead traced back to persistent uncertainty and limited investment opportunities.
To assess the respective contributions of changes in fertility, mortality, and employment rates to macroeconomic developments since 1980, we perform alternative simulations in which we freeze demographic variables from 1960 onward.14 We use the model with dependent children as our baseline model and we keep $$ \beta$$ fixed across simulations so as to isolate the effects of the demographic data.
We present the counter-factual paths of the equilibrium real rate in the top panel of Figure 12. When we keep fertility, mortality, and employment rates all fixed at their 1960 values, we see that there would have been no net decline in the equilibrium real interest rate since 1980. Put differently, the entirety of the decline in the equilibrium real interest rate that our model finds for the recent decades is a direct consequence of the demographic changes that happened from 1960 onward.
To analyze the respective contribution of each demographic factor, we consider the effects of freezing each demographic variable in turn.15 The two most consequential demographic changes are the drop in fertility rates and the increase in employment rates, which each contributes ½ percentage point to the 1¼-percentage-point decline in the equilibrium real rate between 1980 and the present. Intuitively, the demographic dividend stemming from the drop in fertility rates in the 1960s and 1970s facilitated the accumulation of capital in aggregate. Moreover, the retirement of a relatively large cohort of baby boomers has further put upward pressure on the aggregate capital-labor ratio of late, leading to a fall in the equilibrium real interest rate. Similarly, employment rates were relatively low in 1960, as we showed in Figure 7. Since that time, the number of households with two adults who participate in the labor market has increased dramatically. As such, the aggregate labor supply has increased through the latter part of the 20th century, in turn facilitating aggregate capital formation and exacerbating the deceleration in the aggregate labor supply once baby boomers began to retire.
The contribution of lower mortality rates to the fall in the equilibrium real rate since 1980 is only half as large, at ¼ percentage point, than those of the fall in fertility rates and rise in employment rates. That changes in life expectancy alone have had only a small effect on the equilibrium real interest rate over this period is perhaps unsurprising. To put these changes in mortality rates in perspective, we note that the mean life expectancy at birth conditional on the mortality rates observed at the start of 1980, at 79.6 years, was only three and half years less than the corresponding statistic based on the mortality rates prevailing in 2015. By contrast, the total gain in life expectancy over the 1900-2100 period is nearly three and a half decades. Moreover, the gains in life expectancy over the past few decades reflect primarily a fall in mortality rates during an adult's years in retirement, thus having almost no effect on the aggregate supply of labor. And with younger cohorts discounting the consumption of their older selves, the incentives to accumulate more capital during the productive years are little changed either. On net, the aggregate stock of capital rises only modestly, which is consistent with a small fall in the equilibrium real rate at the margin.16
To narrow in on the timing of the demographic changes that were most important for the decline in the equilibrium real interest rate, we do similar experiments in which we freeze demographic variables starting in 1980. These new counter-factual paths for the equilibrium real interest rate are shown in the bottom panel of Figure 12. It is clear that holding demographic variables fixed at their 1980 levels, either independently or jointly, has essentially no effect on the subsequent path of interest rates predicted by the model. The reason for this result is that, by 1980, fertility rates were close to levels that prevail even today (which can be seen in Figure 6), employment rates had increased markedly but then stabilized (which can be seen in Figure 7), and, as mentioned above, mortality rates have fallen only somewhat modestly. In sum, the subsequent decline in real interest rates due to demographic factors was mostly due to demographic changes that took place before 1980. The subsequent dynamics reflect the life cycle of those demographic changes, meaning the contours of the path of interest rates largely reflects the impact of the baby-boom generation.
Figure 13 shows that keeping employment rates or mortality rates fixed at either their 1960 or 1980 levels has little effect on the growth rate of real GDP overall. Instead, the bulk of the fall in real GDP growth of late is accounted for by declines in the aggregate labor supply related to the gradual retirement of the baby-boom generation. As can be seen from Figure 13, fixing fertility rates at their 1960 levels would have kept real GDP growth from falling. However, because fertility rates fell, our model predicts that real GDP growth initially increased as members of the baby-boom generation reached working age and then started falling in the 1980s. The model also predicts that the most dramatic declines in real GDP growth due to demographic changes happened shortly after the year 2000, again around the time that the baby-boom generation began to retire.
We add productivity growth to the model to assess its effects on the transition to the new normal for the U.S. economy. Authors such as Summers (2014), Gordon (2016), and Fernald (2016) argue that the rate of potential GDP growth in the future will be modest relative to its average over the post-war period. Changes in TFP have two direct effects in theory. First, because productivity enters the production function, GDP growth should slow if productivity growth slows. Second, real interest rates are proportional to TFP growth in a broad class of models, meaning interest rates should fall if productivity growth falls. In the standard RBC model, the real interest rate is given by
We perform a dynamic simulation of our model in which technology growth matches prominent estimates of its historical and projected trend. Our series captures relatively rapid productivity growth before the early 1970s, a slow down from the 1970s through the early 1990s, a temporary pickup associated with the information technology boom, and finally modest rates of technology growth from the early 2000s onward of the kind envisioned by Gordon (2016). See our appendix for details on the construction of our series. Consistent with our earlier approach, we assume that these developments are anticipated and calibrate the household's discount factor, $$ \beta$$ , such that the average real rate in the 1980s corresponds to the average point estimate of Johannsen & Mertens (2016b). Absent this adjustment, the introduction of positive technology growth in the model would raise the path of the equilibrium real rate compared with our baseline specification with no technology growth.17
Figure 10 shows that productivity growth shifts up the model's predicted path for GDP growth. Even though we do not use data on aggregate output, the model's predictions for real GDP growth are remarkably similar to the growth rate of the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend in actual output, also shown in Figure 10.18 It is noteworthy how our model captures the size of the decline in real GDP growth from the 1980s to the present. The reason is that, aside from some years of very high productivity growth in the 1990s, data from Fernald (2014) indicate that TFP growth was low even in the 1980s. By contrast, high levels of TFP growth in the 1960s correspond to a larger difference between our baseline calibration and our calibration with TFP growth in terms of real GDP growth. Thus, even with historical movements in TFP, our model predicts that much of the decline in real GDP growth since the 1980s is associated with demographic change.
Relative to the baseline case, the boom in productivity growth initiated in the 1990s keeps the equilibrium real rate elevated through much of the first decade of the 2000s. The equilibrium real rate only begins falling in earnest around the onset of the Great Recession, proceeding to drop almost one percentage point in the span of about 10 years to a level similar to that in our baseline simulation. Importantly, the fall in the equilibrium real rate under this scenario is largely concomitant with the global financial crisis. As such, factoring in the temporarily high productivity gains of the 1990s and early 2000s suggests a material risk that observers could confuse the persistent but ultimately temporary consequences of the financial crisis with other influences originating from the demographic transition and technology growth cycles.
Looking at the whole period shown, Figure 14 points to a rather weak connection between the equilibrium real rate and the pace of technology growth over long horizons. Notably, even though technology growth was elevated by historical standards prior to the early 1970s, and should thus have been associated with a high equilibrium real rate, realized real interest rates were quite low at the time. Accordingly, the figure features a persistently large gap between the equilibrium real rate predicted by the model and the estimates of Johannsen & Mertens (2016b) in the 1960s and 1970s.
Judging the empirical success of our model requires taking a stand on the low-frequency paths of real interest rates and the growth rate of real GDP that the model should seek to capture. We take the change in our Hodrick-Prescott filtered output series as a good estimate of the decline in GDP growth; other low-frequency filters suggest similar contours.19 By contrast, estimates of permanent changes in interest rates are much more uncertain, a point demonstrated in Kiley (2015). Rachel & Smith (2015) seek to explain a 450-basis-point fall in the neutral rate of interest over the past 30 years, a movement that is in line with the fall in real long-term rates over the period. We judge their benchmark to be much too large to reflect the influence of secular factors alone. As we showed in Figure 1, the 1980s were preceded by relatively low but positive real interest rates in the 1960s and early 1970s, and then negative real interest rates in the remainder of the 1970s as inflation picked up. The historically high real interest rates of the 1980s occurred as the Federal Reserve tightened the policy stance to rein in inflation. Unsurprisingly, the estimates of Johannsen & Mertens (2016b), which net out cyclical influences, suggest a significant but much smaller drop since the 1980s. Another reason for our discomfort with the size of the drop in the neutral rate reported by Rachel & Smith (2015) is that some of the explanatory factors in their analysis were already at play prior to the 1980s; one implication of extending the data farther back in time is that the drop in the neutral rate since, say, the 1960s would be implausibly large to us. Additionally, work by Hamilton et al. (2015) presents evidence that if the equilibrium real rate has declined, then that decline is likely smaller than the magnitude reported by Rachel & Smith (2015). Therefore, we assess that a decline in the equilibrium real interest rate of less than 2 percentage points since 1980 is most consistent with the new normal for the U.S. economy.20
Our results are subject to a number of potential caveats. A particularly important assumption we have made is that adults have no intentional bequest motive, an assumption that is standard in the OG literature. Relaxing this assumption would likely weaken the size of the decline in the equilibrium real rate since 1980 by facilitating the extent to which economic agents can engage in intertemporal substitution across generations and thus smooth the effects of the baby boom and other demographic elements. By comparison, the effects on real GDP growth would likely be modest because demographics affect the pace of output growth primarily through changes in the labor supply, which is exogenous in our environment. From an empirical perspective, the extent to which intentional bequests matter for the determination of the equilibrium level of the aggregate capital-labor ratio--and thus for equilibrium interest rates--is unclear. Intentional bequests are certainly observed in practice but often come in the form of housing, which Yang (2009) argues has different properties than capital over the life cycle due notably to large transactions costs, the impossibility of fractionating most capital held in the form of housing, and the utility that housing provides to owners. The consideration of housing is beyond the scope of our model.
Below, we consider a number of alternative scenarios to assess the sensitivity of our results to other model features. We first consider the possibility that the elasticity of substitution between factors of production is lower than we have assumed. This consideration is motivated by the central role played by the aggregate capital-labor ratio in the model for explaining movements in the equilibrium real rate, as well as by empirical evidence that the long-run elasticity of substitution is lower than implied by Cobb-Douglas production functions. We next consider an alternative specification of preferences that some authors have argued is especially successful at matching consumption/saving decisions over the life cycle. We conclude with a comparison of the U.S. and foreign demographic transitions.
So far, our analysis has focused on how demographic characteristics affect the supply of labor and capital by households in equilibrium. We now provide a sensitivity analysis of the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor in production, $$ 1/(1-\rho)$$ , which affects the demand for factors of production in equilibrium, and thus also plays a role in determining equilibrium factor prices and quantities. In particular, the dynamic of the equilibrium real rate in the model is tightly connected to that of the (technology-adjusted) capital-labor ratio. Using Equations (8) and (23), we can write the equilibrium real rate as
In this robustness check, we decrease the elasticity to 0.75 while still imposing that the parameter $$ \alpha$$ is consistent with a share of capital in aggregate income of 35 percent. We also re-calibrate the value of $$ \beta$$ such that the model's average equilibrium real rate in the 1980s matches the point estimate of Johannsen & Mertens (2016b). Figure 14 shows that lowering the elasticity of substitution accentuates the extent of the fall in the equilibrium real rate since 1980 that can be attributed to demographics. The current difference with respect to the baseline case is somewhat small, however, at about 2 tenths of a percentage point.
The predicted peak in household consumption in our baseline model occurs somewhat earlier in the life cycle than it does in the data. As an alternative, we consider a variant of Browning & Ejrnæs (2009) preferences in which total household consumption increases in the age of each of the children, thus postponing the peak in household consumption to when dependent children approach adulthood. These authors' specification of the utility function is of additional interest to us because they show that it can explain the magnitude and timing of the rise and peak in life-cycle consumption without recourse to other causal mechanisms, such as liquidity constraints, precautionary motives, and non-separabilities between consumption and labor supply--features that are also absent in our environment. Household utility is given by
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}^{h}e^{-f_{a+s,t+s}}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}e^{f_{a+s,t+s}}$$. | (14) |
One limitation of our framework is that it does not incorporate international influences on the U.S. equilibrium real rate. Or, there are reasons to expect foreign developments to contribute to the determination of domestic interest rates. Notably, there is a strong correlation across real interest rates worldwide, indicating either common driving factors, strong international spillovers, or both.23 In a similar vein, the global saving glut hypothesis of Bernanke (2005) posits that U.S. interest rates have felt downward pressure from an excess of global savings emanating from Asian and oil-producing economies; this hypothesis challenged the idea that the dynamics of the U.S. current account since the mid-1990s reflected primarily domestic developments. More generally, movements in U.S. financial variables are sometimes traced back to foreign economic and political developments, as has been evident during bouts of shifting global risk appetite in the wake of the financial crisis. While we do not aim to explain the effects of these foreign elements on U.S. real interest rates, it is nonetheless legitimate to ask whether open-economy considerations might affect our estimates of the contribution of demographic factors. A number of elements give us confidence that our finding that demographic factors are an economically important driver of the U.S. equilibrium real interest rate is robust to open-economy considerations.
One such element is that the United States and the world's other advanced economies are undergoing demographic transitions that are similar in terms of magnitude and timing. In the top panel of Figure 15, we show that the step down in U.S. working-age population growth since the 1970s echoes a similar pattern in OECD economies and in the world more broadly. The 2000-2030 period features an especially sharp slowdown in population growth. In the bottom panel, we show that the U.S. mean life expectancy at birth has been rising in tandem with that in OECD economies. Similar gains in life expectancy at birth are observed when we include both developed and developing economies, although the level is pulled down by still markedly higher death rates in the less-developed countries.
Another element is the size and direction of international capital flows. In our model, demographic factors put downward pressure on the return on domestic capital. In an open-economy setting with international capital mobility, a fall in the rate of return on domestic capital would, all else equal, induce domestic investors to seek investment opportunities abroad, resulting in a net capital outflow. To the extent that, in aggregate, U.S. investors have succeeded in finding investment opportunities abroad, our closed-economy estimates of the effect of demographics on the U.S. equilibrium real rate could be overestimated. However, in contrast with the prediction of a capital outflow, the U.S. current account balance has been solidly negative since the early 1980s.
A third piece of evidence is that attempts at incorporating demographics in open-economy settings do not suggest economically large differences between closed-economy and open-economy predictions for U.S. real interest rates. In a closely-related study, Krueger & Ludwig (2007) build a multi-country OG model to explore the effects of demographics factors on the rate of return on capital. For their 2005-2080 simulation period, their model projects net declines in the U.S. real interest rate of 86 basis points under the multi-country version of their model and of 79 basis points under the closed-economy version. The difference in point estimates between versions is arguably small and, taken at face value, suggests that foreign demographic developments tend to amplify rather than to dampen the extent to which the U.S. real rate is being pressured downward by demographic developments. Our model without dependent children, which is close to the model considered by Krueger & Ludwig (2007), predicts that the equilibrium real rate will fall by 54 basis points over their sample period. By comparison, our benchmark model with dependent children predicts a net fall in the equilibrium real rate of 79 basis points.
The results of Krueger & Ludwig (2007) present a number of limitations with respect to our questions of interest. One such limitation is that Krueger & Ludwig (2007) focus on projected developments over the course of this century, in contrast with our goal of explaining movements in the equilibrium real rate and other aggregate variables over the past several decades. The initial period in their simulation period--2005--coincides with a period of historically rapid fall in the equilibrium real rate in our model. Importantly for our ability to expand our framework to a multi-country setting, foreign demographic data are generally not as detailed as the U.S. demographic data we use to calibrate our model. Moreover, the time coverage of the foreign demographic data tends to be limited, in turn restricting one's ability to study phenomena unfolding over several generations. For example, their model does not incorporate dependent children and variation in the labor supply across birth cohorts, which we found to be important for explaining the timing and magnitude of the fall in the equilibrium real rate since 1980. Similarly, their exercise leaves aside non-OECD economies for which there is a dearth of demographic data. Nonetheless, these results and the other evidence presented above, taken together, give us reasonable confidence that demographic developments have been an economically important driver of low-frequency movements in U.S. real interest rates over the past few decades.
In this paper, we used a calibrated OG model with a rich demographic structure to investigate the extent to which past and projected changes in U.S. family composition, life expectancy, and the labor supply have had an influence on real interest rates, GDP growth, and other variables. We found that these demographic factors alone account for a $$ 1\frac{1}{4}$$ -percentage-point decline in the natural rate of interest and real GDP growth since 1980--a magnitude that we argue is in line with empirical estimates. Moreover, the model is consistent with the rate of aggregate investment having slowed appreciably over that period. Looking forward, the model suggests that low interest rates, low output growth, and low investment rates are here to stay, suggesting that the U.S. economy has entered a new normal.
We believe that our results will be of interest to academics and policymakers alike. The model implies that the transition to the new normal has been especially rapid over the past decade or so because of demographic factors most-directly associated with the post-war baby boom--a phenomenon that was fully predictable--and the passing effects of the information technology boom on productivity growth. The rapidity at which our model economy has been transitioning to a new normal suggests a risk that the permanent effects of demographic factors could be misinterpreted as persistent but ultimately transitory downward pressure on the natural rate of interest and net savings stemming from the global financial crisis. Going forward, our results have implications for assessing fiscal sustainability. Moreover, the persistence of a low equilibrium real interest rate means that the scope to use conventional monetary policy to stimulate the economy during typical cyclical downturns will be more limited than it has been the case in the past for a given inflation target.
6F
This technical appendix provides information on data sources and data filtering as well as on the solution method we follow to obtain dynamic solutions of our overlapping-generation (OG) model. To ensure full reproducibility of our data series and simulation results, we are making available a collection of Jupyter notebooks that contains all steps necessary to create the data series and solve the model, along with further instructions. The data and model files are coded in the Julia programming language. The head replication file is GJLS_readme.ipynb. The replication files also include a set of R files to reproduce all figures. Jupyter, Julia, and R are all freely available. Please email the authors to obtain the latest set of files.
We construct yearly and quarterly employment-population ratios (EPRs) series by age and birth cohort from 1900 onward. These EPRs are used to calibrate individual labor endowments in the model. The EPRs are defined as
We downloaded the BLS data on August 1, 2016, from http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/srgate. We arranged the data into CSV files to make them easy to read by our programs. The mnemonics for civilian non-institutional population by age group can be found in Table 1. The mnemonics for total civilian employment by age group can be found in Table 2. The mnemonics for unemployment rate by age group can be found in Table 3. The sources for the Census Bureau's total population estimates are described below.
The historical data underlying the EPRs have been published by the BLS starting in 1948. However, the published age categories have changed over time. Starting in 1967, we have monthly data by 5-year age bins from 20 to 74 years old, as well as for 16 to 19 years and 75+ years old. Prior to 1967, we have monthly data for 16 to 19 years old, 20 to 24 years old, and 65+ years old, as well as for 10-year age bins from 25 to 64 years old. Given our interest in low-frequency movements, we initially work with annual data--thus avoiding issues pertaining to seasonal adjustment--and recover quarterly EPR series through cubic spline interpolations of the trend in yearly rates.
We estimate the EPRs for the missing five-year age bins pre-1967 using information from the 10-year age bins. After inspecting the data, we note that the level of the 25 to 29 years old series and of the 30 to 34 series move in roughly equal percentage-point steps with the 25 to 34 series. For these series, we impute the missing pre-1967 levels by making the identifying assumption that the percentage point difference between the series for 25 to 29 years old and for 30 to 34 years old is equal to the difference observed in 1967:
We adopt the same approach to impute missing statistics by five-year age bins for other prime-age workers, for which the employment-population ratio is fairy constant until 55 years old. We also follow the same approach for workers aged between 55 and 64 years old, although inspection of the data suggests somewhat less stability for that age group. For workers aged 65 years or more, we adopt an imputation procedure that is better suited to capture shifts in labor supply late in life. Upon inspection of the data from 1967 onward, we note that the EPRs for 65 to 69 years old, 70 to 74 years old, and 75+ years old are roughly proportional to each other over time. Our imputation method pre-1967 minimizes a weighted sum of square deviations from the EPRs prevailing in 1967,
$$\displaystyle \frac{POP{}_{t}^{{65 to 69}}}{POP{}_{t}^{{65+}}}\times\bigg(\frac{EPR_{t}^{{65 to 69}}}{EPR_{t}^{{65+}}}-\frac{EPR_{1967}^{{65 to 69}}}{EPR_{1967}^{{65+}}}\bigg)^{2}+\frac{POP{}_{t}^{{70 to 74}}}{POP{}_{t}^{{65+}}}\times\bigg(\frac{EPR_{t}^{{70 to 74}}}{EPR_{t}^{{65+}}}-\frac{EPR_{1967}^{{70 to 74}}}{EPR_{1967}^{{65+}}}\bigg)^{2}$$ | |
$$\displaystyle +\frac{POP{}_{t}^{{75+}}}{POP{}_{t}^{{65+}}}\times\bigg(\frac{EPR_{t}^{{75+}}}{EPR_{t}^{{65+}}}-\frac{EPR_{1967}^{{75+}}}{EPR_{1967}^{{65+}}}\bigg)^{2}$$ |
The EPRs of older workers have been increasing over the past few decades along with life expectancy and health conditions, reversing a pattern of declining EPRs in earlier decades. Our projection of EPRs going forward makes use of the BLS' "Employment Projections: 2014-24". The BLS creates these projections to look at employment by industries. Although they do not include projections of EPRs by age in 2024, they do include projections of the labor force participation ratio (LFPR) by age bins. We use that information, along with an assumption about equilibrium employment rates by age, to recover EPRs by age in 2024. In particular, we assume that the labor market in 2015 is in equilibrium and that the unemployment rates by age that prevailed in that year also prevail in 2024.
For individuals aged less than 25 years or more than 54 years, the LFPRs in the "Employment Projections: 2014-24" directly line up with the EPR age bins derived above. For prime-age workers between the age of 25 and 54 years, the "Employment Projections: 2014-24" are structured by ten-year age bins as opposed to five-year age bins. For these age categories, we make the identifying assumption that the percentage-point difference between two contiguous five-year bins is constant between 2014 and 2024, then retrieve the five-year LFPRs consistent with the published ten-year LFPRs. For example, for the 25-34 years old category, we compute $$ LFPR_{{{25{ to }29}}}^{2024}$$ and $$ LFPR_{{{30{ to }34}}}^{2024}$$ using the definition of the LFPR for the 25-34 years old category
and the restriction that
One minor complication is that the "Employment Projections: 2014-24" do not include detailed non-institutional population statistics, so the relative noninstitutional population shares in the above equations are unobserved for 2024. In a manner similar to the imputation of pre-1967 data, we approximate these shares using corresponding data from the U.S. Census Bureau's 2014 National Population Projections for the total U.S. population. See the notebook "Migration.ipynb" for detailed sources.
Another minor complication is that the historical labor market data have been revised since the publication of the "Employment Projections: 2014-24." For this reason, we adjust the level of the 2024 LFPR data such that they imply the same change (as opposed to level) in LFPR by age bins between 2014 and 2024 as reported in the publication. The 2024 LFPRs were downloaded at the link www.bls.gov/emp/ep_table_303.htm on August 1, 2016.
The imputation of EPRs before 1948 is subject to a great deal of uncertainty for several reasons. Notably, the two world wars altered the size and composition of the U.S. labor force. Moreover, home production was arguably more important in light of a large share of the population living in a rural environment. Both of these elements raise questions that are outside of the purview of our model. For this reason, we simply carry back in time the EPRs by age prevailing in 1948.
Similarly, the projection of EPRs beyond 2024 is subject to a great deal of uncertainty. On the one hand, one might expect further improvement in health and life expectancy to continue to raise the LFPR of older persons. On the other hand, the historical correlation between these variables is very weak outside of the recent decades. Moreover, some of the rise in EPRs over the past couple decades might reflect in part increases in the minimum age at which one becomes eligible to draw social security benefits. Our approach is to simply level off the post-2024 EPRs at their 2024 levels.
To make the data consistent with the time period in the model simulation, the data by age group are carried backward in time before 1948 and forward in time after 2024. Cyclical variation in the data by age group is next removed using an Hodrick-Prescott filter with a Lagrange multiplier of 25,000. We then interpolate the trends in the data by age group across age and over calendar periods using cubic splines. Although our model pools EPRs across genders, we separately compute EPRs for men and women to help us provide a narrative of the changes in EPRs over time. Figures by gender and for the total population are provided in the Jupyter notebook.
Our estimates of mortality rates by age and birth cohort are based on information contained in the publication "Life Tables for the United States Social Security Area 1900-2100" from the Social Security Administration. We downloaded the tables from https://www.ssa.gov/oact/NOTES/as120/LifeTables_Body.html on August 1, 2016. We use two sets of tables: Tables 6 report estimates of the marginal probabilities of death for a person of a given age (in years) at the turn of a particular decade. Tables 7 report estimates of the annualized probabilities of death by years of age for an individual born at the turn of a particular decade.
Bell & Miller (2005) provide mortality tables for each gender but not for the total population. To compute mortality rates for all individuals, we first assume that the ratio of live male births to live female births is constant over time. We then aggregate, for each birth cohort and age, the mortality rates of males and females using their respective shares of the birth cohort that has survived up to that age. The probabilities of surviving to a given age for each cohort and gender are based on the information contained in Tables 6 and Tables 7. The ratio of male births to female births is set to 1.05 based on the analysis of Mathews & Hamilton (2005) at the Center for Disease Control. A value of 1.05 is close to the median yearly value over their 1940-2002 sample period, with the values ranging roughly from 1.046 to 1.059. For Table 7, we simply rescale the male cohort by 5 percent, then take a weighted average across gender based on the number of males/females alive at beginning of period. We apply the same procedure to Table 6. To the extent that mortality rates by age for people alive in 1900 differ from those applying to people born in 1900, the procedure is inexact. However, any difference it might create on the weighed mortality rates across gender should be small and only affect the seeding of the 1900 population in the simulation.
Once we have aggregated the data across genders, we use cubic splines to interpolate the information from Tables 6 and Tables 7 across ages and calendar periods from 1900 to 2100. With those interpolations at hand, we assume that the estimated rates conditional on age in 2100 prevail in all subsequent periods. Similarly, we assume that the estimated rates in 1900 prevailed in all previous periods. In theory, we could use the information in Tables 7 to impute mortality rates beyond 2100 for people born in 2100 or earlier. Similarly, we could use the information in Tables 6 to impute mortality rates prior to 1900 for people born before that year. However, the available usable information before 1900 and beyond 2100 is sparse and, in any case, its usage would have little to no effect on the simulation results over the period of interest. For this reason, we find it convenient to estimate the mortality rates by age of people alive between 1900 and 2100, and carry those rates backward and forward in time as necessary in our applications.
In our model, population size and composition evolves over time as people are born, die, age, and migrate. The construction of our birth rates and mortality rates series was detailed above. This subsection discusses how, given our birth and mortality rates, we create our net migration rates in a way that ensures that the size and composition of the total population closely matches the Census Bureau's historical estimates and projections of population from 1900 to 2060 under our baseline specification of the model.
We amalgamate several Census Bureau products to create a consistent resident population series by single years of age over the 1900-2060 period. All data sources measure the resident population as of July 1 of each calendar year. Up to 2010, we use "intercensal" population statistics, for which Census staff adjusted the data in ways that reconcile discrepancies between decennial censuses and intermediate estimates. For the 2010-2014 data, we use the 2015 vintage of "postcensal" population estimates, which are based on adjustments to the 2010 Census figures based on estimates of births, deaths, and migration. Similarly, we use the latest set of population projections from 2014 to 2060 based on the 2010 Census. The data sources are listed below, along with the age coverage available.
The derivation of net migration estimates uses information on our interpolation of mortality rates from Bell & Miller (2005). Per our timing assumptions, births, deaths, and migration take place at the beginning of the period whereas population measurement takes place at the end. Thus, we treat a population estimate for July 1 as corresponding to the population at the end of the second quarter of the calendar year. By definition,
For the data beyond 2060, we assume that our estimates of net migration linearly converge to those published by the Census for 2060. These Census estimates are roughly consistent with a stabilization in the absolute level of net migration around 2060. Our estimates and those of the Census for 2060 are similar with two minor exceptions. First, our estimated number of the net migration of infants (that is, less than a year old) is mildly negative whereas that of the Census is a bit positive, likely reflecting differences in assumptions between the UN projections that we used for projecting live births through 2100 and the assumptions underlying the Census population projections (the details of these Census assumptions are not publicly available). Second, we have slightly negative net migration for older people, likely capturing differences in assumptions about mortality late in life. Both elements are unlikely to affect our macroeconomic results as they have little if any incidence on the aggregate capital-labor ratio.
Due to our interpolation to a quarterly frequency of age and calendar period, our population statistics need not correspond exactly to those published by the Census Bureau. However, the difference accumulated to only about 1/4 percent of the level of the population by 2060, indicating that the cumulative discrepancy is very small.
This subsection deals with our stitching of historical estimates and projections of live births in the United States to produce a consistent series from 1900 onward. It uses information from four data sources:
To derive yearly birth estimates based on yearly Census population figures, we initially assume that the number of quarterly births is constant between population measurements, which correspond to July 1 of each calendar year. This identifying assumption is made to take into account high infant mortality in the initial quarters of life. The steps in the underlying quarterly birth series are then smoothed when we aggregate the data back to a yearly frequency and then use splines to extract a smooth quarterly series. Consistent with these timing assumptions, we treat Census population estimates as of July 1 as if they correspond to the measure of the surviving population at the end of the second quarter of calendar years. Given that the calibration uses quarterly data, alternative timing assumptions with respect to births, deaths, and population measurement would have negligible consequences for our population and births estimates.
We now detail the extraction of estimates of live birth from the yearly population series. Let $$ POP_{\left[0,1\right),t}$$ be the number of infants less than a year old estimated by the Census at the end of period t. Let Bt be the number of births at the beginning of period t; consistent with the model, births take place before deaths during the period, so that newborns face a nonzero probability of not reaching period t+1. The number of infants less than a year old is the sum of surviving births in the current and previous three quarters,
$$\displaystyle POP_{\left[0,1\right),t}=\gamma_{0,t}B_{t}+\gamma_{1,t}\gamma_{0,t-1}B_{t-1}+\gamma_{2,t}\gamma_{1,t-1}\gamma_{0,t-2}B_{t-2}+\gamma_{3,t}\gamma_{2,t-1}\gamma_{1,t-2}\gamma_{0,t-3}B_{t-3}$$, | (15) |
For the 1972-2014 period, we get annual birth figures directly from NCHS.24 The annual NCHS estimates tracks the annual estimates that we derived above from mortality rates and infant population estimates from 1972 to 1979 when the two samples overlap. We thus construct an annual births series from 1900 to 2014 by stitching the yearly figures derived from Census estimates for 1900 to 1971 with those from NCHS for 1972 to 2014.
To obtain annual birth estimates after 2014 onward, we note that, in recent decades, yearly observations from the NCHS series essentially coincide with the corresponding five-year WPPmeasured at the middle year (the blue circles). We thus allocate WPP data after 2009&rarr#to; the mid-point of their five-year intervals through 2100, and stitch those five-year observations with the annual series through 2014. We then use cubic splines to extract quarterly birth estimates from 1900:Q2 to 2099:Q4. Of note, by the end of the current century, the WPP data project that live births have stabilized. Using this observation, we impose that the number of live births is constant from the last WPP data point (that is, 2097.5) through 2400. This assumption, along with constant mortality rates and no immigration, ensures the existence of a stable population distribution in the model over the long run.
Finally, we note that our live birth estimates do not adjust for infants who might have migrated to the United States or a foreign country in the period they were born. The series may also be subject to imprecise reporting or minor errors in our imputation. That said, our procedure that uses net international migration to ensure that the size and composition of total population remains consistent with the population figures published by the Census Bureau should correct any discrepancy.
To take into account the effects of family composition on households' economic decisions, we need to allocate births to their parents. In this subsection, we first construct a time series of live births from a variety of sources. We then allocate the births to their mothers based on the historical shares of births by the age of mothers. We finally adjust the age of the mother in a way that factors in the historical age difference between fathers and mothers, so that adults are representative of both genders. Per our timing assumptions in the model, we posit that births, deaths, and population measurement occur sequentially during the period.
The data on the number of births by age of mother is taken from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention's National Center for Health Statistics (NCHS). The data can be found under "Cohort Fertility Tables" at www.cdc.gov/nchs/cohort_fertility_tables.htm (last accessed on August 8, 2016). We downloaded the data on August 8, 2016. We use two sets of historic tables. The first set is put together by Hamilton & Cosgrove (2010) and consists of two separate data releases. The first release is titled "Table 1. Central birth rates, by live-birth order, current age, and race of women in each cohort from 1911 through 1991: United States, 1960-2005". The second release is titled "Table 1. Central birth rates, by live-birth order, current age, and race of women in each cohort from 1957 through 1995: United States, 2006-2009". The methodology and data sources are consistent across the two releases. We saved the data in separate CSV files that are read in the notebook below. Consistent with the timing of population estimates in the Census, women who belong to, say, the 1960 cohort, are born within a twelve-month period centered on January 1, 1960, and thus running from July 1, 1959, to June 30, 1960.
The second set of data is based on the historical publication "Fertility Tables for Birth Cohorts by Color: United States, 1917-73", DHEW Publication No. (HRA) 76-1152, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, April 1976, Washington D.C. The link to a PDF of that publication is http://www.cdc.gov.nchs/dad/misc/fertiltbacc.pdf (last accessed on August 8, 2016). We extracted the information from Table 4A, "Central birth rates for all women during each year 1917-1973 by age and life-birth order for each cohort from 1868 to 1959, Total birth group", and entered that information manually into a CSV file.
The two sets of files do not use identical methodology. In particular, there are methodological differences in judgmental adjustments for under-registration of births, under-enumeration of the number of women, and misstatement of age for all years. That said, the differences appear too small to have a material effect on the key simulation results in our paper. We also note that the shares of births by age of the mother are fairly similar for the overlapping period between 1960 and 1973. For these reasons, we use the 1960-2009 data in their entirety, and only the 1917-1959 data from the early sample. Finally, we assume that the share of births attributable to mothers by age were constant at their 1917 level in all prior years. Similarly, we carry forward the shares in 2009 to all subsequent years.
We adjust the age of the mother by an estimate of the age difference between married men and women to obtain the age of the representative parent. This adjustment is based on our interpolation of historical information on the median age of men and women at time of their first marriage published by the Census Bureau. The data are obtained at www.census.gov/hhes/families/data/marital.html (downloaded on August 8, 2016). The publication is called "Estimated Median Age at First Marriage, by Sex: 1890 to the Present". These data cover the period 1890 to 2015. Yearly estimates are available staring in 1947; prior to that year, only decennial estimates corresponding to census years are available.
The median age gap between men and women has been somewhat stable over the past several decades, at between 1.5 and 2.5 years. In our application, we assume that average age difference observed in recent years will prevail beyond 2015, then fit a polynomial to the historical and projected values to obtain a smooth series.
A question arises with teen pregnancies because young parents may still be dependent children themselves. In the absence of detailed information, we follow a somewhat simple procedure. Whenever a child is born to a representative parent whose average age is less than 18 years old, we temporarily allocate the child to her representative grandparent until the representative parent turns 18 years old, at which point the representative parent becomes fully responsible for her child's consumption. With all the above information at hand, we can allocate children at the end of 1899 to their parents and calculate the average number of dependents entering the parents' consumption function. We can then iteratively calculate the population and family structure over the full sample period by letting the population evolve according to births, deaths, and net migration. Finally, we note that our procedure works only with averages rather than actual family cells. For example, deaths of adults and children do not result in discrete jumps in the number of surviving parents or dependents.
For our alternative dynamic simulation with historical total factor productivity (TFP) growth, we primarily use historical quarterly estimates compiled by Fernald (2014). The data were downloaded on on May 25, 2016, from the San Francisco Fed's website at the following link: http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/indicators-data/total-factor-productivity-tfp/. The estimates run from 1947:Q2 to 2016:Q1. More documentation on the methodology can be found on the website as well as the accompanying Excel spreadsheet.
We extend the Fernald series forward in time using projections made by Gordon (2015). This author estimates that total factor productivity will grow at a annual rate of 1.1 percent per year through 2032, a rate that we extend beyond that date. We also extend the Fernald series back in time using an informed guess of average technology growth in earlier decades. The rate chosen--2 percent--is in the middle of the range of estimates surveyed by Shackleton (2013).
Our simulations do not seek to explain high-frequency movements in the equilibrium real rate, GDP, and other aggregate variables. For this reason, we feed our model with a smoothed version of the quarterly (log) TFP growth series. To create this smoothed series, we first convert our extended Fernald TFP growth series to levels and then use the Hodrick-Prescott filter on the log of that resulting series to extract a smooth trend; the Lagrange multiplier is set to 25,000. We finally convert the smoothed level series back to growth rates (again measured in log changes).
The model we consider in this technical appendix is slightly more general than in the paper in that it allows for subsistence levels in the consumption of adults and their dependent children. The introduction of these objects in done in a manner that preserves the balanced growth properties of the model.
A representative adult aged a in period t maximizes
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\left(\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}-Z_{t+s}\bar{C}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}+\epsilon\left(n_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{\eta}\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}^{c}-Z_{t+s}\bar{C}^{c}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}\right),$$ | (16) |
The first-order optimality conditions of the household are
$$\displaystyle \epsilon\left(n_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{\eta}\left(C_{a+s,t+s}^{c}-Z_{t+s}\bar{C^{c}}\right)^{-\nu}=n_{a,t+s}\lambda_{a,t+s}$$ | (18) |
$$\displaystyle \lambda_{a+s,t+s}=\beta\lambda_{a+1+s,t+1+s}\left(R_{t+1+s}^{K}+1-\delta\right)$$ | (19) |
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\left(1+\epsilon^{\frac{1}{\nu}}\left(n_{a+s,t+s}\right)^{1+\frac{\eta-1}{\nu}}\right)\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}-Z_{t+s}\bar{C}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}$$ | (20) |
$$\displaystyle \left(\frac{C_{a+1,t+1}-Z_{t+1}\bar{C}}{C_{a,t}-Z_{t}\bar{C}}\right)^{\nu}=\beta\Gamma_{a,t,t+1}\left(1+R_{t+1}^{K}-\delta\right).$$ | (21) |
Firms maximize
$$\displaystyle \frac{W_{t}}{Z_{t}}=\left(1-\alpha\right)\left(\frac{Y_{t}}{Z_{t}L_{t}}\right)^{1-\rho}.$$ | (23) |
In our OG economy, the size of the population varies from period to period as new individuals are born and others die. Let $$ \mu_{s,t}$$ be the number of individuals aged s at the beginning of period t after a new cohort of babies have been delivered but before deaths have occurred. Equilibrium in the labor market requires that
In a perfect-foresight equilibrium, in each period, (a) goods and factor markets clear, (b) factor prices correspond to their marginal product, (c) the bequests received by surviving adults sum up to the capital held by adults who passed away at the beginning of the period (net of any destroyed capital), and (d) household optimality conditions are satisfied.
We follow an iterative procedure to compute an equilibrium in which (a) cohort-representative adults and the representative firm optimize conditional aggregate variables and demographic factors and (b) aggregate objects are consistent with the aggregation of individual decisions across adults and firms. This equilibrium is conditional on the path of the parameters of the model, the demographic variables, and initial distributions of the population and capital holdings. The steps in the procedure are as follows:
The most computing intensive element is step 4 because it requires solving each cohort-representative adult's life-cycle problem. The computation of a solution is made simpler by two sets of assumptions. First, the problem is solved under perfect foresight of demographic and aggregate variables. Second, as we show below, the problem of the adult is linear in leads and lags of her capital holdings conditional on the paths of the aggregate objects and demographics. This linearity allows us to use linear algebra techniques to quickly derive a solution. Before we do so, we scale the equilibrium objects so that we have a stationary equilibrium along the balanced growth path.
Let the generic variable $$ \tilde{X}_{t}=X_{t}/Z_{t}$$ , where Zt is labor augmenting technology. We begin by scaling the representative firm's optimality conditions--Equations (23) and (24)--that relate the real rental rate of capital to its marginal product,
We note that the above expression is linear in the leads and lags of individual capital holdings conditional on aggregate variables and demographic factors. This observation allows us to express the equilibrium conditions of a cohort-representative adult aged a in period t as a system of linear equations, $$ \mathbf{M}\left(a,t\right)\mathbf{\tilde{K}}\left(a,t\right)=\mathbf{\Psi}\left(a,t\right)$$ . The vector of length $$ \left(A-a\right)$$ containing the scaled capital holdings of the representative adult is
We consider a variant of the preferences in Browning & Ejrnæs (2009) in which total household consumption increases in the ages of the children. The motivation for considering this alternative specification is two-fold. First, the predicted peak in household consumption in our baseline model occurs earlier in the life cycle than it does in the data; the adult-equivalent consideration recognizes that older children tend to require more resources for schooling, entertainment, etc, thus postponing the peak in consumption later in the life of the household. Second, this specification has encountered empirical success in terms of generating realistic life-cycle dynamics. Browning & Ejrnæs (2009) show that an adult-equivalent specification can match pre-retirement consumption dynamics of adult couples--including the sharp rise in the early years--without recourse to any other contributing factors (which include liquidity constraints, rules of thumbs, precautionary motives, and non-separability between consumption and the supply of labor).
As was the case with the main version of the model, we consider a more general specification of the utility function that features subsistence levels in consumption. This specification is also consistent with balanced growth. One difference with the baseline specification of the utility function is that the consumption of adults and their dependent children can no longer be expressed in an additive manner.
Household utility is given by
$$\displaystyle \sum_{s=0}^{A-a}\beta^{s}\Gamma_{a,t,t+s}\frac{\left(C_{a+s,t+s}^{h}e^{-f_{a+s,t+s}}-Z_{t+s}\bar{C}\right)^{1-\nu}}{1-\nu}e^{f_{a+s,t+s}}$$, | (24) |
The objective is to maximize Equation (25). We can write the Lagrangian as
Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Age | Total | Men | Women |
---|---|---|---|
16 to 19 years | LNU00000012 | LNU00000013 | LNU00000014 |
20 to 24 years | LNU00000036 | LNU00000037 | LNU00000038 |
25 to 29 years | LNU00024932 | LNU00000163 | LNU00000326 |
30 to 34 years | LNU00024933 | LNU00000171 | LNU00000332 |
35 to 39 years | LNU00024934 | LNU00000172 | LNU00000333 |
40 to 44 years | LNU00024935 | LNU00000179 | LNU00000338 |
45 to 49 years | LNU00024936 | LNU00000181 | LNU00000340 |
50 to 54 years | LNU00024937 | LNU00000188 | LNU00000345 |
55 to 59 years | LNU00000094 | LNU00000189 | LNU00000346 |
60 to 64 years | LNU00000096 | LNU00000197 | LNU00000352 |
65 to 69 years | LNU00024938 | LNU00000203 | LNU00000358 |
70 to 74 years | LNU00024941 | LNU00024939 | LNU00024940 |
75+ years | LNU00024942 | LNU00015346 | LNU00015349 |
25 to 34 years | LNU02000089 | LNU02000164 | LNU02000327 |
35 to 44 years | LNU02000091 | LNU02000173 | LNU02000334 |
45 to 54 years | LNU02000093 | LNU02000182 | LNU02000341 |
55 to 64 years | LNU02000095 | LNU02000190 | LNU02000347 |
65+ years | LNU02000097 | LNU02000199 | LNU02000354 |
Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Age | Total | Men | Women |
---|---|---|---|
16 to 19 years | LNU02000012 | LNU02000013 | LNU02000014 |
20 to 24 years | LNU02000036 | LNU02000037 | LNU02000038 |
25 to 29 years | LNU02024932 | LNU02000163 | LNU02000326 |
30 to 34 years | LNU02024933 | LNU02000171 | LNU02000332 |
35 to 39 years | LNU02024934 | LNU02000172 | LNU02000333 |
40 to 44 years | LNU02024935 | LNU02000179 | LNU02000338 |
45 to 49 years | LNU02024936 | LNU02000181 | LNU02000340 |
50 to 54 years | LNU02024937 | LNU02000188 | LNU02000345 |
55 to 59 years | LNU02000094 | LNU02000189 | LNU02000346 |
60 to 64 years | LNU02000096 | LNU02000197 | LNU02000352 |
65 to 69 years | LNU02024938 | LNU02000203 | LNU02000358 |
70 to 74 years | LNU02024941 | LNU02024939 | LNU02024940 |
75+ years | LNU02024942 | LNU02015346 | LNU02015349 |
25 to 34 years | LNU00000089 | LNU00000164 | LNU00000327 |
35 to 44 years | LNU00000091 | LNU00000173 | LNU00000334 |
45 to 54 years | LNU00000093 | LNU00000182 | LNU00000341 |
55 to 64 years | LNU00000095 | LNU00000190 | LNU00000347 |
65+ years | LNU00000097 | LNU00000199 | LNU00000354 |
Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Age | Total | Men | Women |
---|---|---|---|
16 to 19 years | LNU04000012 | LNU04000013 | LNU04000014 |
20 to 24 years | LNU04000036 | LNU04000037 | LNU04000038 |
25 to 29 years | LNU04024932 | LNU04000163 | LNU04000326 |
30 to 34 years | LNU04024933 | LNU04000171 | LNU04000332 |
35 to 39 years | LNU04024934 | LNU04000172 | LNU04000333 |
40 to 44 years | LNU04024935 | LNU04000179 | LNU04000338 |
45 to 49 years | LNU04024936 | LNU04000181 | LNU04000340 |
50 to 54 years | LNU04024937 | LNU04000188 | LNU04000345 |
55 to 59 years | LNU04000094 | LNU04000189 | LNU04000346 |
60 to 64 years | LNU04000096 | LNU04000197 | LNU04000352 |
65 to 69 years | LNU04024938 | LNU04000203 | LNU04000358 |
70 to 74 years | LNU04024941 | LNU04024939 | LNU04024940 |
75+ years | LNU04024942 | LNU04015346 | LNU04015349 |